Archive for October, 2009

Contingent Capital: Blinder Supports Squam Lake Model

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

Alan S. Blinder, the Gordon S. Rentschler Memorial Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Princeton University and former Vice-Chairman of the Fed’s Board of Governors, gave a wonderfully informative and chatty speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston conference at Chatham, Massachussets, on October 23, 2009 titled
It’s Broke, Let’s Fix It: Rethinking Financial Regulation.

One quote I simply must highlight is:

After all, regulatory failure on a grand scale was one major cause of the mess.

However, at the moment I am more interested in his thoughts on Contingent Capital than anything else:

I myself am attracted to a particular idea for “contingent capital” suggested recently by the Squam Lake Working Group on Financial Regulation, an ad hoc panel of academic experts. Under the proposal, regulators would have the power, by declaring a systemic crisis, Their idea, which derives from Mark Flannery’s (2005) clever earlier proposal for “reverse convertible debentures,” is to require certain banks to issue a novel type of convertible bond. Conventional convertible debt gets exchanged for equity at the option of the bondholder; and because this option has value, convertible debt bears lower interest rates than ordinary debt. The proposed new form of convertible debt would reverse the optionality by giving it to the regulators instead.

Under the proposal, regulators would have the power, by declaring a systemic crisis, to force holders of these special convertibles (but not holders of other debt instruments) to convert to equity. As in many cases, one key question is price—specifically, how large an interest rate premium would investors demand to cover the risk that their bonds could be converted into equity against their will? If this premium proved to be very large, these new convertibles would be a very expensive form of “capital” that banks might shun, preferring ordinary equity instead. Only experience will tell. —thus giving banks more equity capital (and less debt) just when they need it most. Naturally, the existence of such an option would detract from the value of the bond and therefore would make the interest rate on reverse convertibles higher than on ordinary debt. Indeed, if the requirement was limited to TBTF institutions, as seems appropriate, that higher interest rate on a fraction of their debt would constitute a natural penalty cost for being TBTF. Furthermore, the spread on this new type of debt over regular debt could become a useful market indicator of the likelihood of a systemic crisis.

As in many cases, one key question is price—specifically, how large an interest rate premium would investors demand to cover the risk that their bonds could be converted into equity against their will? If this premium proved to be very large, these new convertibles would be a very expensive form of “capital” that banks might shun, preferring ordinary equity instead. Only experience will tell.

I have previously discussed the Squam Lake proposals, as well as the original Flannery paper; I think they need a little work. My major objections are that:

  • It mixes book value with market value; theoretically suspect and leading in times of stress to unpredictable – probably procyclical – results, and
  • by incorporating regulatory discretion into the conversion trigger, it unnecessarily introduces regulatory uncertainty into the evaluation of the investment, as well as encouraging regulatory capture and even corruption.

He breaks my heart by advocating credit ratings by government agencies:

But many observers think the fundamental problem lies deeper: with the issuer-pays model. As long as rating agencies are for-profit companies, paid by the issuers of the securities they rate, the agencies will have a natural tendency to try to please their customers—just as any business does. Unfortunately, the most obvious alternative, switching to an investors-pay model, is probably infeasible except in markets with very few investors. Otherwise, information flows too readily, and everyone wants to free ride. What to do? The way out of this dilemma, it seems to me, is to arrange for some sort of third-party payment. The government (e.g., the SEC) or an organized exchange or clearinghouse seem to be the natural alternative payers. In either case, they could raise the necessary funds by levying a user-fee on all issuers.

He also discusses the separation of prop trading from vanilla banking:

For example, the Group of Thirty (2009, p. 28)—hardly a bunch of wild-eyed radicals–recently concluded that, “Large, systemically important banking institutions should be restricted in undertaking proprietary activities that present particularly high risks…and large proprietary trading should be limited by strict capital and liquidity requirements.” That’s not quite a ban, but it’s getting close.

But there is a downside. Roping off “proprietary trading” from other, closely-related activities of banks is not as easy as it sounds. For example, banks buy and sell securities, foreign exchange, and other assets for their clients all the time. Often, such buying and selling is imperfectly synchronized or leaves banks with open positions for other reasons. Does that constitute “proprietary trading”? Furthermore, market-making has obvious synergies with dealing on behalf of clients. Do we want to label all such activities as “proprietary trading”? The point is: There is no bright line. That is why Adair Turner (2009), the chairman of Britain’s FSA, concluded that “we could not proceed by a binary legal distinction—banks can do this but not that—but had to focus on the scale of position-taking and the capital held against position-taking.”

I say – yes. we do want to label all such activities as “proprietary trading”; and the fact that there is no bright line is just something we’ll have to get used to. As previously urged on PrefBlog, I suggest that there be two regulatory regimes – for investment banks and vanilla banks, the former imposing relatively heavier capital charges on long term positions, the latter imposing relatively heavier charges on short term positions. It won’t be perfect, by any stretch of the imagination; but it will allow each type of institutions to make decisions on a tactical basis, according to their marginal value.

One of the things that brought down the investment banks was that they engaged in buy-and-hold strategies, which are more properly the province of vanilla banks, which have (or should have!) the expertise and controls in place to look beyond the next portfolio flip.

Best & Worst Performers: October, 2009

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

These are total returns, with dividends presumed to have been reinvested at the bid price on the ex-date. The list has been restricted to issues in the HIMIPref™ indices.

