Archive for the ‘Regulation’ Category

Treasury Announces Bank Capitalization Wish-List

Thursday, September 3rd, 2009

Treasury has announced:

the core principles that should guide reform of the international regulatory capital and liquidity framework to better protect the safety and soundness of individual banking firms and the stability of the global financial system and economy.

There are eight of these core principles given a brief explanation in the detailed announcement:

Core Principle #1: Capital requirements should be designed to protect the stability of the financial system (as well as the solvency of individual banking firms).

Among other things, a macro-prudential approach to regulation means: (i) reducing the extent to which the capital and accounting frameworks permit risk to accumulate in boom times, exacerbating the volatility of credit cycles; (ii) incorporating features that encourage or force banking firms to build larger capital cushions in good times; (iii) raising capital requirements for bank and non-bank financial firms that pose a threat to financial stability because of their combination of size, leverage, interconnectedness, and liquidity risk (Tier 1 FHCs) and for systemically risky exposure types; and (iv) improving the ability of banking firms to withstand firm-specific and system-wide liquidity shocks that can set off deleveraging spirals.

The document refers to Tier 1 FHCs quite often, raising the disquieting potential that this status will officially bestowed, which is the wrong thing to do. Instead, it would be far superior to (i) assign a progressive surcharge onto Risk-Weighted Assets as the firm gets larger; e.g., if RWA=$250-billion, no surcharge; 10% surcharge on the next $50-billion; 20% on the next $50-billion; and so on. A dual-track regime (one for Tier 1 FHCs, another for also-rans) is just going to create problems; and (ii) eliminate the favoured status of bank paper in the risk-weighting, so that banks in general hold less of each other’s paper.

Core Principle #2: Capital requirements for all banking firms should be higher, and capital requirements for Tier 1 FHCs should be higher than capital requirements for other banking firms.

See above

Core Principle #3: The regulatory capital framework should put greater emphasis on higher quality forms of capital.

For these reasons, during good economic conditions, common equity should constitute a large majority of a banking firm’s tier 1 capital, and tier 1 capital should constitute a large majority of a banking firm’s total regulatory capital. In addition, the inclusion in regulatory capital of deferred tax assets and non-equity hybrid and other innovative securities should be subject to strict, internationally consistent qualitative and quantitative limits.
We also consider it important that voting common equity represent a large majority of a banking firm’s tier 1 capital.

In other words, they don’t like the extent to which preferred shares and Innovative Tier 1 Capital have been used and they really dislike sub-debt.

Core Principle #4: Risk-based capital requirements should be a function of the relative risk of a banking firm’s exposures, and risk-based capital ratios should better reflect a banking firm’s current financial condition.

Among other things, we must reduce to the extent possible the vulnerabilities that may arise from excessive regulatory reliance on internal banking firm models or ratings from credit rating agencies to measure risk.
Risk weights should be a function of the asset-specific risk of the various exposure types, but they also should reflect the systemic importance of the various exposure types. From a macro-prudential perspective, exposure types that exhibit a high correlation with the economic cycle, or whose prevalence is likely to contribute disproportionately to financial instability in times of economic stress, should attract higher risk-based capital charges than other exposure types that have the same level of expected risk. One of the key examples of a systemically risky exposure type during the recent crisis was the structured finance credit protection purchased by many banking firms from AIG, the monoline insurance companies, and other thinly capitalized special purpose derivatives products companies.

I think that this is as close as Treasury will every get to admitting it goofed big-time on allowing uncollateralized leverage credit protection to offset cash positions.

Core Principle #5: The procyclicality of the regulatory capital and accounting regimes should be reduced and consideration should be given to introducing countercyclical elements into the regulatory capital regime.

The regulatory capital and accounting frameworks should be modified in several ways to reduce their procyclicality. First, the regulatory capital regime should require banking firms to hold a buffer over their minimum capital requirements during good economic times (to be available for drawing down in bad economic times).

There’s a possibility that good times and bad times might become something of a political football, isn’t there? We should not forget that one reason why the FDIC has to increase rates charged to banks right now is because Congress gave a long contribution holiday for political reasons.

I am gratified to see:

Finally, we should examine the merits of providing favorable regulatory capital treatment for, or requiring some banking firms (such as Tier 1 FHCs) to issue, appropriately designed contingent capital instruments – including (i) long-term debt instruments that convert to equity capital in stressed conditions; or (ii) fully secured insurance arrangements that pay out to banking firms in stressed conditions.

See my essay on insurers’ risk transformation.

Core Principle #6: Banking firms should be subject to a simple, non-risk-based leverage constraint.

To mitigate potential adverse effects from an overly simplistic leverage constraint, the constraint should at a minimum incorporate off-balance sheet items.

They couldn’t get the Europeans to agree to the leverage ratio last time, and now they’re MAD!

Core Principle #7: Banking firms should be subject to a conservative, explicit liquidity standard.

The liquidity regime should be independent from the regulatory capital regime. The liquidity regime should make both individual banking firms and the broader financial system more resilient by limiting the externalities that banking firms can create by taking on imprudent levels and forms of funding mismatch. Introducing strict but flexible liquidity regulations would reduce the chances of destabilizing runs by enhancing the ability of debtor banking firms to withstand withdrawals of short-term funding and by making creditor banking firms less likely to withdraw short-term funding from other firms.

