The drive to send the CDS market to London and Dubai continues, with Christopher Cox of the SEC jumping on the bandwagon:
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission Chairman Christopher Cox said Congress should grant authority to regulate the credit-default swaps market amid concern the bets are helping fuel the global financial crisis.
Lawmakers should “provide in statute the authority to regulate these products to enhance investor protection and ensure the operation of fair and orderly markets,” Cox told the Senate Banking Committee today at a hearing in Washington.
…
Cox today said investors who buy swaps without owning the underlying debt may be similar to naked short sellers who sell stocks they don’t own or borrow. Such short sales can flood the market and illegally drive down stocks.
Similar to naked shorts of stocks? Well … hasn’t that been obvious from the beginning? The mechanics of CDSs have been discussed on PrefBlog; Mr. Cox’s full remarks have been posted at the SEC site.
The theory that Sarbanes-Oxley makes the US capital markets less attractive is one to which I subscribe; but there is a column on VoxEU by Craig Doidge, George Andrew Karolyi and Rene M. Stulz that takes the opposite view:
In a recent paper, we examined the 59 firms that deregistered in the six months after Rule 12h-6 was adopted.1 Our analysis shows that deregistering firms have poor growth opportunities and experienced poor stock return performance over a number of years before deregistration. Compared to other foreign firms cross-listed on US exchanges, deregistering firms also have a significantly lower “cross-listing premium”, the valuation difference between cross-listed firms and their home-market counterparts, and this lower cross-listing premium cannot be explained by an adverse impact of Sarbanes-Oxley.
…
Overall, the evidence supports the hypothesis that foreign firms list shares in the US in order to raise capital at the lowest possible cost to finance growth opportunities and that, when those opportunities disappear, a US listing becomes less valuable to corporate insiders, so such firms are more likely to deregister and go home.
I’m not sure that the Sarbanes-Oxley is as easily excused as all that. I quite agree that companies will – in general – make a rational investment choice when listing in the US and will leave when the costs outweigh the benefits. If Sarbanes-Oxley is a cost, however, a decision to leave becomes more likely. More insidiously, and much harder to examine in an academically satisfactory way, is the initial decision to list.
For example, Marsh Carter of the NYSE stated in 2006:
Finally, foreign companies are unquestionably concerned about the costs and added regulatory burdens associated with the U.S. regulation, including Sarbanes-Oxley.
…
Indeed, one of the underlying motivations for companies listing in the U.S. is the increase in value – which averages about 30 percent — that accrues as a result of adhering to the high standards of governance that the U.S. markets demand. But companies are increasingly viewing the costs associated with these regulatory requirements, as well as their impact on the speed with which they can reach the market, as outweighing the valuation premium they offer. The way that the requirements of Section 404 were implemented is perceived to have resulted in substantial cost and duplication of effort that has caused international companies to conclude that the additional costs of our regulatory structure outweigh the benefits.
…
When the London Stock Exchange surveyed 80 international companies that conduced IPOs on its market, it reported that 90 percent of the companies that had listed on the LSE felt that the demands of U.S. corporate governance rules made listing in London more attractive. The Wall Street Journal recently reported that small U.S. companies are turning to London’s small-cap market, AIM, for a variety of reasons, including the regulatory costs of going public. The article noted that “one of the reasons most commonly cited is the strain of Sarbanes-Oxley regulations in the [United S]tates.”
Also in VoxEU, Jeffrey Frankel wants a piece of the bank action, not just Bagehot:
What Mallaby calls the core insight is also the crux of Krugman’s logic (“Cash for Trash”):
“…the financial system needs more capital. And if the government is going to provide capital to financial firms, it should get what people who provide capital are entitled to – a share in ownership, so that all the gains if the rescue plan works don’t go to the people who made the mess in the first place.”
This follows a call by Charles W. Calomiris for preferred stock buys rather than loans:
Instead of buying toxic assets, the US government should buy preferred stock capital in ailing banks that could raise matching private sector equity. This would avoid the intractable problems of how the government should value the toxic assets and directly address the banks’ immediate problem – a lack of bank capital.