October 2009
Issue Index DBRS Rating Monthly Performance Notes (“Now” means “October 30”)
BAM.PR.G FixFloat Pfd-2(low) -10.41%
PWF.PR.K PerpetualDiscount Pfd-1(low) -5.87% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.27% based on a bid of 19.89 and a limitMaturity.
ELF.PR.F PerpetualDiscount Pfd-2(low) -5.86% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.02% based on a bid of 19.10 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.W PerpetualDiscount Pfd-1(low) -5.64% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.83% based on a bid of 21.07 and a limitMaturity.
PWF.PR.L PerpetualDiscount Pfd-1(low) -5.57% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.14% based on a bid of 20.91 and a limitMaturity.
TRP.PR.A FixedReset Pfd-2(low) +1.56% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.39% based on a bid of 25.37 and a call 2015-01-30 at 25.00.
BMO.PR.P FixedReset Pfd-1(low) +1.59% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.34% based on a bid of 26.77 and a call 2015-3-27 at 25.00.
MFC.PR.A OpRet Pfd-1(low) +1.75% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 3.36% based on a bid of 26.16 and a softMaturity 2015-12-18 at 25.00.
IAG.PR.C FixedReset Pfd-2(high) +1.96% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.28% based on a bid of 27.01 and a call 2014-1-30 at 25.00.
NA.PR.N FixedReset Pfd-2 +2.42% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 3.79% based on a bid of 26.35 and a call 2013-9-14 at 25.00.

There were no repeaters from the September list, which is rather unusual – there’s usually some rebounding, but not this time.

Contingent Capital: Squam Lake Working Group

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

The papers of the Squam Lake Working Group , a very distinguished group of academics, are published by the Council on Foreign Relations (which seems rather strange, but there you go), who also publish the periodical Foreign Affairs, which I love but don’t have time to read any more.

The Squam Lake paper titled An Expedited Resolution Mechanism for Distressed Financial Firms: Regulatory Hybrid Securities is of great interest, albeit lamentably short on detail.

Most notably, they propose a double trigger for conversion:

A bank’s hybrid securities should convert from debt to equity only if two conditions are met. The first requirement is a declaration by regulators that the financial system is suffering from a systemic crisis. The second is a violation by the bank of covenants in the hybrid-security contract.

This double trigger is important for two reasons. First, debt is valuable in a bank’s capital structure because it provides an important disciplining force for management. The possibility that the hybrid security will conveniently morph from debt to equity whenever the bank suffers significant losses would undermine this productive discipline. If conversion is limited to only systemic crises, the hybrid security will provide the same benefit as debt in all but the most extreme periods.

Second, the bank-specific component of the trigger is also important. If conversion were triggered solely by the declaration of a systemic crisis, regulators would face enormous political pressure when deciding whether to make such a declaration. Replacing regulatory discretion with an objective criterion creates more problems because the aggregate data regulators might use for such a trigger are likely to be imprecise, subject to revisions, and measured with time lags. And, perhaps most important, if conversion depended on only a systemic trigger, even sound banks would be forced to convert in a crisis. This would dull the incentive for these banks to remain sound.

I don’t like the first trigger, the declaration by regulators that a systemic crisis exists. First, there is more than one regulator, which will lead, at the very least, to delays while simultaneous announcements are arranged and, at worst, to political kerfuffles regarding cross-border banks if there is no widespread agreement.

Secondly, it introduces an element of political uncertainty regarding conversion, which will lead to the political pressure they allude to in their discussion of the second trigger.

Thirdly, I just plain don’t trust the regulators.

It will be noted that the group skims rather lightly over the justification for the first trigger!

The group also suggests using Tier 1 Capital Ratios as a trigger:

What sort of covenant would make sense for the bank-specific trigger? One possibility, which we find appealing, would be based on the measures used to determine a bank’s capital adequacy, such as the ratio of Tier 1 capital to risk-adjusted assets.

I don’t like it, for reasons which have been discussed in my posts Contingent Capital: Reverse Convertible Debentures and Lloyds bank to Issue Contingent Capital with Tier 1 Ratio Trigger?. Tier 1 ratios are too easy for a bank and regulators to manipulate, do not measure the degree of investor confidence in an institution and do not provide a framework for market arbitrage. As a bank’s situation deteriorates, the price response of the hybrid should gradually become more-and-more equity-like, which suggests a market based approach rather than the binary now-it’s-debt-now-it’s-equity paradigm implied by an all-or-nothing conversion based on calculated figures. I have not seen anything yet to shake my belief that a fixed-rate conversion with a trigger based on the trading price of the common is the best solution.

The authors discuss the conversion rate:

In addition to the triggers, this new instrument will have to specify the rate at which the debt converts into equity. The conversion rate might depend, for example, on the market value of equity or on the market value of both equity and the hybrid security. Conversions based on market values, however, can create opportunities for manipulation. Bondholders might try to push the stock price down by shorting the stock, for example, so they would receive a larger slice of the equity in the conversion. Using the average stock price over a longer period, such as the past twenty days, to measure the value of equity makes this manipulation more difficult, but it opens the door for another manipulation. If the stock price falls precipitously during a systemic crisis, management might intentionally violate the trigger and force conversion at a stale price that now looks good to the stockholders. Finally, in some circumstances, a conversion ratio that depends on the stock price can lead to a “death spiral,” in which the dilution of the existing stockholders’ claims that would occur in a conversion lowers the stock price, which leads to more dilution, which lowers the price even further.

An alternative approach is to convert each dollar of debt into a fixed quantity of equity shares, rather than a fixed value of equity. There are at least two advantages of such an approach. First, because the number of shares to be issued in a conversion is fixed, death spirals are not a problem. Second, although management might consider triggering conversion (for example, by acquiring a large number of risky assets) to avoid a required interest or principal payment on the debt, this would not be optimal unless the stock price were so low that the shares to be issued were worth less than the bond payment. Thus, management would want to intentionally induce conversion only when the bank is struggling. The advantages and disadvantages of different conversion schemes are complicated, however, and will require both further study and detailed input from the financial and regulatory community.

It seems that they believe that a problem with the conversion at a fixed rate is the potential for manipulation of the trigger terms by management. This would be avoided with a market-based trigger.