Much of this would be addressed by eliminating the favourable risk-weighting applied to inter-bank holdings, as noted above.

Core Principle #8: Stricter capital requirements for the banking system should not result in the re-emergence of an under-regulated non-bank financial sector that poses a threat to financial stability.

Money market mutual funds will be subject to tighter regulation, including tighter regulation of their credit and liquidity risks.

Basically, they want to regulate everything that moves, which will have bad effects on the economy. They should spend more time properly regulating the boundary between banks and non-banks, so that shadow-bank collapses will not have a severe effect on the highly regulated core banking system.

C-EBS Releases Counter-Cyclical Capital Buffer Position Paper

Friday, July 17th, 2009

The Committee of European Banking Supervisors has released a position paper on counter-cyclical capital buffers, favouring discretionary supervision (Pillar 2) over Capital Rules (Pillar 1):

While the mechanisms identified might be alternatively employed in Pillar 1, its use under the Pillar 2 umbrella is still considered the most sensible option at this stage. Pillar 2 allows for flexibility in testing new prudential tools; moreover, an application in Pillar 1 would require further work and refinements.

With regard to this last point a meeting with rating agencies was organized. They stated very clearly that transparency on capital adequacy is a key issue and it is a precondition for market acceptance of time-varying capital buffers. Rating agencies seem to prefer Pillar 1 solutions, considered more transparent [and] less prone to national discretions; however, they seem also aware that Pillar 2 would allow quicker responses and may be used for testing tools to be subsequently improved and, possibly, implemented under Pillar 1.

I suggest it’s not a matter of awareness: it’s a matter of trust. In Canada, of course, we have OSFI with its demonstrated willingness to short-circuit Pillar 1 on the basis of a panicky ‘phone call, as well as contemptuous opacity towards the concerns of investors (Pillar 3).

Essentially, the position paper aims at a different methodology for calculating Expected Losses (EL) – see Expected Losses and the Assets to Capital Multiple. EL is calculated by the formula

EL = PD * EAD * LGD

where PD = Probability of Default
EAD = Exposure at Default
LGD = Loss Given Default (a percentage)

What C-EBS is aiming at is:

the use of mechanisms that rescale probabilities of default (PDs) estimated by banks, in order to incorporate recessionary conditions.

Currently:

The input to the IRB formula is the annual PD expected to be incurred in that grade (computed as the long-run average of one-year default rates).

As for the LGD, banks are requested to use LGD estimates that are as much as possible estimated for an economic downturn (where these are more conservative than the long-run average).

One problem I see with the approach is there does not appear to be an allowance for the term of the exposure. Would a bank dealing exclusively in mortgages with a 5-year term be expected to use the same recessionary PD as a bank with a portfolio of exclusively 30-year mortgages?

BIS Tweaks Capital Rules

Tuesday, July 14th, 2009

The Bank for International Settlements has tweaked its capital rules, announcing:

At its 8-9 July meeting, the newly expanded Basel Committee on Banking Supervision approved a final package of measures to strengthen the 1996 rules governing trading book capital and to enhance the three pillars of the Basel II framework.

Most of the modifications have to do with securitizations. The document Enhancements to the Basel II framework gives the details; the most interesting – to me! – extracts are:

During the recent market turmoil, several banks that provided LFs to ABCP programmes chose to purchase commercial paper issued by the ABCP conduit instead of having the conduit draw on its LF. The LF provider then risk weighted the ABCP based on the paper’s external rating. As a result, the LF provider benefited from the external rating on the commercial paper when assigning a risk weight to that paper, even though the rating was due in large part to the bank’s own support of the conduit in the form of the LF.

That particular loophole has been plugged!

In a nod to the political needs of the Canadian government, GMD facilities (which became one of the scapegoats for the non-bank ABCP fiasco) have been eliminated:

More specifically, paragraph 580 states that banks may apply a 0% CCF to eligible liquidity facilities that are only available in the event of a general market disruption (ie where more than one SPE across different transactions are unable to roll over maturing commercial paper, and that inability is not the result of an impairment in the SPEs’ credit quality or in the credit quality of the underlying exposures). Paragraph 638 states that an eligible liquidity facility that can only be drawn in the event of a general market disruption is assigned a 20% CCF under the SF. That is, an IRB bank is to recognise 20% of the capital charge generated under the SF for the facility.

The framework has been changed to eliminate paragraphs 580 and 638, in the SA and IRB Approach, respectively. This eliminates any favourable treatment accorded to market disruption liquidity facilities under Basel II.

I asked OSFI if they had any examples of a GMD line causing problems for a bank when the the GMD line was independent of reputational concern. With their customary aplomb, OSFI has declined to answer the question.

The section on Supervision discusses reputational risk:

Reputational risk can be defined as the risk arising from negative perception on the part of customers, counterparties, shareholders, investors, debt-holders, market analysts, other relevant parties or regulators that can adversely affect a bank’s ability to maintain existing, or establish new, business relationships and continued access to sources of funding (eg through the interbank or securitisation markets).

A bank should incorporate the exposures that could give rise to reputational risk into its assessments of whether the requirements under the securitisation framework have been met and the potential adverse impact of providing implicit support.