I like that idea a lot better. Look, a lot of the problem here is simply that sub-prime paper is not being rationally priced and the owners are being forced to mark to market. I recently noted that Moody’s is projecting a 22% loss on 2006 vintage mortgages. As I have discussed at length, the AAA portion of subprime debt is subordinated by roughly 20% (the precise amount will depend on the deal). So, OK, the mezzanine and equity portions have been wiped out … but the AAA tranches are only a little impaired. But as was noted by the OECD paper previously discussed, the mark-to-market on these things is a discount of 14%!
I suggest that banks do not want to sell paper worth $98 for only $86. They want to hoard their cash, let the paper run off gradually, and get their $98. So they won’t want to sell to Treasury at “market price” and Treasury will not – politically – be able to come close to “intrinsic value”. Stand off. To fix the problem in a Bagehotish sort of way, allow the banks term financing at Fed Funds + 100bp … which is the old discount window + 50bp, and the new discount window + 75bp. This is similar to the preferred stock idea of Calomiris, but gets the capital threat to Treasury more deeply subordinated, particularly if there’s a nice stiff haircut in the loan value.
CEBS has released a rather bureaucratic Statement on the Current Crisis Situation with the main points (bolded in the original):
- In our view, banks’ exposures to Lehman Brothers are manageable and mostly non-material, compared to the banks’ total assets and capital base.
- …
- With respect to EU banks’ exposures on AIG: given the US government support provided to AIG, EU bank supervisors view that this counterparty risk can be sufficiently mitigated for the moment.
So we can all sleep better at night. C-EBS has spoken!
James Hamilton of Econbrowser makes an interesting point regarding Monday’s spike in oil prices:
The most striking thing about yesterday’s oil prices was the disparity between different futures contracts. The October contract, which expired yesterday, did indeed settle at $120.92, up more than $16. But oil for delivery in November closed at $109.27, an increase of only $6.62, and longer-forward contracts saw an even more modest increase. Unquestionably what was going on was a short squeeze, in which traders who had sold the October contract short were scrambling to close out their positions before expiration, and having a hard time finding people willing to take the other side.
…
I’m guessing that part of the answer must be that some of these operators were following rules of thumb which usually work just fine in a properly functioning market, and weren’t alert to the profit opportunities at hand. I certainly would not expect a discrepancy of this magnitude to persist for as long as 24 hours.But another possibility that suggests itself is some degree of local monopoly power in the Cushing market. If you’re selling that $121 October oil, you might not be anxious to cook the golden goose by bringing any extra oil to the temporarily thirsty market. This might be a reasonable case for the FTC and CFTC to investigate the mechanics of exactly what happened yesterday.
PerpetualDiscounts were off a bit today on average volume. The excitement of the day was Nesbitt’s crosses of BCE issues – some of them usually very sleepy traders.
Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30. The Fixed-Reset index was added effective 2008-9-5 at that day’s closing value of 1,119.4 for the Fixed-Floater index. |
|||||||
Index | Mean Current Yield (at bid) | Mean YTW | Mean Average Trading Value | Mean Mod Dur (YTW) | Issues | Day’s Perf. | Index Value |
Ratchet | N/A | N/A | N/A | N/A | 0 | N/A | N/A |
Fixed-Floater | 4.69% | 4.77% | 77,965 | 15.78 | 6 | -0.1530% | 1,090.7 |
Floater | 5.00% | 5.01% | 48,092 | 15.49 | 2 | -1.3746% | 801.2 |
Op. Retract | 4.99% | 4.68% | 122,680 | 3.42 | 14 | +0.0718% | 1,047.4 |
Split-Share | 5.53% | 6.72% | 51,553 | 4.32 | 14 | -0.4710% | 1,013.4 |
Interest Bearing | 6.59% | 7.55% | 53,596 | 5.18 | 2 | -1.0366% | 1,081.5 |
Perpetual-Premium | 6.23% | 6.06% | 57,480 | 2.17 | 1 | +0.1996% | 997.0 |
Perpetual-Discount | 6.11% | 6.18% | 180,055 | 13.62 | 70 | -0.1222% | 874.2 |
Fixed-Reset | 5.06% | 4.93% | 1,361,337 | 14.26 | 10 | +0.0202% | 1,118.5 |
Major Price Changes | |||
Issue | Index | Change | Notes |