Contingent Capital: Reverse Convertible Debentures

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

Mark J. Flannery Bank of America Eminent Scholar Chair of Finance at the University of Florida proposed Reverse Convertible Debentures in 2002 in his paper No Pain, No Gain? Effecting Market Discipline via “Reverse Convertible Debentures”:

The deadweight costs of financial distress limit many firms’ incentive to include a lot of (taxadvantaged) debt in their capital structures. It is therefore puzzling that firms do not make advance arrangements to re-capitalize themselves if large losses occur. Financial distress may be particularly important for large banking firms, which national supervisors are reluctant to let fail. The supervisors’ inclination to support large financial firms when they become troubled mitigates the ex ante incentives of market investors to discipline these firms. This paper proposes a new financial instrument that forestalls financial distress without distorting bank shareholders’ risk-taking incentives. “Reverse convertible debentures” (RCD) would automatically convert to common equity if a bank’s market capital ratio falls below some stated value. RCD provide a transparent mechanism for un-levering a firm if the need arises. Unlike conventional convertible bonds, RCD convert at the stock’s current market price, which forces shareholders to bear the full cost of their risk-taking decisions. Surprisingly, RCD investors are exposed to very limited credit risk under plausible conditions.

Of interest is the example of some Manny-Hanny bonds:

The case of Manufacturers Hanover (MH) in 1990 illustrates the problem. The bank had issued $85 million dollars worth of “mandatory preferred stock,” which was scheduled to convert to common shares in 1993. An earlier conversion would be triggered if MH’s share price closed below $16 for 12 out of 15 consecutive trading days (Hilder [1990]). Such forced conversion appeared possible in December 1990. In a letter to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York concerning the bank’s capital situation, MH’s CFO (Peter J. Tobin) expresses the bank’s extreme reluctance to permit conversion, or to issue new equity at current prices. At yearend 1990, MH’s book ratio of equity capital to total (on-book) assets was 5.57%, while its market equity ratio was 2.53%. The bank was also adamant in announcing that it would not omit its quarterly dividend. Despite the low market capital ratio, the Fed appeared unable to force MH to issue new equity. Chemical Bank acquired Manufacturers Hanover at the end of 1991.

When Manufacturers’ Hanover confronted a possible conversion of preferred stock in late 1990 (see footnote 6), they considered redeeming the issue using cash on hand. Such a “plan” only works if a supervisor will accept it. Under a market value trigger, such redemption would have to be financed by issuing equity; otherwise, the redemption would further lower the capital ratio. Another important feature of the MH convertible preferred issue was that the entire issue converted if common share prices were even $.01 too low over the specified time interval.

Flannery proposes the following design parameters for RCD:

RCD would have the following broad design features:

  • 1. They automatically convert into common equity if the issuer’s capital ratio falls below a pre-specified value.
  • 2. Unless converted into shares, RCD receive tax-deductible interest payments and are subordinated to all other debt obligations.
  • 3. The critical capital ratio is measured in terms of outstanding equity’s market value. (See Section III.)
  • 4. The conversion price is the current share price. Unlike traditional convertible bonds, one dollar of debentures (in current market value) would generally convert into one dollar’s worth of common stock.
  • 5. RCD incorporate no options for either investors or shareholders: conversion occurs automatically when the trigger is tripped.
  • 6. When debentures convert, the firm must promptly sell new RCD to replace the converted ones.

An example of RCD conversion is provided:

The bank in Figure 1 starts out at t = 0 with a minimally acceptable 8% capital ratio, backed by RCD equal to an additional 5% of total assets. With ten shares (“N”) outstanding, the initial share price (“PS”) is $0.80. By t = ½, the bank’s asset value has fallen to $97, leaving equity at $5.00 and the share price at $0.50. The bank is now under-capitalized ($5/$97 = 5.15% < 8%). Required capital is $7.76 (= 8% of $97). The balance sheet for t = 1 shows that $2.76 of RCD converted into equity to restore capital to 8% of assets. Given that PS = $0.50 at t = ½, RCD investors receive 5.52 shares in return for their $2.76 of bond claims. These investors lose no principal value when their debentures convert: they can sell their converted shares at $0.50 each and use the proceeds to re-purchase $2.76 worth of bonds. The initial shareholders lose the option to continue operating with low equity, because they must share the firm’s future cash flows with converted bondholders.

The critical part of this structure is that the triggering capital ratio values outstanding equity at market prices, rather than book. Additionally, not all – not necessarily even all of one issue – gets converted. Flannery suggests that issues be converted in the order of their issuance; first-in-first-out.

A substantial part of the paper consists of a defense of this market value feature, which I shall not reproduce here.

Flannery repeatedly touts a feature of the plan that I consider a bug:

Triggered by a frequently-evaluated ratio of equity’s market value to assets, RCD could be nearly riskless to the initial investors, while transmitting the full effect of poor investment outcomes to the shareholders who control the firm.

I don’t like the feature. I believe that a fixed-price conversion with a fixed-price trigger will aid in the analysis of this type of issue and make it easier for banks to sell equity above the trigger point – which is desirable! It is much better if the troubled bank can sell new equity to the public at a given price than to have the RCDs convert – Flannery worries about a requirement that the banks replace converted RCDs in short order, which is avoided if the trigger is avoided. If new equity prospects are not aware of their possible dilution if bad times become even worse, they will be less eager to buy.

Additionally, I am not enamoured of the use of regulatory asset weightings as a component of the trigger point. The last two years have made it very clear that there is a very wide range of values that may be assigned to illiquid assets; honest people can legitimately disagree, sometimes by amounts that are very material.

Market trust in the quality of the banks’ mark-to-market of its assets will be reflected, at least to some degree, by the Price/Book ratio. So let’s re-work Flannery’s Table 1 for two banks; both with the same initial capitalization; both of which mark down their assets by the same amount; but one of which maintains its Price/Book ratio (investors trust bank management) while the other’s P/B ratio declines (investors don’t trust bank management, or for some other reason believe that the end of the write-downs is yet to come).

