BoC Releases Autumn 2012 Review

The Bank of Canada has released the Bank of Canada Review – Autumn 2012 with articles:

The first article attracted some notice from the Globe and Mail, in pieces by David Parkinson and Kevin Carmichael. An earlier working paper by Ms. Pomeranets and Daniel G. Weaver which focussed on the historical experience in New York State was reviewed on PrefBlog. This paper was quoted in support of the conclusion:

On balance, the literature suggests that an FTT is unlikely to reduce volatility and may instead increase it, which is consistent with arguments made by opponents of the tax.

The current paper is introduced with:

ƒƒ

  • The financial transaction tax (FTT) is a policy idea with a long history that, in the wake of the global financial crisis, has attracted renewed interest in some quarters.
  • Historically, there have been two motivating factors for the introduction of the tax. The first is its potential to raise substantial revenues, and the second is its perceived potential to discourage speculative trading and reduce volatility.
  • There is, however, little empirical evidence that an FTT reduces volatility. Numerous studies suggest that an FTT harms market quality and is associated with an increase in volatility and a decrease in both market liquidity and trading volume. When the cost of acquiring a security rises, its required rate of return and cost of capital also increase. As a result, an FTT may reduce the flow of profitable projects, decreasing levels of real production, expansion, capital investment and even employment.
  • There are many unanswered questions regarding the design of FTTs and their ability to raise significant revenues.

The imposition of a 20bp transaction charge in France (which has resulted in a greater interest in derivatives such as Contracts For Difference) was discussed on PrefBlog on November 15.

The authors also see fit to highlight:

Umlauf (1993) examines how financial transaction taxes (FTT s) affect stock market behaviour in Sweden. In 1984, Sweden introduced a 1 per cent tax on equity transactions, which was doubled to 2 per cent in 1986. Umlauf studies the impact of these changes on volatility and finds that volatility did not decline following the increase to the 2 per cent tax rate, but equity prices, on average, did decline.

Furthermore, Umlauf concludes that 60 per cent of the trading volume of the 11 most actively traded Swedish share classes migrated to London to avoid the tax. After the migration, the volatilities of London-traded shares fell relative to their Stockholm-traded counterparts. As trading volumes fell in Stockholm, so did revenues from capital gains taxes, completely offsetting the 4 billion Swedish kronor that the tax had raised in 1988.

Pomeranets also points out:

Critics of the FTT argue that it reduces market liquidity by making each trade more costly, simply because it is a tax and also because market forces react to it by offering fewer and lower-quality trading opportunities. The cost impact is evident in the way the FTT widens the bid-ask spread. Bid-ask spreads compensate traders for three things—order-processing costs, inventory risk and information risk—often called the three components of the bid-ask spread. The FTT will increase the costs of these three components in the following ways:…

And finally, we get the the social function of markets – capital formation:

Another measure of market quality examined in the literature is the cost of capital. Amihud and Mendelson (1992) conclude that a 0.5 per cent FTT would lead to a 1.33 per cent increase in the cost of capital. This result is consistent with their previous work that finds a positive relationship between required rates of return and transaction costs (Amihud and Mendelson 1986). When the cost of acquiring a security increases, its required rate of return and cost of capital also increase. As a result, an FTT would increase the cost of capital, which could have several harmful consequences. It could reduce the flow of profitable projects, shrinking levels of real production, expansion, capital investment and even employment.

Ms. Pomeranets concludes:

This article examines the main arguments regarding the costs and benefits of FTTs and explores some of the significant practical issues surrounding the implementation of an FTT. Little evidence is found to suggest that an FTT would reduce speculative trading or volatility. In fact, several studies conclude that an FTT increases volatility and bid-ask spreads and decreases trading volume. Furthermore, a number of challenges associated with the design and effectiveness of an FTT could limit the revenues that FTTs are intended to raise. For these reasons, countries considering the imposition of FTTs should be aware of their negative consequences and the challenges involved in implementation.

The second article examines a hobby-horse of mine – central clearing for derivatives, a dangerous policy recklessly promoted by the political establishment both directly and through their mouthpiece, Lapdog Carney. The last BoC attempt at justification, in the June 2012 Financial System Review was discussed on PrefBlog.