Reputational risk also arises when a bank sponsors activities such as money market mutual funds, in-house hedge funds and real estate investment trusts (REITs). In these cases, a bank may decide to support the value of shares/units held by investors even though is not contractually required to provide the support.

For instance, to avoid damaging its reputation, a bank may call its liabilities even though this might negatively affect its liquidity profile. This is particularly true for liabilities that are components of regulatory capital, such as hybrid/subordinated debt.

By providing implicit support, a bank signals to the market that all of the risks inherent in the securitised assets are still held by the organisation and, in effect, had not been transferred. Since the risk arising from the potential provision of implicit support is not captured ex ante under Pillar 1, it must be considered as part of the Pillar 2 process.

There are also changes to calculation of market risk for the trading book:

In October 2007, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (the Committee) released guidelines for computing capital for incremental default risk for public comments. At its meeting in March 2008, it reviewed comments received and decided to expand the scope of the capital charge. The decision was taken in light of the recent credit market turmoil where a number of major banking organisations have experienced large losses, most of which were sustained in banks’ trading books. Most of those losses were not captured in the 99%/10-day VaR. Since the losses have not arisen from actual defaults but rather from credit migrations combined with widening of credit spreads and the loss of liquidity, applying an incremental risk charge covering default risk only would not appear adequate. For example, a number of global financial institutions commented that singling out just default risk was inconsistent with their internal practices and could be potentially burdensome.

The incremental risk charge (IRC) is intended to complement additional standards being applied to the value-at-risk modelling framework.

This is a major issue for insurers. Assiduous Readers may recall that one of the issues regarding capital adequacy of insurers is their practice of estimating bond risk without consideration of price; if the rating – or their internal analysis – indicated a 0.1% chance of default, say, that’s what was used for risk purposes, regardless of whether the bond was trading at governments +10bp or governments +500bp. To some extent this is rational; to some extent it ain’t. The question of how forcefully this idea is applied to the investment book of insurers will be a fascinating subject over the next few years.

These BIS tweaks further extend into the calculation of market risks.

OSFI Seeks Comments on P&C Capitalization!

Monday, June 29th, 2009

The Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions has announced:

The Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions and the Canadian P&C insurance industry are working together through the Minimum Capital Test (MCT) Advisory Committee to develop more advanced risk measurement techniques (internal models) for incorporation into the MCT / Branch Adequacy of Assets Test. These techniques will include the development of risk management and disclosure criteria for risk-sensitive methodologies for use by companies that have the commitment and resources to implement them.

The MCT Advisory Committee has developed and proposed a set of high level key principles to guide the development of a new capital framework. Please provide your comments by August 31, 2009.

This is significant. In the past I have harshly criticized OSFI’s lack of consultation. There’s no way of telling at this point whether this is genuine consultation or merely window-dressing, but it is undeniably a step forward.

The Key Principles are, unfortunately, so generic as to be useless. Like, f’rinstance:

Capital requirements should be risk-based.

It’s pretty hard to argue about that!

The section that might prove contentious is:

To allow market discipline, the meaning and methodology for, and the factual disclosure related to, regulatory capital and capital requirements should be transparent.

Assiduous Readers will know of my long-standing complaint about the lack of disclosure of the double-leverage inherent in the holdco/sub structure. The accompanying letter provides information regarding submission of comments:

For comments or questions, please contact Bernard Dupont at (613)990-7797 or bernard.dupont@osfi-bsif.gc.ca or Judith Roberge at (613) 990-4412 or judith.roberge@osfi-bsif.gc.ca.

I suggest that all those with an interest in the preferred shares issued by P&C holdcos (e.g., ELF.PR.F, ELF.PR.G) write in and suggest that ownership of a controlling interest in a P&C operating company be made conditional on the holdco publishing deconsolidated financial statements.

And, with respect to procedure, it will also be worthwhile to suggest that

  • All comments be made public
  • The response of the committee to the comments be published

Exchange Traded CDS

Thursday, May 14th, 2009

Well … it looks like they’re coming. Accrued Interest will be happy.

Treasury today unveiled its new website, with a press release on the previously touted regulation of OTC derivatives:

Promoting Efficiency And Transparency Within The OTC Markets — To ensure regulators would have comprehensive and timely information about the positions of each and every participant in all OTC derivatives markets, this new framework includes: Amending the CEA and securities laws to authorize the CFTC and the SEC to impose:

  • Recordkeeping and reporting requirements (including audit trails).
  • Requirements for all trades not cleared by CCPs to be reported to a regulated trade repository.
  • CCPs and trade repositories must make aggregate data on open positions and trading volumes available to the public.
  • CCPs and trade repositories must make data on individual counterparty’s trades and positions available to federal regulators.
  • The movement of standardized trades onto regulated exchanges and regulated transparent electronic trade execution systems.
  • The development of a system for the timely reporting of trades and prompt dissemination of prices and other trade information.
  • The encouragement of regulated institutions to make greater use of regulated exchange-traded derivatives.

Credit Default Swaps are not mentioned specifically in the press release, but clearly fall under the heading of “OTC Derivatives” and “standardized trades” … at least, the plain-vanilla ones do.

