Archive for the ‘Contingent Capital’ Category

Contingent Capital: UK Authorities Attempting to Debase Bond Indices

Wednesday, November 4th, 2009

One thing that has irritated me for a long time has been the inclusion of Innovative Tier 1 Capital (IT1C) in the major bond indices. Those things aren’t even bonds! IT1C is simply preferred shares dressed up as bonds – this doesn’t degrade their utility as an investment vehicle and can make them quite attractive for non-taxable portfolios … but it doesn’t make them bonds.

However, Scotia stuck them in the index when the DEX indices were still the Scotia Capital indices, which I always presumed was just a way to make them easier to sell. There is never any shortage of pig-ignorant portfolio managers who neither know nor care about the specific risks of particular investments; the dirty part about this is that since institutional clients generally know even less and benchmark against “the index”, portfolio managers must make the choice: not buy them, and risk underperforming for 9 years out of ten; or buy them and pretend that, yes, they really are bonds.

I have previously pointed out that the lack of first-loss protection means that the Lloyds notes are not bonds. They may have merit as investments, certainly, but they are not bond investments.

Now Duncan Kerr of eFinancial News reports that UK government and regulatory authorities are teaming up to pull exactly the same trick with ludicrous index inclusions in a column titled Investor threat remains to Lloyds’ contingent capital plans:

Some of the UK’s biggest fixed-income investors are already frustrated about Lloyds’ lack of clarity over its plans, and some are even threatening to block the inclusion of the new capital securities on widely-used bond indices.

The UK Treasury and Financial Services Authority have been pushing hard for Lloyds’ new contingent capital bonds to be included on the main indices, which would make them more attractive to fixed-income investors.

However, according to analysts some of the UK’s biggest bond investors are arguing that the new securities should not be classed as debt and therefore cannot be included on the main traded indices, which could severely dent investor demand.

>“The Treasury and FSA have been pushing very hard for contingent capital to be in the indices, clearly because it is more attractive when it is part of a tradable index. And if it is more attractive, the more is sold to investors and the less the Treasury will have to buy of this new instrument,” the [anonymous] banks analyst said.

One factor exacerbating this crisis has been the lack of trust in the authorities: when the BoE lent money on good collateral to Northern Rock, they felt they should do so covertly, in contrast to prior practice … doubtless feeling that their word that the instution was solvent but illiquid would be doubted. How much of the current crisis would have been averted if a man with the gravitas of J.P.Morgan had simply asked his right man “Are they solvent?” and reliquified freely on an affirmative answer, as happened in the Panic of 1907? The reliquification and word of J.P.Morgan that it was indeed reliquification was good enough to stem the panic … but nowadays, that sort of statement from the authorities is regarded as just another lie. Well done with the record of integrity, guys!

And now we have the UK authorities trying to pretend that these notes are actual bonds and should be in the bond indices, right up there with 10-year Gilts. It’s a disgrace.

And so the seeds of the next disaster are sown: we’ve seen what happens when the myth that Money Market Funds are risk-free gets punctured, even by just a little bit … should the authorities be successful in weaving the myth that Contingent Capital = Bonds, we will learn the effect of an overnight drop in bond funds due to mandatory conversion to over-priced common.

Lloyds Contingent Capital Poorly Structured

Wednesday, November 4th, 2009

I can only hope that the structure of the Lloyds Contingent Capital notes (now referred to as “CoCos” by the ultracool). It really does not require a lot of thought to arrive at the conclusion that these are bad investments at any rate of interest that may be of interest to the issuer; that they do not go very far towards meeting policy objectives; and that they are strongly procyclical.

Prior posts in the series about these notes are:

… while Contingent Capital has been discussed in the posts:

Gee … I’ll have to think about adding a category!

There are two elements of a contingent capital deal that are of interest:

  • The conversion trigger, and
  • The conversion price

In the Lloyds deal, the conversion is triggered when the “published core tier 1 capital ratio falls below 5 per cent“. Commentators have been breathlessly announcing that in order to reach this level “loan losses in 2009 and 2010 would have to be about 50 billion pounds”.