Note that Flannery’s specification for the Market Ratio:

The market value equity ratio is the market value of common stock divided by the sum of (the book value of total liabilities plus the market value of common stock).

Two banks: t=0
Trusty Bank
Assets Liabilities
100 87 Deposits
5 RCD
8 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.80, Price = $1.20;
Market Ratio = 12/(87+5+12) = 11.5%
Sleazy Bank
Assets Liabilities
100 87 Deposits
5 RCD
8 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.80, Price = $1.20;
Market Ratio = 12/(87+5+12) = 11.5%

This is basically the same as Flannery’s example; however, he uses a constant P/B ratio of 1.0 to derive a Market Ratio of 8%. In addition, I will assume that the regulatory requirement for the Market Ratio is 10% – the two banks started with a cushion.

Disaster strikes at time t=0.5, when asset values decline by 3%. Trusty Bank’s P/B remains constant at 1.5, but Sleazy Bank’s P/B declines to 0.8.

Two banks: t=0.5
Trusty Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
5 RCD
5 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.50, Price = $0.75;
Market Ratio = 7.50 / (87+5+7.5) = 7.54%
Sleazy Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
5 RCD
5 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.50, Price = $0.40;
Market Ratio = 4.00 / (87+5+4) = 4.17%

In order to get its Market Ratio back up to the 10% regulatory minimum that is assumed, Trusty Bank needs to solve the equation:

[7.5+x] / [87 + (5-x) + (7.5 + x)] = 0.10

where x is the Market Value of the new equity and is found to be equal to 2.45. With a stock price of 0.75, this is equal to 3.27 shares

Sleazy Bank solves the equation:

[4.0+x] / (87 + (5-x) + (4.0 +x)) = 0.10

and finds that x is 5.60. With a stock price of 0.40, this is equal to 14.00 shares.

Two banks: t=1.0
Trusty Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
2.55 RCD
7.45 Equity
N = 13.27, Book = $0.56, Price = $0.75;
Market Ratio = (13.27*0.75)/(87+2.55+(13.27*0.75)) = 10%
Sleazy Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
-0.60 RCD
10.60 Equity
N = 24.00, Book = $0.44, Price = $0.40;
Market Ratio = (24*0.4)/(87-0.6+(24*0.4)) = 10%

Sleazy Bank doesn’t have the capital on hand – as shown by the negative value of balance sheet RCD at t=1 – so it goes bust instead. In effect, there has been a bank run instigated not by depositors but by shareholders.

Note that in the calculations I have assumed that the price of the common does not change as a result of the dilution; this alters the P/B ratio. Trusty Bank’s P/B moves from 1.50 to 1.34; Sleazy Bank’s P/B (ignoring the effect of the negative value of the RCDs) moves from 0.8 to 0.91. Whether or not the assumption of constant market price is valid in the face of the dilution is a topic that can be discussed at great length.

I will note that the Price/Book ratio of Japanese banks in early 2008 was 0.32:1 and Citigroup’s P/B ratio is currently 0.67:1.

While Dr. Flannery’s idea has its attractions, I am very hesitant about the idea of mixing book and market values. From a theoretical viewpoint, capital is intended to be permanent, which implies that once the bank has its hands on the money, it doesn’t really care all that much about the price its capital trades at in the market.

Using a fixed conversion price, with a fixed market price trigger keeps the separation of book accounting from market pricing in place, which offers greater predictability to banks, investors and potential investors in times of trouble.

Update 2009-11-1: Arithmetical error corrected in table.

It should also be noted that the use of market value of equity in calculating regulatory ratios makes the proposal as it stands extremely procyclical.

Lloyds Bank to Issue Contingent Capital with Tier 1 Ratio Trigger?

Friday, October 30th, 2009

Lloyds Banks has announced:

Lloyds Banking Group (Lloyds) notes recent media speculation regarding its proposed potential participation in the Government Asset Protection Scheme (GAPS). Lloyds is in advanced discussions with HM Treasury, UK Financial Investments and the Financial Services Authority regarding alternatives to participation in GAPS.

Lloyds believes that any alternative proposals to GAPS would be likely to include a substantial capital raising of core tier 1 and contingent core tier 1 capital to increase the Group’s capital ratios to an appropriate level of strength and flexibility, and would provide a strong capital base for the future stability and success of the Group. The alternative proposals would also meet the FSA’s requirements for stressed economic conditions.

Capital raising options currently under consideration include a combination of raising immediately available core tier 1 capital by way of a rights issue and generating contingent core tier 1 and/or core tier 1 capital through the exchange of certain existing Group capital securities.

Media speculation, indeed! Wealth Bulletin reports (note that the WSJ credits Duncan Kerr of Financial News for this interview):

Owen Murfin, global fixed-income manager at BlackRock in London, said that Lloyds’ plan to generate contingent capital through an exchange would only work at “attractive levels” but that if the transaction does go well, “it will probably form the template of the future of hybrid bank capital, or certainly the shape of capital going forward”.

Murfin added that for investors to get fully behind it, some key issues needed to be addressed, such as what will be used as the triggers, and who or what will decide when these measures have been breached.

He said: “Core tier-one is probably going to be the most likely trigger used. The existing regulatory minimum is around 4%, so the level would probably have to be above that and somewhere around 5%. Core tier-one capital would then be replenished at a far higher level as a result of the conversion.

Reuters also suggests a Tier 1 Ratio Trigger, but with no attribution:

The conversion trigger needs to be set low enough that it is unlikely to be reached, but high enough that it provides help before a bank hits crisis point. That could see it triggered when the Core Tier 1 equity falls below 5 or 6 percent, depending on new industry standards under discussion.