I think it’s a mistake. OTC markets reward those with a vague idea of what they’re doing; the transparency of an exchange gives incompetent advisors a free ride. On the bright side, it will at least dampen the endless whining for centralized bond exchanges that accompany every discussion of bond market reform … once Joe Retail sees that, for instance, a CDS on CM at 500bp with an end-date of April 10, 2013 traded 2 contracts last month and are quoted at a 200bp spread, perhaps he won’t feel so hard done by when looking at dealer quotes for his $5,000 lot.

No argument is presented in favour of the idea. The closest approach is the opening paragraph:

As the AIG situation has made clear, massive risks in derivatives markets have gone undetected by both regulators and market participants. But even if those risks had been better known, regulators lacked the proper authorities to mount an effective policy response.

… which, as I’m sure Geithner knows perfectly well is totally ficticious. It would have been the easiest thing in the world for the Fed to have altered bank capitalization rules (and for the SEC to have altered broker capitalization rules) to have required more margin (or capital charges in lieu thereof) for swaps.

In which case, AIG’s ability to sell uncollateralized protection to the financial system behemoths would have been sharply curtailed, and direct damage limited to non-regulated entitites. However, this would involve regulators ‘fessing up to inadequacy, which ain’t gonna happen.

ABCP: Accumulate Bank of Canada Power!

Wednesday, May 6th, 2009

The Canadian Press reports that Mark Carney has proposed yet another regulator (while, I suspect, coughing and pointing at himself):

The central bank governor told a Senate committee that the country’s regulatory fiefdoms need a new mechanism to ensure individual financial watchdogs do not have blinders on that prevents them from seeing the bigger picture.

Carney said the central bank had warned years in advance about the risks involved with the $32-billion non-bank asset-backed commercial paper market, but its cautions were ignored.

“We view ourselves as having an advocacy role identifying problems and making them known,” he said.

“The advice has not always been followed, and in some cases problems have been repeatedly identified.

“In one case, the issue was really the only serious capital market problem we have had in this crisis (and) had been identified by the bank some years in advance.”

Carney’s argument for what he called a new “mechanism” that would require individual regulators to consider the wider implications of their actions came at the conclusion of a two-hour hearing with the Senate banking committee.

Unfortunately, there is no mention of such a thing in the Official Opening Remarks.

Let’s recapitulate, shall we?

The seeds of the ABCP fiasco were sown long ago, when OSFI required that banks put up capital for undrawn, guaranteed lines of credit (“Global Liquidity”). They did not require capital for undrawn vague committments, such as the General Market Disruption clause. I consider this to have been an entirely prudent ruling. For this reason, the ABCP market in Canada relied on GMD agreements, since Global Liquidity cost too much extra.

In the States, the Fed did not require capital for Global Liquidity; since it did not require capital it was cheap; since it was cheap that’s what ABCP issuers chose.

Later, the Fed changed their rules to be more consistent with the Canadian approach. At that time, the US ABCP market was sufficiently well-established that the extra costs were absorbed. Canadian issuers did not change their ways because there was no point: there would have been extra costs for whoever went first with no competitive advantage.

In 2003 the Bank of Canada published a warning about ABCP – well done BoC and I hope Paula Toovey and John Kiff get bonuses!

By 2007, the market was a little bit rigged: an enormous fraction of outstanding Canadian ABCP was held by accounts controlled/advised by entities that also had ownership interests in producers. There has never been a satisfactory explanation – public and satisfactory to me, anyway – of whether the portfolio managers responsible for the accounts holding the paper were motivated solely by concerns about the best interests of the accounts they were managing.

In mid/late 2007 the market collapsed. It became apparent that there were many holders of ABCP who were enormously concentrated in the asset class, if not a single name within that asset class. As far as I know, not a single PM has lost his license due to over-concentration. The regulatory response has concentrated on investment suitability, which I don’t understand at all. Even with hindsight, I consider non-Bank Canadian ABCP to be a suitable money-market investment that, unfortunately went bad. Please note that the word “suitable” means “on the list”. It means “sure, consider this stuff for inclusion in a diversified portfolio”. It does not mean “back up the trucks, guys, and load up 100% in this paper”. If that’s what the word “suitable” meant, NOTHING would be “suitable”.

I have not yet heard of anybody losing their license – or even being charged – for concentration risk.

Some people got burned and got burned badly, sure. That’s what happens when you load up on a single sure-fire can’t-miss investment. The only systemic implications I have seen is that some financial institutions were forced for reputational reasons to take the defaulted paper onto their books at par, without this reputational risk having been accounted for as part the financial institutions’ capital requirements.

This reputational risk needs to be addressed in Basel 3, if not sooner. As I have urged, for instance, the assets held by bank-sponsored money market funds should be included in Risk-Weighted Assets for capital calculation purposes. I have not yet heard any argument as to why such a course of action is not both necessary and sufficient.

IIROC Publishes Proposed Retail Bond Rules

Friday, April 17th, 2009

The Investment Industry Regulatory Organization of Canada has announced:

a proposed rule and guidance note to address fair pricing of over-the-counter (OTC) traded securities including fixed income securities such as bonds. The proposal would amend existing trade confirmation requirements by mandating yield disclosure for fixed income securities. It will require firms to disclose on confirmations sent to retail clients for OTC transactions if the dealer’s remuneration has been added to the price in the case of a purchase or deducted in the case of a sale. The general purpose of these proposed amendments is to enhance the fairness of pricing and transparency of OTC market transactions.