I won’t take issue with this statement but it should be fairly obvious that this is not the only way in which conversion can be triggered. Other pathways are:

  • A deliberate increase in Risk-Weighted Assets, and
  • Changes in the regulatory regime

From an investment perspective, changes in the regulatory regime must be considered a random variable. At time of conversion, under the terms of the issue, it is the published Tier 1 Ratio that is used – not the Tier 1 Ratio computed in accordance with procedures in place at time of issue. Thus, investors are being asked to buy into a regulatory regime that may have completely changed in effect prior to maturity of their investment. How is anybody supposed to price that? The risk of regulatory change will add significantly to the coupon required by a rational investor, increasing the expense to the issuer and – potentially – leading to political pressure on the regulators to take or refrain from action for the convenience of one side or the other.

Investment isn’t some kind of new age cooperative game. An investor must consider the issuers to be his enemies, eager to take action to compromise his interests. This is particularly true for bond investors, who have no role in the selection of management.

From a public policy perspective, the trigger-point of 5% Tier 1 Ratio is unsatisfactory. What if regulatory changes make 6% the mandatory level? The issuer could then be in a position where it was wound down due to insufficient capital – or forced to issue equity at fire-sale prices – without the conversion being triggered.

Triggers based on regulatory ratios mix market value considerations with book value considerations. While not necessarily a deal-killer all by itself, such mixtures require close inspection.

The other problem with the Lloyds issue is the conversion price – put management, the FSA and the EU together in the same room and you know that something ridiculous will emerge! The conversion price is, basically, equal to the price at time of issue.

What this means is that conversion may be triggered at some point in the future due to unfortunate results, but that the price is based on today’s price. In other words, holders of these notes have no first-loss protection on losses experienced between issue date and conversion date. And without first-loss protection … they’re not even bonds. They are merely equities with a limited upside. Sounds like a really, really good deal, eh?

It is the interaction between the two vital elements of the issue terms that introduces the greatest danger. Let us assume that – some time after issue, but well before maturity – we enter normal banking times in which management is free, subject to normal regulatory requirements, to make its own decisions regarding risk and leverage.

Management works for the shareholders, so what is the optimal course of action to take on their behalf? I suggest that it is optimal to lever up the company with as much risk as possible to a level slightly above the conversion trigger. If things work out well … then pre-existing shareholders get to claim all the rewards, paying the contingent capital noteholders their coupon. If things work out badly … well, pre-existing shareholders lose money, sure, but they get to share these losses with the contingent capital holders.

The risk/reward outlook for the existing shareholders has become skewed – precisely the thing that the regulators are telling us they’re oh-so-worried about! This asymmetric risk/return is a source of systemic instability.

As has been previously argued, I support a model for contingent capital in which:

  • The conversion trigger is a decline of the common stock to a value below X, where X is less than the issue date price
  • The conversion price is X

Such a model

  • provides noteholders with first-loss protection
  • is unambiguous (uncertainty in times of crisis can be rather disturbing!)
  • allows the market to work out prices using extant option pricing models, without incorporating regulatory uncertainty, and
  • simply formalizes “normal coercive” exchange offers such as that of Citigroup

I suggest that a good place to start thinking about the value of X is:

  • half the issue-date price for issues to be considered Tier 1 (e.g., preferred shares and Innovative Tier 1 Capital)
  • one-quarter the issue-date price for issues to be considered Tier 2 (e.g., subordinated debt).

Update, 2015-4-12: Lloyds ECNs at centre of legal dispute:

Lloyds Banking Group has won permission from the City regulator for a controversial plan to redeem some of its high-yield convertible bonds, although it has suspended the redemption until the courts clarify the law.

The bank’s “enhanced capital notes” were issued in the teeth of the financial crisis, switching investors, many of them pensioners, from preference shares and permanent interest-bearing shares in a bid to improve its capital base.

The notes would convert to equity if Lloyds’ core tier one capital ratio fell below 5pc, although this threshold turned out to be too low to count under the European Banking Authority’s rules on convertible capital.

While the Prudential Regulation Authority has agreed that, from the point of view of Lloyds’ financial strength, the bonds can be redeemed at par, the matter will now go to court for a “declaratory judgement” on whether a redemption would breach bondholders’ contractual rights.

Redeeming the bonds would strip investors of generous interest payments. The bonds have until recently traded above their par value as they offered annual payments as high as 16.125pc, making them particularly attractive as interest rates on other savings products have dwindled.

However, Lloyds said in December that it would seek permission to redeem the bonds at par value, following the Bank of England’s stress tests that did not take the bonds into account when measuring the bank’s capital strength.