FT Alphaville quotes JPM analysts Carla Antunes da Silva and Amit Goel musing that:

What are the challenges? Several uncertainties surround these instruments including (i) setting appropriate trigger points; (ii) pricing the instruments such that they are attractive to both investors and the issuing institutions; and (iii) market treatment in terms of share count/equity.

I have real problems with using Tier 1 Capital Ratios as a trigger for conversion. Accrued Interest points out:

Look at Lehman. They had a Tier 1 ratio of 11 just weeks before they were bankrupt. Their problem was part their funding mix which was very reliant on repo and prime brokerage, and part the fact that the market didn’t believe their valuations on some illiquid assets. Maybe had either of those circumstances been different, i.e, the same leverage and assets but a more stable funding mix, they would have survived. Regardless, a regulator scheme based on leverage ratios never would have caught Lehman before it was too late. Nominally, they had plenty of capital.

This is why the idea of contingent capital makes so much sense to me. A bank has a ready set of equity investors whenever its needed. It instills market discipline, as the current stock price would reflect the potential for dilution, but the falling stock price wouldn’t prevent a capital raise. In effect, this is a little like a standard bankruptcy, where bond holders take control of a company, except that instead of the company actually going through such a disruptive process, ownership just transfers (in part) to the contingent capital bondholders automatically.

More generally than the anecdotal Lehman example, the IMF looked at various bail-out predictors in Chapter 3 of the April 09 GFSR:

The results in Table 3.1 show the following:

  • • Capital adequacy ratios were unable to clearly identify institutions requiring intervention. In fact, contrary to the common belief that low capital adequacy ratios would signal weakness for a FI, all four capital adequacy ratios examined for intervened commercial banks were significantly higher than (or similar to) the nonintervened commercial banks as a whole (Figure 3.1). There are, of course, regional differences among nonintervened commercial banks. During 2005:Q1–2007:Q2, the capital-to-assets ratio for nonintervened commercial banks in Asia and the euro area were higher than for intervened commercial banks. However this was not the case for FIs in the noneuro area. This suggests that regional differences can make direct comparisons problematic.
  • • Several basic indicators of leverage appear to be informative in identifying the differences in the institutions, although the reasons for this deserve further examination. The higher ratios of debt to common equity, and short term debt to total debt in the intervened commercial banks and intervened investment banks, all indicate that these measures of leverage are especially informative about the differences (Figure 3.2).
  • • Traditional liquidity ratios are not very indicative of the differences between intervened and nonintervened institutions. In part, this is because these liquidity ratios may not be able to fully measure wholesale funding risks.
  • • Asset quality indicators show a mixed picture. Similar to the capital adequacy ratios, the ratio of nonperforming loans (NPL) to total loans for the intervened commercial banks has been lower than for the nonintervened commercial banks, indicating that NPL ratios are not very reliable indicators of the deterioration in asset quality. However, the lower provisions for the loan-losses-to-total-loans ratio for the nonintervened commercial banks suggests that this is a better indicator
    than the NPL ratio.

  • • The standard measures of earnings and profits show a mixed picture. While return on assets (ROA) for the intervened institutions are much higher than those in the nonintervened commercial banks, suggesting that elevated risks are associated with higher returns, return on equity (ROE) has not captured any major differences between the FIs that were intervened or not (Figure 3.3). This contrast between the effectiveness in ROA and ROE may reflect the high leverage ratio of intervened FIs, which typically rely on higher levels of debt to produce profits.
  • • Stock market indicators are able to capture some differences. The price-to-earnings ratios, earning per share, and book value per share of the intervened investment banks have been generally higher than those in the nonintervened commercial banks, which suggest that the higher equity prices and earnings do not necessarily reflect healthier institutions, but perhaps concomitant higher risks.

I confess that I don’t understand the last point very well. Book value per share? Earnings per share? Surely these simply reflect the number of shares issued against the size of the bank. If they discussed Price-to-Book ratios, that would be one thing, but they don’t. They do, however, include Price/Earnings ratio in the various tests and find it does not discriminate between bailed-out and non-bailed-out banks.

My objection to using Capital Ratios as a trigger point is simply that they haven’t worked very well in this crisis: all the failed banks met the capital tests before being bailed out. This does not mean that I disdain Capital Ratios. On the contrary, I think they’re the single most valuable metric for quantifying the strength of a bank. “Single most”, however, has a different meaning from “Only required”. It is now accepted that a blunt leverage ratio – in Canada, the Assets to Capital multiple – is a very useful additional tool; I will not be at all surprised to see a metric based on liquidity introduced at some point.

Why do bank runs happen? Confidence. During the crisis, nobody trusted capital ratios because they are dependent upon the degree to which markdowns on bad assets had been taken; if you did not trust the accounting, you did not trust the capital ratio and – critically – you sold the stock.

I continue to believe that the most appropriate trigger is simply the common stock’s trading price. As I stated in my commentary on the HM Treasury response to the Turner Report, this has the advantage of being known in advance; no judgement by the regulatory authorities is required and therefore, in a crisis, there won’t be the chance of the market attempting to second-guess just what the authorities’ decision really means. The advantage of known conversion triggers will also allow a certain amount of arbitrage, which will boost liquidity for these instruments at a time when we may assume that such liquidity will be sorely needed.

For instance, to take my basic idea of a new issue of contingent-equity preferreds, issued at $25 at a time when the common is trading (for convenience in referring to the exchange ratio) at $50. The preferred converts to common on a one-to-one basis if the monthly (quarterly?) volume-weighted-average-price of the common dips below $25; that being the exchange price, set to one-half of the common’s price at the time when the preferred was issued.

Should bad times come and the common starts trading in the high twenties, it may well be imagined that puts on the common with a $25 strike will become very popular, going some way towards transferring the income from the prefs into the hands of speculators who don’t mind taking a chance. The preferreds will trade more and more like equity, in a smooth and transparent manner, as the equity price declines. Isn’t this exactly what the doctor ordered?