In this go-round, the authors state:

ƒƒ

  • Central counterparties manage and mitigate counterparty credit risk in order to make markets more resilient and reduce systemic risk. Better management of counterparty risk can also open up markets to new participants, which in turn should reduce concentration and increase competition. These benefits are maximized when access to central counterparties is available to a wide range of market participants.
  • In an over-the-counter market, there is an important trade-off between competition and risk. Concentrated, less competitive markets are more profitable and thus participants are less likely to default. But a central counterparty that provides sufficient access can improve this trade-off, since the gains from diversification—which will become greater as participation grows—can simultaneously reduce risk and increase competition.
  • Regulators have developed, and central counterparties are implementing, new standards for fair, open and risk-based access criteria. Such standards will, among other things, counter any incentives that might exist for members of a central counterparty to limit access in order to protect their market share.

In other words, a major goal of Central Clearing is to provide employment for regulators, who will make fair and open, and, it must be emphasized, entirely corruption-free decisions regarding which smaller and and less creditworthy firms will be admitted to the club.

The crux of the matter is this:

The improved management of counterparty credit risk at a CCP opens markets to greater participation, which can increase competition. In OTC markets that are cleared bilaterally, participants are directly exposed to the risk that their counterparties may default and therefore have an incentive to restrict trading to counterparties that are known to be creditworthy. When a CCP with strong risk controls takes on the management of credit risk, however, participants can feel more secure trading with others—even anonymously— since the CCP guarantees that the terms of the trade will be honoured.

In other words, when the Bank of Downtown Plonksville enters into a trade with central clearing, its counter-party will charge exactly the same risk premium as it charges to the Bank of Canada. Some people consider this to be an advantage of the new regime.

If direct access to a CCP was limited to the largest dealers, their systemic importance would increase, potentially exacerbating the “too-big-to-fail” problem and preventing the CCP from providing the full benefits of diversification. Limited access could also make mid-tier institutions more vulnerable in times of stress and slow the transition to central clearing (Slive, Wilkins and Witmer 2011).

I wonder if the CCP itself is “too-big-to-fail” ….

The authors emphasize the importance of regulators and their awesomely wise, highly informed decisions throughout the process.

The third article is introduced with:

ƒƒ

  • The financial crisis of 2007–09 and the subsequent extended period of historically low real interest rates in a number of major advanced economies have revived the question of whether economic agents are willing to take on more risk when interest rates remain low for a prolonged time period.
  • This type of induced behaviour—an increased appetite for risk that causes economic agents to search for investment assets and strategies that generate higher investment returns—has been called the risk-taking channel of monetary policy.
  • Recent academic research on banks suggests that lending policies in times of low interest rates can be consistent with the existence of a risk taking channel of monetary policy in Europe, South America, the United
    States and Canada. Specifically, studies find that the terms of loans to risky borrowers become less stringent in periods of low interest rates. This risk-taking channel may amplify the effects of traditional transmission mechanisms, resulting in the creation of excessive credit.

This effect is also inherent in the offsetting behaviours of the “expectations” component and the “risk premium” component of long-term rates, discussed in the Summer 2012 review discussed in PrefBlog.

The results suggest that the difference in the all-in-drawn spreads between loans to risky and less-risky borrowers decreases when interest rates are low relative to periods when they are high. Accounting for loan, firm and bank balance-sheet factors, as well as yearly and quarterly factors, the results show that the difference in the all-in-drawn spread between risky and less-risky borrowers is 48 per cent smaller when interest rates are lower than when they are higher (based on the first definition). This result is also economically significant: it implies that the difference in loan rates between risky and less-risky borrowers is 107 basis points smaller when the rates are low than when they are high.

The fourth article, of great interest to those in the field and to the Bank, but of somewhat less importance to other investors, is summarized as:

ƒƒ

  • The share of cash in overall retail payments has decreased continuously
    over the past 20 years.

  • Recent Bank of Canada research on consumers’ choice of payment instruments indicates that cash is frequently used for transactions with low values because of its speed, ease of use and wide acceptance, while debit and credit cards are more commonly used for transactions with higher values because of perceived attributes such as safety and record keeping.
  • While innovations in retail payments currently being introduced into the Canadian marketplace could lead to a further reduction in the use of cash over the longer term, the implications for the use of cash of some of the structural and regulatory developments under way are less clear.
  • The Bank of Canada will continue to monitor various developments in retail payments and study their implications for the demand for cash over the longer term.

Leave a Reply

You must be logged in to post a comment.