The text of the proposed rule states that, generally speaking:

the proposed amendments will:
• Require Dealer Members to fairly and reasonably price securities traded in OTC markets;
• Require Dealer Members to disclose yield to maturity on trade confirmations for fixed-income securities and notations for callable and variable rate securities; and
• Require Dealer Members to include on trade confirmations sent to retail clients in respect of OTC transactions a statement indicating that they have earned remuneration on those transactions unless the amount of any mark-up or mark-down, commissions and other service charges is disclosed on the confirmation.

These are rules only a regulator could love. They note, for instance, that:

the pricing mechanisms used for fixed income securities are less understood by retail clients. Specifically, retail clients may not understand the inverse relationship between price and yield or the various factors that can affect yield calculations and the relative risk of a particular fixed income security. All these factors contribute to the difficulty retail investors are faced with when determining whether a particular fixed income security is fairly priced (and therefore offers an appropriate yield) and of appropriate risk. IIROC therefore wishes to underscore the responsibility of Dealer Member firms to use their professional judgment and market expertise to diligently ascertain and provide fair prices to clients in all circumstances, particularly in situations where the Dealer Member must determine inferred market price because the most recent market price does not accurately reflect market value of that security.

If a client does not understand the inverse relationship between price and yield, THE CLIENT SHOULD NOT BE BUYING BONDS. Full stop.

The underlying purpose of the rules may be deduced from:

Market regulators’ surveillance of fixed income market activity will provide the tools to monitor for patterns and trends in prices and will allow regulators to more effectively identify price outliers. IIROC is currently considering how best to implement such a system to monitor our Dealer Members’ OTC security (both fixed income and equity) trading, which would allow IIROC to identify circumstances where trade prices do not correspond with the prevailing market at that time.

In other words, somebody at IIROC wants to expand his empire. Or, maybe, has looked at his career prospects and decided that a good future job title would be “Compliance Manager, Retail Bond Desk, Very Big Brokerage Inc.”

Rules 2 (Yield disclosure) and 3 (Compensation disclosure) are derisory; the latter simply requires a statement that the dealer is making money (or hoping to, anyway), something that most people are able to deduce from the fact that the confirmations already state that it’s a principal transaction.

Rule 1, however, is more complex. IIROC has drafted a Guidance Note:

When executing an OTC trade as agent for a customer, a Dealer Member will have to use diligence to ascertain a fair price. For example, in the context of an illiquid security this “reasonable efforts” requirement may require the Dealer Member to canvass various parties to source the availability and the price of the specific security. Passive acceptance of the first price quoted to a Dealer Member executing an agency transaction will not be sufficient.

This will kill the market, such as it is. Why would they bother, when they can just say “No offer” or “No bid”? If they do bother, and they do go through this canvassing process, and they do charge a fair price for their efforts, is the price still going to be halfway reasonable? I doubt it.

Most insidiously:

It is important to note that the fair pricing responsibility of Dealer Members requires attention both to the market value of the security as well as to the reasonableness of compensation. Excessive commissions, mark-ups or mark-downs obviously may cause a violation of the fair pricing standards described above. However, it is also possible for a Dealer Member to restrict its profit on transactions to reasonable levels and still violate the Rule because of inattention to market value. For example, a Dealer Member may fail to assess the market value of a security when acquiring it from another dealer or customer and in consequence may pay a price well above market value. It would be a violation of fair pricing responsibilities for the Dealer Member to pass on this misjudgment to another customer, as either principal or agent, even if the Dealer Member makes little or no profit on the trade.

So, in other words, you could make a good faith misjudgement of a market price – such as, for instance, a bond market professional makes all the time – and be subject to regulatory action. Not to mention being liable (forever) for the difference between the price at which you offset the client transaction and the price some regulator decides is fair.

Just in case there are some people out their with the belief that these rules might actually result in a net improvement to the retail bond market:

IIROC expects Dealer Members to maintain adequate documentation to support the pricing of OTC securities transactions. In most instances, existing transactions records, including audio recordings, will allow Dealer Members to reconstruct the basis on which an OTC transaction price was determined to be fair, and will therefore suffice for purposes of supporting the fairness of a transaction. IIROC anticipates that hard-to-value transactions, are likely to require additional supporting documentation. Proper documentation of such transactions may be the subject of IIROC trading reviews, and the failure to maintain documentation to support the fairness of pricing of hard-to-value transactions will be a consideration in any potential enforcement actions.

It is rather sweet that IIROC believes we can reach a Nirvana through imposition of more rules, but all this stuff simply betrays total lack of comprehension of how the bond market – retail or institutional – works. These rules are the product of people who have never in their lives got on the ‘phone in a cold sweat and said “Done”; it is the product of people who believe they know everything on the basis of their two-year Ryerson certificate in Boxtickingology.