It should also be noted that the bank bailouts resulted in Tier 1 Capital NEVER falling below regulatory minima, although I have no figures on how close it got. This was a deliberate feature of the plan – the fiscal authorities didn’t want the banks to get shut down. However, this raises the spectre of the potential for a bank to be bailed out before the conversion trigger is reached, which would be a Bad Thing. Conversion is much more likely to be triggered by a decline in the price of the common.

We’ll see how it all turns out. But I think that Tier 1 Ratio triggers are simply a Bad Idea for contingent capital.

I will note that Bernanke mentioned contingent capital in passing near the end of his testimony to the House Committee on Financial Services, 2009-10-1:

In addition, we are working with our fellow regulatory agencies toward the development of capital standards and other supervisory tools that would be calibrated to the systemic importance of the firm. Options under consideration in this area include requiring systemically important institutions to hold aggregate levels of capital above current regulatory norms or to maintain a greater share of capital in the form of common equity or instruments with similar loss-absorbing attributes, such as “contingent” capital that converts to common equity when necessary to mitigate systemic risk.

Contingent Capital has been discussed often on PrefBlog of late:

OFSI Joins Contingent Capital Bandwagon

Tarullo Confronts ‘Too Big To Fail’

Dudley of FRBNY Supports Contingent Capital

HM Treasury Responds to Turner Report

October 30, 2009

Friday, October 30th, 2009

The CIT saga continues:

CIT Group Inc., the 101-year-old commercial lender trying to avoid collapse, reached a deal with Goldman Sachs Group Inc. to reduce a $3 billion credit facility to $2.13 billion and keep the line open should CIT file for bankruptcy.

In exchange, Goldman Sachs received $285 million in termination fees, New York-based CIT said today in a filing with the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. Under the terms of the two companies’ original agreement, Goldman Sachs would have been due a $1 billion termination payment to close the credit line after a CIT bankruptcy.

CIT is attempting to cut its bills by asking creditors to exchange about $30 billion of debt for new securities. If the plan fails, the company may go bankrupt, which could erase most of the $2.3 billion stake held by U.S. taxpayers. CIT said in a statement today that the deadline for bondholders to vote on the plan passed last night and it is still counting ballots.

CIT has come to an agreement with Icahn, which suggests to me the restructuring has failed:

it has entered into an agreement with Carl Icahn to support its restructuring plan and secured an incremental $1 billion committed line of credit from Icahn Capital LP to provide supplemental liquidity for CIT as it pursues that plan.

This new line of credit may be drawn by the Company on or prior to December 31, 2009, subject to definitive documentation and other customary conditions, and may be drawn as debtor-in-possession financing in the event of bankruptcy. Together with CIT’s $4.5 billion expansion facility, announced on October 28, 2009, and other available sources of liquidity, the line of credit will further enhance CIT’s liquidity during the execution of its restructuring plan and ensure its ability to serve its existing small business and middle market customers.

The preferred share market closed a lousy month on a high note, with PerpetualDiscounts up 13bp and FixedResets up 11bp. Volume was light, which may be related to the banks’ year-ends today; the prop desks being less willing than usual to facilitate trading by taking positions.

PerpetualDiscounts closed yielding 6.04%, equivalent to 8.46% interest at the standard equivalency factor of 1.4x. Long Corporates continue to yield a hair under 6.0% – having returned +44bp for the month – and thus the pre-tax interest-equivalent spread is now in the 245-250bp range, indistinguishable from the 250bp reported on October 28.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.2234 % 1,474.1
FixedFloater 6.54 % 4.61 % 48,168 18.06 1 2.2769 % 2,381.1
Floater 2.64 % 3.09 % 99,856 19.48 3 -0.2234 % 1,841.5
OpRet 4.88 % -6.10 % 117,472 0.09 15 -0.2045 % 2,289.4
SplitShare 6.39 % 6.47 % 456,408 3.93 2 0.1989 % 2,068.0
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.2045 % 2,093.4
Perpetual-Premium 5.91 % 5.96 % 137,808 13.78 11 -0.0807 % 1,852.9
Perpetual-Discount 5.99 % 6.04 % 205,311 13.85 63 0.1279 % 1,731.6
FixedReset 5.53 % 4.26 % 443,286 3.99 41 0.1094 % 2,106.7
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
TD.PR.Q Perpetual-Discount -1.78 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 23.59
Evaluated at bid price : 23.78
Bid-YTW : 5.92 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet -1.39 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 24.75
Bid-YTW : 5.66 %
RY.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.04 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 19.36
Evaluated at bid price : 19.36
Bid-YTW : 5.82 %
TD.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 1.05 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 21.15
Evaluated at bid price : 21.15
Bid-YTW : 5.77 %
PWF.PR.M FixedReset 1.13 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-02
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.80
Bid-YTW : 4.18 %
BNS.PR.N Perpetual-Discount 1.36 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 22.91
Evaluated at bid price : 23.07
Bid-YTW : 5.72 %
CIU.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.56 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 19.56
Evaluated at bid price : 19.56
Bid-YTW : 5.99 %
PWF.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 1.57 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 22.15
Evaluated at bid price : 22.60
Bid-YTW : 6.10 %
BAM.PR.G FixedFloater 2.28 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 16.62
Bid-YTW : 4.61 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
TRP.PR.A FixedReset 141,755 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.37
Bid-YTW : 4.39 %
CM.PR.J Perpetual-Discount 104,400 TD crossed 99,900 at 18.90.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 18.70
Evaluated at bid price : 18.70
Bid-YTW : 6.06 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 66,942 RBC crossed 56,700 at 19.30.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 19.24
Evaluated at bid price : 19.24
Bid-YTW : 6.14 %
TD.PR.K FixedReset 51,550 Desjardins crossed 43,300 at 27.20.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.16
Bid-YTW : 4.32 %
BMO.PR.N FixedReset 44,500 RBC bought two blocks from TD at 27.95: 12,500 and 10,000 shares.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-27
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.91
Bid-YTW : 3.92 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 31,507 RBC crossed 10,000 at 20.03 and 10,600 at 20.00.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-30
Maturity Price : 20.00
Evaluated at bid price : 20.00
Bid-YTW : 6.04 %
There were 23 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