Lloyds intends to call in 23 tranches of bonds, worth a total of almost £860m, that were issued in 2009 and 2010.

Lloyds Issues Contingent Capital

Tuesday, November 3rd, 2009

It has been rumoured for a while and now it’s official – Lloyds is issuing contingent capital:

Lloyds Banking Group plc (‘Lloyds Banking Group’) today announces proposals intended to meet its current and long-term capital requirements which, if approved by shareholders, will mean that the Group will not participate in the Government Asset Protection Scheme (‘GAPS’).

  • Fully underwritten Proposals to generate at least £21 billion of core capital1, comprising:
    • £13.5 billion rights issue. HM Treasury, advised by UKFI, has undertaken to subscribe in full for its 43 per cent entitlement
    • Exchange Offers to generate at least £7.5 billion of contingent core tier 1 and/or core tier 1 capital (core tier 1 capital capped at £1.5 billion)
  • High quality, robust and efficient capital structure:
    • Immediate 230bps increase in core tier 1 capital ratio from 6.3 per cent to 8.6 per cent2
    • Significant contingent core tier 1 capital – equates to additional core tier 1 capital of 1.6 per cent3 if the Group’s published core tier 1 capital ratio falls below 5 per cent
    • Reinforces the Group’s capital ratios in stress conditions and meets FSA’s stress test
    • Higher quality capital compared to GAPS where capital benefit reduces over time

The exchange offer is a way of addressing the burden-sharing demanded by the EC.

Offering documents seem to be available, but are not accessible since the world’s regulators are protecting investors from news and foreign prospectuses are, generally, better protected than the Necronomicon. It is not clear – it never is – whether this protection is explicit, or whether they’ve introduced such a conflicting snarl of regulation that the issuers simply throw up their hands and refuse to take the chance.

However, it appears that there is a single conversion trigger based on published Tier 1 Capital Ratios, which I think is thoroughly insane. What happens if the rules for calculation of this ratio change? They’re supposed to change! Treasury and BIS are working feverishly to change them! Does Lloyds have to maintain a calculation of ratios under today’s rules? In that case, not only is there huge expense and confusion, but unintended effects when the trigger occurs under one set of rules but not another. If the rules do change in the interim, then investors are being asked to buy into a blind pool, which will make the securities even more risky than intended.

Update: The cool way to refer to this structure is CoCo:

Contingent convertible bonds differ from traditional equity-linked notes, which can be handed over for stock when a share rises to a pre-agreed “strike price.” CoCos became popular in the U.S. in 2006 as issuers took advantage of accounting rules to sell securities that could only be swapped for stock after the shares passed a threshold above the conversion price and stayed there for a set length of time.

To reach the trigger for the CoCo notes to convert after a 13.5 billion-pound rights issue, loan losses in 2009 and 2010 would have to be about 50 billion pounds, according to [Evolution Strategies’ head Gary] Jenkins.

The CoCo notes were rated at BB by Fitch Ratings today, two steps below investment grade, while Moody’s Investors Service rates the securities at an equivalent Ba2.

Update: Neil Unmack points out that this is a coercive exchange:

However, contingent capital is untested. It is not clear what price investors will demand to hold debt that carries a risk of turning into equity if things go wrong. The proposed exchange could also be problematic. Many fixed income investors aren’t allowed to buy equity-linked debt.

As a result, Lloyds is paying up to get investors on board. They get to switch out of their existing debt into the new contingent capital at par, and get a coupon that is up to 2.5 percent higher than the one they’re getting at the moment. For investors who bought the debt below par — some Lloyds bonds traded as low as 15 percent of face value last March — this means a healthy pay day.

The sweeter coupon alone probably wouldn’t clinch it. Many investors would rather stick with what they have rather than accept an untested instrument which may trade poorly and could be forcibly converted into shares at a later date.

Enter the European Commission, with which Lloyds has been negotiating over state aid. The Commission is compelling Lloyds to cut off coupon payments for up to two years on bonds where it has the right to defer interest. This should help investors with any lingering doubts to make up their minds.

A healthy appetite for the bonds will be a boon for Lloyds, but it doesn’t necessarily mean contingent capital will catch on. For one, it is very expensive: Lloyds is paying interest of up to 16 percent on its bonds. Not every bank will want to pay that.