My brief remarks when the gist of the rules was leaked on April 14 attracted comments, both on the post and in my eMail. One Assiduous Reader writes in and says:

I have a similar observation over the few years for bond with short maturity (1 – 5 years). Could you explain some of the factors why retail brokerages seem to be offering a better deal on GIC? Is the difference between a retail bond offering and a GIC the cost of “liquidity” (ability to sell before maturity) and the markup by the brokerage?

GICs are completely easy for the brokerages to offer. They get a feed from the issuer showing the rates, they can offer all they like at those rates in any wierd quantity desired, they get a commission, click, bang, done. A little bit of profit, no market exposure at any time for the brokerage, and the so-called trader can be any eighteen year old teller with the requisite CSI course.

Best of all, when the issuer runs into difficulties and gets its name in the headlines, they don’t have to deal with thousands of desperate, angry, confused clients who don’t understand why the brokerage doesn’t want to buy back every single piece of paper they’ve ever sold at the original price.

There has also been some discussion on Financial WebRing:

On the other hand, we require all sorts of disclosures for mutual fund investors, presumably targeted at unsophisticated investors. If that holds for mutual funds, why not for bonds?

Because mutual funds are sold on the basis that you are hiring somebody – and paying them – to exercise their best efforts. Bonds are sold on the basis that you don’t want to pay exhorbitant management fees on something so simple as bonds, and are therefore buying them yourself as principal and saving all kinds of money, yay!

Definitely agree that bonds should be on more of a transparent exchange than presently. If more complicated forms of debt such as pref shares and debentures can be exchange-traded, why not plain and simple bonds?

Because there are thousands and thousands and thousands of bonds, all but a few of which trade by appointment only. I don’t want to pay listing fees for something that’s going to trade three times a year; you can if you like.

Update: I was quoted by Bloomberg:

“The net effect of these proposed rules will be to decrease the choice of retail offerings even further,” said James Hymas, a fixed-income and preferred-share specialist at Hymas Investment Management Inc. in Toronto. “There’s a lot of overhead for the brokers. They may simply choose to limit the number of offerings they make.”

Fed Postpones Tightening of Bank Capital Quality Rules

Tuesday, March 17th, 2009

The Fed has announced:

the adoption of a final rule that delays until March 31, 2011, the effective date of new limits on the inclusion of trust preferred securities and other restricted core capital elements in tier 1 capital of bank holding companies (BHCs).

The final rule explains:

Under limits on restricted core capital elements that are currently in effect, a BHC generally may include in tier 1 capital cumulative perpetual preferred stock and trust preferred securities up to 25 percent of the sum of core capital elements (including cumulative perpetual preferred stock and trust preferred securities). The new limits would limit restricted core capital elements includable in the tier 1 capital of a BHC to 25 percent of the sum of core capital elements (including restricted core capital elements), net of goodwill less any associated deferred tax liability. In addition, internationally active BHCs would be subject to a further limitation.

In particular, the amount of restricted core capital elements (other than qualifying mandatory convertible preferred securities) that an internationally active BHC could include in tier 1 capital could not exceed 15 percent of the sum of core capital elements (including restricted core capital elements), net of goodwill less any associated deferred tax liability.

In light of conditions in the capital markets, the Board has considered whether an additional extension of the effective date of the new limits is appropriate. The economic conditions for the past 18 months, and currently, have created a situation in which requiring adherence to the new limits by the March 31, 2009, effective date creates a substantial burden for many BHCs in a way that was not anticipated when the final rule was adopted in 2005. In the prevailing market conditions, it is especially important for BHCs to expend efforts to increase their overall capital levels, although it is challenging to do so now through retention of earnings, the most typical means. Therefore, to promote stability in the financial markets and the banking industry as a whole, the Board has decided to further delay the effective date of the new limits until March 31, 2011. The Board believes that this extended transition period would allow affected BHCs sufficient flexibility to satisfy the Board’s risk-based and leverage capital guidelines during the current stressed market conditions.

BIS Discusses Bank Capital & Deposit Insurance

Friday, March 13th, 2009

The Bank for International Settlements has announced (via the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision):

that the level of capital in the banking system needs to be strengthened to raise its resilience to future episodes of economic and financial stress. This will be achieved by a combination of measures such as introducing standards to promote the build up of capital buffers that can be drawn down in periods of stress, strengthening the quality of bank capital, improving the risk coverage of the capital framework and introducing a non-risk based supplementary measure. Also, the regulatory minimum level of capital will be reviewed in 2010, taking into account the above and other relevant factors to arrive at a total level and quality of capital that is higher than the current Basel II framework. Strengthening the global capital framework in this manner will enhance confidence and lay the foundation for a more resilient banking system.

The Committee notes that current reactions in the market place regarding capital levels have been highly procyclical. It will not increase global minimum capital requirements during this period of economic and financial stress. Indeed, the Committee has earlier stated that capital buffers above the regulatory minimum are designed to absorb losses and support continued lending to the economy.

We can hope that OSFI signs on to the bit about increasing bank capital quality! The important issue being discussed is the “build up of capital buffers” – one of the issues in the current crisis is that bank capital as currently defined may be all very well and good in terms of protecting depositors when a bank is wound-up, but doesn’t help too much when a bank gets into trouble and needs to recapitalize. A system of surcharges based on asset growth would go a long way towards fixing this problem.