BAM.PR.B | Floater | -2.8144% | |
BSD.PR.A | InterestBearing | -2.7778% | Asset coverage of just under 1.5:1 as of September 19 according to Brookfield Funds. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.64% based on a bid of 8.75 and a hardMaturity 2015-3-31 at 10.00. |
POW.PR.D | PerpetualDiscount | -2.5373% | Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.40% based on a bid of 19.59 and a limitMaturity. |
BNA.PR.B | SplitShare | -2.2564% | Asset coverage of 3.2+:1 as of August 31 according to the company. Coverage now of just under 2.7:1 based on BAM.A at 27.84 and 2.4 BAM.A held per preferred. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.56% based on a bid of 19.06 and a hardMaturity 2016-3-25 at 25.00. Compare with BNA.PR.A (7.33% to 2010-9-30) and BNA.PR.C (10.41% to 2019-1-10). |
BCE.PR.Z | FixFloat | -2.1658% | |
BNA.PR.C | SplitShare | -1.8750% | See BNA.PR.B, above. |
IAG.PR.A | PerpetualDiscount | -1.6086% | Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.31% based on a bid of 18.35 and a limitMaturity. |
HSB.PR.C | PerpetualDiscount | -1.2683% | Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.34% based on a bid of 20.24 and a limitMaturity. |
CIU.PR.A | PerpetualDiscount | -1.2339% | Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.06% based on a bid of 19.21 and a limitMaturity. |
DFN.PR.A | SplitShare | -1.0132% | Asset coverage of just under 2.3:1 as of September 15, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.80% based on a bid of 9.77 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00. |
GWO.PR.I | PerpetualDiscount | +1.0609% | Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.26% based on a bid of 18.10 and a limitMaturity. |
BMO.PR.H | PerpetualDiscount | +1.4520% | Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.20% based on a bid of 21.66 and a limitMaturity. |
BCE.PR.R | FixFloat | +1.5833% |
Volume Highlights | |||
Issue | Index | Volume | Notes |
BCE.PR.D | Scraps (would be Ratchet but there are volume concerns) | 405,000 | Nesbitt crossed 395,000 at 25.50. |
BCE.PR.B | Scraps (would be Ratchet but there are volume concerns) | 326,500 | Nesbitt crossed 325,500 at 24.99. |
BCE.PR.R | FixFloat | 200,800 | Nesbitt crossed 200,000 at 24.38 |
BCE.PR.Y | Ratchet | 60,278 | Nesbitt crossed 59,000 at 24.80. |
BCE.PR.A | FixFloat | 56,425 | Nesbitt crossed 47,500 at 24.65 |
BAM.PR.O | OpRet | 55,400 | CIBC crossed 40,400 at 22.00. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.40% based on a bid of 21.75 and optionCertainty 2013-6-30 at 25.00. Compare with BAM.PR.H (6.74% to 2012-3-30), BAM.PR.I (5.97% to 2013-12-30) and BAM.PR.J (6.28% to 2018-3-30). |
RY.PR.I | FixedReset | 53,398 |
There were twenty-two other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today
“I suggest that banks do not want to sell paper worth $98 for only $86. They want to hoard their cash, let the paper run off gradually, and get their $98. So they won’t want to sell to Treasury at “market price” and Treasury will not – politically – be able to come close to “intrinsic value”.”
To your (and Calomiris’) point that the US Treasury should issue prefs to the banks rather than buy back debt:
1. The Treasury would have more success with Warren Buffett’s approach to Goldman Sachs — prefs plus options on the common at the then-prevailing common price. In his case a 10% pref yield and a 5-year at-the-money option is giving him close to a 20% return.
What the banks need is replacement capital and the Treasury needs some level of protection of its investment. This structure was essentially used in the AIG rescue (Bonds plus common) and has aspects employed with Fannie/Freddie (Priority pref). By having a penal rate on the pref, it automatically has some degree of priority to be paid back first when the bank improves.
2. Right now, the Treasury and Fed are bogged down in Congress over the price at which to buy back bad bank debts. Your note has the example of an “intrinsic” or expected value of $98 and a current market price of $86 (for example). Obviously, if the price is set too low (close to market) bank’s reported losses will increase; if set too high (expected losses) then the Treasury is not likely to make any return from its huge commitment. Based on reports of Bernanke’s testimony, the Fed wants a high price (too high in my view — close to “intrinsic”) in order to stabilize the bank system.