Still, not every bank is in as dire a situation as Lloyds. Without mafia-style coercion, these kind of large-scale debt exchanges will be harder to pull off.

And S&P took action:

Standard & Poor’s Ratings Services said today that it affirmed its ‘A/A-1′ long- and short-term counterparty credit ratings on Lloyds Banking Group PLC (Lloyds) and its subsidiaries. The outlook remains stable. At the same time, with the exception of issues from Lloyds’ insurance subsidiaries, we lowered our ratings on hybrids with discretionary coupons to ‘CC’ from the current range of ‘B’ to ‘CCC+’. Furthermore, with the exception of issues from Lloyds’ insurance subsidiaries, we raised the ratings on hybrids without optional deferral clauses to ‘BB-‘ from ‘B-‘ in the case of holding company issues, and ‘BB’ from ‘B’ in the case of bank issues.

So the senior’s at “A” and the CoCo’s at “BB”. Six notches!

Update: Bloomberg’s John Glover notes:

Lloyds will stop making discretionary interest payments on the existing notes and won’t exercise options to redeem the debt early for two years starting Jan. 31, the bank said, citing this as a condition laid down by the European Commission. Lloyds will decide whether to call the old bonds on a purely economic basis after the two years are up, it said.

The price at which Lloyds’ new contingent capital bonds will convert into equity will be the greater of the volume- weighted average price in the five trading days from Nov. 11 to Nov. 17, or a calculation based on 90 percent of the stock’s closing price on Nov. 17 multiplied by a factor.

Update, 2009-11-5: Hat tip to the Fixed Income Investor website of the UK, whose post regarding Lloyds Preference Shares linked to the Non-US Exchange Offering Memorandum.

Update, 2009-11-6: The Economist observes:

“When banks get into problems, it is usually not just a marginal 1-2% addition to capital that they need,” says Elisabeth Rudman of Moody’s, a rating agency.

That could make things worse, not better. With previous hybrid instruments, banks were reluctant to halt interest payments and did all they could to buy back bonds on specified dates for fear of showing weakness to markets. Converting the new debt could also slam confidence without raising a big enough slug of equity capital to restore it. That may encourage banks to hoard capital rather than breach the trigger-point.

Contingent Capital: Lloyds & the RBC CLOCS

Tuesday, November 3rd, 2009

Neil Unmack of Reuters wrote a good post about Contingent Capital, Lloyds’ escape plan won’t come cheap:

Regulators are keen on contingent capital because they believe it provides banks with a better buffer against losses than subordinated debt. But banks have yet to answer the call. Royal Bank of Canada has issued some contingent capital, but that was nine years ago. As a result, it’s still not clear whether a public market of any real size can exist, and what the correct cost of the securities should be.

Because contingent capital is untested and carries more explicit risks than existing subordinated bonds, Lloyds is likely to have to offer a higher interest rate than hybrid debt, which would imply a coupon of at least 10 percent and probably more. There’s also the threat the European Commission may force Lloyds to stop paying coupons on its existing subordinated debt, which would encourage investors to switch to the new instruments.

However, some holders of Lloyds’ subordinated debt won’t be able to hold the new securities because they don’t fit the risk profile of a pure fixed income fund.

As a result, investors should be wary. If Lloyds prospers, investors’ upside is limited; but if loan losses soar they will rank first in line for losses. The new securities could end up having all the disadvantages of equity, without much of the benefit. Bond investors should demand a high coupon. Whether the deal is viable for Lloyds’ shareholders will come down to how desperate they are to escape the UK government’s clutches.

The RBC issue was with Swiss Re under their CLOCS (Committed Long Term Capital Solutions) programme: the capital was preferred shares with a dividend rate set at the time of the agreement; the trigger was “exceptional”, but not crippling, losses on RBC’s loan portfolio. Swiss Re touted the transaction as:

Reduces on-balance sheet capital without increasing overall risk profile of company (helps e.g. solvency ratio, capital adequacy )

It has been noted that transactions of this sort involve a certain amount of counterparty risk – what if RBC triggered the transaction, but Swiss Re could not or would not cover the purchase price of the prefs?

Simon Nixon of the WSJ comments in Lloyds Banking on Contingent Capital for Escape:

That points to going further down the capital structure to create contingent capital, such as using Tier 2 debt, which might typically yield around 6%. Including the price of the option, the cost to issuers might be closer to that of core Tier 1 securities.