I will bet a nickel that the “non-risk based supplementary measure” is the leverage ratio (US nomenclature) / Assets-to-Capital Multiple (Canadian nomenclature).

I am very disappointed that there is no mention of the influence of bank size. A Megabank has so many layers of management that the Board’s Risk Committee – comprised, generally, of people who are appointed for their gender and/or connections, nothing to do with ability – has many, many layers of self-interested subordinates between it and the guts of the matter.

Their other announcement is a joint paper with the International Association of Deposit Insurers. The consultative document is open for comments – hear that, OSFI? Comments from affected parties! How revolutionary! – until May 15. I suspect that debate between Iceland and the UK will be highly entertaining, as briefly review on Guy Fawkes’ Day.

Update: I also note a recent speech by David Longworth, Deputy Governor of the Bank of Canada:

Now, the assumption that most market participants use the same risk-management systems based on short historical samples is very much an exaggeration. Some researchers, however, have argued that enough institutions follow very similar risk-management systems that the dynamics described above can happen, and indeed have happened, in the real world in response to sizable shocks.14 Moreover, in its Global Financial Stability Report issued in the second half of 2007, the International Monetary Fund concluded – based on simulations it carried out, which seemed realistic based on observed risk-management practices – that “seemingly prudent behavior by individual firms, reacting to similar market-risk systems, could serve to amplify market volatility in periods of stress beyond what would otherwise have occurred.”15 Observations and anecdotal information following the failure of Lehman Brothers suggest that this behaviour of firms was very important in amplifying price volatility in the autumn of 2008. Analysis of such behaviour strongly suggests the need for a macroprudential approach.

[Footnotes]14. See A. Persaud (previous footnote) and the Committee on the Global Financial System, “A Review of Financial Market Events in Autumn 1998” (CGFS Publications No.12, Bank for International Settlements, 1999). This latter text has a section (see page 14) on the over-reliance on quantitative tools.

15. International Monetary Fund, “Do Market Risk Management Techniques Amplify Systemic Risks?” in Global Financial Stability Report October 2007, 52-76.

Cliff risk due to similarity of trading techniques (that is, the “best practices” so beloved of bureaucracies) were last discussed on PrefBlog on March 12. It has been a worry for BoC for a long time.

Back to David Longworth:

Two main principles have been proposed. The first is that, in parallel with the probability of default on credit exposures on the banking book being calculated on a “through-the-cycle” basis, VaR for the trading book also be calculated on a through-the-cycle basis. One implication of this principle is that all historical data should be exploited to calculate the distribution of possible losses for a given asset or asset class. The second principle is that a “stress VaR” – a VaR calculated on the basis of assumed stress conditions – should be used, especially to consider the heightened correlation of losses across various assets or asset classes. It is well known that correlations among losses in categories of risky assets increase dramatically (sometimes approaching one), when the financial system is under great stress.

I have problems with the “through the cycle” approach. It throws out a lot of data; and should a firm become insolvent it doesn’t mean a lot to say ‘well, we’re solvent through the cycle, so trust me!’ There is a reason for cycles; recessions are nature’s way of telling us we’re doing something wrong. The problem should be attacked from the other end, focussing on capital.

The “stress VaR” is nothing more nor less than common sense.

Bernanke Opines on Financial Regulation

Tuesday, March 10th, 2009

Bernanke made an important speech today on the future of financial regulation:

The global imbalances were the joint responsibility of the United States and our trading partners, and although the topic was a perennial one at international conferences, we collectively did not do enough to reduce those imbalances. However, the responsibility to use the resulting capital inflows effectively fell primarily on the receiving countries, particularly the United States. The details of the story are complex, but, broadly speaking, the risk-management systems of the private sector and government oversight of the financial sector in the United States and some other industrial countries failed to ensure that the inrush of capital was prudently invested, a failure that has led to a powerful reversal in investor sentiment and a seizing up of credit markets. In certain respects, our experience parallels that of some emerging-market countries in the 1990s, whose financial sectors and regulatory regimes likewise proved inadequate for efficiently investing large inflows of saving from abroad.

I’ll buy it … but he’s skating around the responsibility of the Fed. If, in fact, there was a lack of prudence in the investment of capital, the implication is that monetary policy was too loose. It also implies fiscal policy was too loose.

Looking to the future, however, it is imperative that policymakers address this issue by better supervising systemically critical firms to prevent excessive risk-taking and by strengthening the resilience of the financial system to minimize the consequences when a large firm must be unwound.

Achieving more effective supervision of large and complex financial firms will require a number of actions. First, supervisors need to move vigorously–as we are already doing–to address the weaknesses at major financial institutions in capital adequacy, liquidity management, and risk management that have been revealed by the crisis. In particular, policymakers must insist that the large financial firms that they supervise be capable of monitoring and managing their risks in a timely manner and on an enterprise-wide basis. In that regard, the Federal Reserve has been looking carefully at risk-management practices at systemically important institutions to identify best practices, assess firms’ performance, and require improvement where deficiencies are identified. Any firm whose failure would pose a systemic risk must receive especially close supervisory oversight of its risk-taking, risk management, and financial condition, and be held to high capital and liquidity standards.[footnote]

Footnote:Such an approach would also help offset the incentives for financial firms to become too big to fail.