TDS.PR.B: Partial Call for Redemption

Friday, October 30th, 2009

TD Split Inc. has announced:

that it has called 194,364 Preferred Shares for cash redemption on November 13, 2009 representing approximately 21.4% of the outstanding Preferred Shares as a result of holders of 194,364 Capital Shares exercising their special annual retraction rights. The Preferred Shares shall be redeemed on a pro rata basis, so that each remaining holder of Preferred Shares will have approximately 21.4% of their Preferred Shares redeemed. The redemption price for the Preferred Shares will be $28.10 per share. Holders of Preferred Shares that have been called for redemption will be entitled to receive dividends thereon which have been declared but remain unpaid up to but not including November 13, 2009.

In addition, holders of a further 129,600 Preferred and Capital Shares have deposited such shares concurrently for retraction on November 13, 2009. As a result, a total of 323,964 Preferred and Capital Shares, or approximately 31.3% of both classes of shares currently outstanding will be redeemed.

Payment of the amount due to retracting shareholders will be made by the Company on November 13, 2009. From and after November 14, 2009 the holders of Preferred Shares that have been called for redemption will not be entitled to dividends or to exercise any right in respect of such shares except to receive the amount due on redemption.

TDS.PR.B was last mentioned on PrefBlog when it was upgraded to Pfd-3(high) by DBRS. TDS.PR.B is tracked by HIMIPref™ but is relegated to the “Scraps” subindex on both credit and volume concerns.

Stop-Loss Orders

Friday, October 30th, 2009

Stop-Loss Orders have always seemed completely insane to me. They completely ignore fundamentals; they are set according to price only.

If you’re willing to sell something at $20, why wouldn’t you sell it at $21 when you have the chance? The deliberate introduction of negative convexity into a portfolio – without getting paid for it! – is something that has bothered me even before I could express the idea in terms of convexity.

I was asked a question regarding Stop-Loss orders recently, which I answered as politely as I could; but it would be helpful to have some academic references to buttress my biases … or, who knows, maybe even refute them, although that would be the complete antithesis of how I have managed money throughout my career.

So … I’m starting this post to keep my notes in. Carry on!

Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Speculation, J. Bradford De Long, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence H. Summers and Robert J. Waldmann. Yep, that’s THE Larry Summers. Anyway, the argument here is that there will be a certain proportion of “positive feedback” traders in the market, no matter what – they might even be margin traders, getting margin calls in a down market. Therefore, it becomes rational for informed traders to overreact to actual news, because they know that uninformed traders will overreact even more while the informed traders liquidate. While interesting, the authors are more interested in demonstrating the variability of the market and determining “critical points” – where a decline becomes a discontinuous crash – rather than looking at empirical evidence of stop-loss profit-and-loss.

Market Liquidity, Hedging, and Crashes by Gerard Gennotte and Hane Leland has much the same theme. There’s a nice line in the conclusion: “Traditional models which do not recognize that many investors are poorly informed will grossly overestimate the liquidity of stock markets” …. I’ll have to think about how that might tie in with the Credit Cruch!

FortisAlberta 30-Year Note & FTS.PR.F

Thursday, October 29th, 2009

FortisAlberta has issued new 30-year notes at 5.37%:

DBRS has today assigned a rating of A (low), with a Stable trend, to the $125 million 5.37% medium-term notes (MTNs) due October 30, 2039, issued by FortisAlberta Inc. (FortisAlberta). The MTNs are expected to settle on October 30, 2009. The MTNs are being issued pursuant to FortisAlberta’s Short Form Base Shelf Prospectus dated December 15, 2008.

The MTNs will rank equally with all of FortisAlberta’s other present and future unsecured and unsubordinated senior obligations.

Thirty-year medium-term notes, eh? There’s a stretch!

FortisAlberta is a wholly-owned subsidary of Fortis Inc.:

As owner and operator of more than 60 per cent of Alberta’s total electricity distribution network, FortisAlberta’s focus remains the safe and reliable delivery of electricity to 460,700 customers in 175 communities across southern and central Alberta.

The Corporation is a regulated electricity distribution utility in the Province of Alberta. Its business is the ownership and operation of regulated electricity distribution facilities that distribute electricity generated by other market participants from high-voltage transmission substations to end-use customers. The Corporation does not own or operate generation or transmission assets and is not involved in the direct sale of electricity. The Corporation has limited exposure to exchange rate fluctuations on foreign currency transactions. It is intended that the Corporation remain a regulated electric utility for the foreseeable future, focusing on the delivery of safe, reliable and cost-effective electricity services to its customers in Alberta.

While FortisAlberta is the largest of Fortis Inc.’s electric companies, in terms of both assets and profits, it’s a relatively small component of the entire group, contributing about 15% of total profit in 2008. Additionally, there is a big difference between a small regional fully-regulated subsidiary and a multinational company with ambitions:

Fortis is the largest investor-owned distribution utility in Canada serving more than 2,000,000 gas and electricity customers. Its regulated holdings include electric utilities in five Canadian provinces and three Caribbean countries and a natural gas utility in British Columbia. Fortis owns non-regulated generation assets, primarily hydroelectric, across Canada and in Belize and Upper New York State and hotels and commercial real estate in Canada. In 2008, the Corporation’s electricity distribution systems met a combined peak electricity demand of more than 5,700 megawatts (“MW”) and its gas distribution systems met a peak day demand of 1,402 terajoules (“TJ”). The vision of Fortis is to be the world leader in those segments of the regulated utility industry in which it operates and the leading service provider within its service areas. Fortis has adopted a strategy of profitable growth with earnings per common share as the primary measure of performance. The Corporation’s first priority is to pursue organic growth opportunities in existing operations. Additionally, Fortis pursues profitable growth through acquisitions.