If the approach of buying up debt is going to be used in spite of the benefits of pref shares plus options, it seems to me the best method would be for the Treasury to buy debt at a price reflecting 2-3X the expected losses (in this example, then, $94-96 not $98). This is often where the fixed income market operates under normal conditions — spreads are made up of expected losses plus risk and/or liquidity premia which are often the same size or larger.
Either of these two methods would seem to work better than vague promises or “leave it up to the Treasury” (which seems to be the Paulson testimony). If banks are short of capital, they can have it without giving up control through pref shares at a penalty rate; OR if banks want to sell off some of the problematic debt they could do so at a price more reflective of normal market conditions.
if the price is set too low (close to market) bank’s reported losses will increase
I’m not too sure about this part – a large part of the problem is that banks are all marking to market.
it seems to me the best method would be for the Treasury to buy debt at a price reflecting 2-3X the expected losses (in this example, then, $94-96 not $98).
I agree that this would make sense, but I’m not sure if it would fly politically – if we assume that this debt is on the banks books at the market price of $86, they’ll be booking huge profits on their sale to Treasury.
I don’t know about this whole buy-the-debt thing. To me, it suffers from the same problem that MLEC did last fall – market price is just so different from fundamental price that nobody wants to trade; and they won’t until the creditors force them to.
Preferred shares at a punitive rate is fine with me!
Mr. Hymas, wouldn’t it be a good thing if credit default swaps were traded in London, Singapore, Timbuktu etc. and banned from the NYSE, TSX – anywhere my money might be put at risk by these gamblers? Insurance, be it bond default, mortgage default, I can understand but this is well beyond my (and apparently a whole lot more so-called “experts”) little brain and grasp.
I forgot to ask another question, so your indulgence please. Why shouldn’t this debt, whatever it is, be marked to market? When I buy a bond today and tomorrow someone somewhere decides it’s no longer worth what I paid for it, were I to want to sell it, guess what, I ain’t gittin’ what I paid for it, know what I mean Vern? Why the hell should they? You pays your money and you takes your chances.
wouldn’t it be a good thing if credit default swaps were traded in London, Singapore, Timbuktu etc. and banned from the NYSE, TSX – anywhere my money might be put at risk by these gamblers?
Well, you’re not alone in a distaste for the vehicle! However, it’s nothing more nor less than a bet that the company will default and is therefore very hard to ban.
I think that a lot of the excesses we’re seeing are due largely to the novelty of the instruments. It cannot make sense to short corporate credit in the long term; corporate credit spreads include a large liquidity premium, a bigger premium than their default premium. It is only in the short term that it makes sense; companies will have to get used to it and manage their capitalization such that they can withstand being locked out of the bond markets for a year or more at a time.
Why shouldn’t this debt, whatever it is, be marked to market?
There are problems with both an automatic mark-to-market on bonds, and an automatic amortization-from-price-bought-at.
The big problem with mark-to-market is that it implicitly assumes that there is a market and this is simply not the case with huge quantities of issued bonds right now.
Look at it this way: I figure my house is worth $500,000. When I have to prepare financial statements for people, that’s what I put. But if I go home at 3pm and stick a for-sale sign on the front lawn, I’m not going to get a $500,000 bid for the place before dinner time. So what’s my mark-to-market on the house? Should I report it as zero, because I ain’t got no bids in my hand?
When things get marked-to-market, and the market is chunky and illiquid, very strange things can happen. Of course, strange things can also happen if, for instance, I’m allowed to keep it on the books at my purchase price forever and claim that since I’m living in it the value hasn’t changed.
Mark-to-market, by the way, is one reason why private equity has become so big in recent years. Let’s say you’re a pension fund and you have a choice of two investments. The companies are identical, except that one’s publicly traded, the other is private. You would almost certainly choose the private company, because then you can tell your auditors to value it off the projected cash flows, which is going to a lot more stable, and much better corellated with your marked-to-yield-curve liabilities, than any publicly traded vehicle will ever be.
[…] Blodgett of Clusterstock emphasizes a point I made September 23 regarding market value vs. intrinsic value of the securities targetted for TARB purchase in a post […]
[…] W. Calomiris of Columbia University has been mentioned on PrefBlog before, most recently on September 23. He has just posted a piece on VoxEU, Financial Innovation, Regulation and Reform that is […]