This is good, and I am particularly encourage by the reference to high capital standards and offsetting the incentives for financial firms to become too big to fail. I have argued before – and I will argue again – that there should be a sliding scale of regulatory charges to capital based on size; and to prevent games-playing this should be calculated as an increment to Risk-Weighted-Assets. If, for example, a factor of (Lesser of (a) 1.0, or (b) pre-increment RWA / $250-billion) were to be applied to RWA, then any firm growing beyond $250-billion in RWA will find itself needing more and more capital to operate; smaller, regional, banks will be in the sweet spot.

Second, we must ensure a robust framework–both in law and practice–for consolidated supervision of all systemically important financial firms organized as holding companies. The consolidated supervisors must have clear authority to monitor and address safety and soundness concerns in all parts of the organization, not just the holding company. Broad-based application of the principle of consolidated supervision would also serve to eliminate gaps in oversight that would otherwise allow risk-taking to migrate from more-regulated to less-regulated sectors.

He’s still angry about AIG, as mentioned on March 3.

Third, looking beyond the current crisis, the United States also needs improved tools to allow the orderly resolution of a systemically important nonbank financial firm, including a mechanism to cover the costs of the resolution.

I’m not such a big fan of this point. With all the best intentions, it will create a Regulator of Everything. His primary example is the jawboning by the New York Fed – led by his former underling and current boss – on CDS clearinghouses, which may well be a good solution, but should not be a mandated solution. The mandated solution should be realistic capital charges for exposure and concentration; let the private sector determine whether the overhead of a central clearinghouse is worthwhile.

In light of the importance of money market mutual funds–and, in particular, the crucial role they play in the commercial paper market, a key source of funding for many businesses–policymakers should consider how to increase the resiliency of those funds that are susceptible to runs. One approach would be to impose tighter restrictions on the instruments in which money market mutual funds can invest, potentially requiring shorter maturities and increased liquidity. A second approach would be to develop a limited system of insurance for money market mutual funds that seek to maintain a stable net asset value. For either of these approaches or others, it would be important to consider the implications not only for the money market mutual fund industry itself, but also for the distribution of liquidity and risk in the financial system as a whole.

“Money Market Fund” is a term defined in Ontario securities law and I’ll assume the situation is similar in the states. It should be a simple matter to bring MMFs under the supervision of bank regulators so that they are regulated as banks, and required to have (and to disclose regularly) the usual amounts of Tier 1 and Total Capital.

Because banks typically find raising capital to be difficult in economic downturns or periods of financial stress, their best means of boosting their regulatory capital ratios during difficult periods may be to reduce new lending, perhaps more so than is justified by the credit environment. We should review capital regulations to ensure that they are appropriately forward-looking, and that capital is allowed to serve its intended role as a buffer–one built up during good times and drawn down during bad times in a manner consistent with safety and soundness.

I couldn’t agree more. Higher capital charges for new – or expanded – relationships should be implemented. Or, perhaps, just apply a surcharge for year-over-year increases in (Risk Weighted) assets.

How could macroprudential policies be better integrated into the regulatory and supervisory system? One way would be for the Congress to direct and empower a governmental authority to monitor, assess, and, if necessary, address potential systemic risks within the financial system. The elements of such an authority’s mission could include, for example, (1) monitoring large or rapidly increasing exposures–such as to subprime mortgages–across firms and markets, rather than only at the level of individual firms or sectors; (2) assessing the potential for deficiencies in evolving risk-management practices, broad-based increases in financial leverage, or changes in financial markets or products to increase systemic risks; (3) analyzing possible spillovers between financial firms or between firms and markets, such as the mutual exposures of highly interconnected firms; and (4) identifying possible regulatory gaps, including gaps in the protection of consumers and investors, that pose risks for the system as a whole. Two areas of natural focus for a systemic risk authority would be the stability of systemically critical financial institutions and the systemically relevant aspects of the financial infrastructure that I discussed earlier.

I wonder if at this point in the speech he was coughing theatrically and pointing at himself?

Some commentators have proposed that the Federal Reserve take on the role of systemic risk authority; others have expressed concern that adding this responsibility would overburden the central bank. The extent to which this new responsibility might be a good match for the Federal Reserve depends a great deal on precisely how the Congress defines the role and responsibilities of the authority, as well as on how the necessary resources and expertise complement those employed by the Federal Reserve in the pursuit of its long-established core missions.

It seems to me that we should keep our minds open on these questions. We have been discussing them a good deal within the Federal Reserve System, and their importance warrants careful consideration by legislators and other policymakers. As a practical matter, however, effectively identifying and addressing systemic risks would seem to require the involvement of the Federal Reserve in some capacity, even if not in the lead role.

* cough, cough *

Financial crises will continue to occur, as they have around the world for literally hundreds of years. Even with the sorts of actions I have outlined here today, it is unrealistic to hope that financial crises can be entirely eliminated, especially while maintaining a dynamic and innovative financial system. Nonetheless, these steps should help make crises less frequent and less virulent, and so contribute to a better functioning national and global economy.

Thank you, Mr. Bernanke! Expectations of a New Millennium of Bank Regulation are far too high at the moment. Shit happens. Get used to it.