Despite the caveat, it’s of interest to compare the 5.37% on the subsidiary’s 30-year note with the YTW on the parent’s PerpetualDiscount issue, FTS.PR.F.

FTS.PR.F closed today at 21.85-95, with a yield-to-worst of 5.70%. At this point, a table is in order:

Fortis Inc
and
FortisAlberta
Attribute Fortis Inc. FortisAlberta
Credit Rating
Senior Bond
DBRS
BBB(high) A(low)
Credit Rating
Senior Bond
S&P
A- A-
Credit Rating
Preferred
DBRS
Pfd-3(high) NR
Credit Rating
Preferred
S&P
P-2 NR
Yield
Long Bond
N/A 5.37%
Yield
PerpetualDiscount
5.70% (div)
7.98% (int. eq.)
N/A

I like DBRS’ ratings better than S&P’s – it seems to me that some notching is appropriate in this case. While the parent is wonderfully diversified relative to the subsidiary, which would normally imply equal ratings, in this case the sub is a regulated utility, while the parent is an expanding collection of businesses, some of which are unregulated. While I will agree that a compelling case can be made for equal ratings, I like a one notch better.

It is notable that FTS.PR.F is trading below the yield of the better-rated index; this is probably due to the market’s fondness for non-financials, which is proxied by the “cumulative” attribute. For all that, the spread of about 260bp (interest equivalent) is probably a little low, given that the index-to-index spread is about 250bp. To me, the preferred seems a little expensive against the bond here, all in.

October 29, 2009

Thursday, October 29th, 2009

The CIT restructuring continues to encourage speculation:

Since CIT Chief Executive Officer Jeffrey Peek started a $30 billion debt swap Oct. 1, the company’s notes due Nov. 3 have dropped 13 cents to 67 cents on the dollar, according to Trace, the bond-price reporting system of the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority. Holders of the $500 million in notes are being offered 90 cents on the dollar in new debt and equity in an out-of-court exchange. They would get 70 cents on the dollar in bonds and new stock in a pre-packaged bankruptcy.

The CIT notes due Nov. 3 fell 2.5 cents to 67 cents on the dollar yesterday, Trace data show.

The cost to protect CIT debt against default for five years has risen 4.7 percentage points to 38.7 percent upfront since Sept. 30, according to CMA DataVision.

It was a mild day for the Canadian preferred share market, with PerpetualDiscounts gaining 1bp, while FixedResets gained 2bp. Volume was steady.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0000 % 1,477.4
FixedFloater 6.69 % 4.74 % 47,663 17.89 1 -1.4554 % 2,328.1
Floater 2.64 % 3.09 % 103,575 19.48 3 0.0000 % 1,845.7
OpRet 4.87 % -6.52 % 115,996 0.09 15 0.0281 % 2,294.1
SplitShare 6.41 % 6.37 % 461,873 3.93 2 0.3548 % 2,063.9
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0281 % 2,097.7
Perpetual-Premium 5.90 % 5.90 % 139,747 13.78 11 -0.1283 % 1,854.4
Perpetual-Discount 6.00 % 6.05 % 207,650 13.82 63 0.0102 % 1,729.4
FixedReset 5.53 % 4.28 % 443,397 4.00 41 0.0219 % 2,104.4
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -2.18 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 21.11
Evaluated at bid price : 21.11
Bid-YTW : 6.00 %
POW.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -1.58 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 21.22
Evaluated at bid price : 21.22
Bid-YTW : 6.37 %
BAM.PR.G FixedFloater -1.46 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 16.25
Bid-YTW : 4.74 %
PWF.PR.M FixedReset -1.30 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-02
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.50
Bid-YTW : 4.48 %
RY.PR.G Perpetual-Discount -1.24 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 19.16
Evaluated at bid price : 19.16
Bid-YTW : 5.88 %
BNS.PR.Q FixedReset -1.16 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-11-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.60
Bid-YTW : 4.34 %
PWF.PR.L Perpetual-Discount -1.14 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 20.81
Evaluated at bid price : 20.81
Bid-YTW : 6.17 %
TD.PR.O Perpetual-Discount -1.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 20.93
Evaluated at bid price : 20.93
Bid-YTW : 5.83 %
CIU.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.05 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 19.26
Evaluated at bid price : 19.26
Bid-YTW : 6.09 %
GWO.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.47 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 23.30
Evaluated at bid price : 23.45
Bid-YTW : 6.09 %
MFC.PR.A OpRet 1.78 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2015-12-18
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.31
Bid-YTW : 3.25 %
BNS.PR.P FixedReset 2.42 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-05-25
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.80
Bid-YTW : 4.04 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BNS.PR.X FixedReset 48,022 TD bought 10,000 from National at 27.21.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-25
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.22
Bid-YTW : 4.17 %
SLF.PR.F FixedReset 36,250 RBC crossed 33,100 at 27.05.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.98
Bid-YTW : 4.31 %
SLF.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 35,419 RBC crossed 22,900 at 19.88.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 19.87
Evaluated at bid price : 19.87
Bid-YTW : 6.12 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 28,537 RBC crossed 17,700 at 20.04.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 19.95
Evaluated at bid price : 19.95
Bid-YTW : 6.06 %
RY.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 27,963 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 20.14
Evaluated at bid price : 20.14
Bid-YTW : 5.85 %
RY.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 27,875 RBC crossed 15,000 at 19.40.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-10-29
Maturity Price : 19.34
Evaluated at bid price : 19.34
Bid-YTW : 5.83 %
There were 37 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.