The snag is that many Tier 2 investors are prohibited from owning equity, and few fixed-income investors — used to measuring performance in 10ths of a percentage point — are willing to expose their portfolios to equity volatility.

To square this circle, issuers will need to set the trigger sufficiently low that there is little prospect it will ever be hit. Yet the banks must also satisfy regulators it will convert into loss-bearing capital when needed.

Several European banks have investigated contingent capital and concluded there is no market.

Update, 2009-11-3: RBC’s CLOCS were discussed in a June 2001 article in CFO magazine by Russ Banham, Just-in-case capital. (hat tip: Tracy Alloway, FT Alphaville.

Contingent Capital: Blinder Supports Squam Lake Model

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

Alan S. Blinder, the Gordon S. Rentschler Memorial Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Princeton University and former Vice-Chairman of the Fed’s Board of Governors, gave a wonderfully informative and chatty speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston conference at Chatham, Massachussets, on October 23, 2009 titled
It’s Broke, Let’s Fix It: Rethinking Financial Regulation.

One quote I simply must highlight is:

After all, regulatory failure on a grand scale was one major cause of the mess.

However, at the moment I am more interested in his thoughts on Contingent Capital than anything else:

I myself am attracted to a particular idea for “contingent capital” suggested recently by the Squam Lake Working Group on Financial Regulation, an ad hoc panel of academic experts. Under the proposal, regulators would have the power, by declaring a systemic crisis, Their idea, which derives from Mark Flannery’s (2005) clever earlier proposal for “reverse convertible debentures,” is to require certain banks to issue a novel type of convertible bond. Conventional convertible debt gets exchanged for equity at the option of the bondholder; and because this option has value, convertible debt bears lower interest rates than ordinary debt. The proposed new form of convertible debt would reverse the optionality by giving it to the regulators instead.

Under the proposal, regulators would have the power, by declaring a systemic crisis, to force holders of these special convertibles (but not holders of other debt instruments) to convert to equity. As in many cases, one key question is price—specifically, how large an interest rate premium would investors demand to cover the risk that their bonds could be converted into equity against their will? If this premium proved to be very large, these new convertibles would be a very expensive form of “capital” that banks might shun, preferring ordinary equity instead. Only experience will tell. —thus giving banks more equity capital (and less debt) just when they need it most. Naturally, the existence of such an option would detract from the value of the bond and therefore would make the interest rate on reverse convertibles higher than on ordinary debt. Indeed, if the requirement was limited to TBTF institutions, as seems appropriate, that higher interest rate on a fraction of their debt would constitute a natural penalty cost for being TBTF. Furthermore, the spread on this new type of debt over regular debt could become a useful market indicator of the likelihood of a systemic crisis.

As in many cases, one key question is price—specifically, how large an interest rate premium would investors demand to cover the risk that their bonds could be converted into equity against their will? If this premium proved to be very large, these new convertibles would be a very expensive form of “capital” that banks might shun, preferring ordinary equity instead. Only experience will tell.

I have previously discussed the Squam Lake proposals, as well as the original Flannery paper; I think they need a little work. My major objections are that:

  • It mixes book value with market value; theoretically suspect and leading in times of stress to unpredictable – probably procyclical – results, and
  • by incorporating regulatory discretion into the conversion trigger, it unnecessarily introduces regulatory uncertainty into the evaluation of the investment, as well as encouraging regulatory capture and even corruption.

He breaks my heart by advocating credit ratings by government agencies:

But many observers think the fundamental problem lies deeper: with the issuer-pays model. As long as rating agencies are for-profit companies, paid by the issuers of the securities they rate, the agencies will have a natural tendency to try to please their customers—just as any business does. Unfortunately, the most obvious alternative, switching to an investors-pay model, is probably infeasible except in markets with very few investors. Otherwise, information flows too readily, and everyone wants to free ride. What to do? The way out of this dilemma, it seems to me, is to arrange for some sort of third-party payment. The government (e.g., the SEC) or an organized exchange or clearinghouse seem to be the natural alternative payers. In either case, they could raise the necessary funds by levying a user-fee on all issuers.

He also discusses the separation of prop trading from vanilla banking:

For example, the Group of Thirty (2009, p. 28)—hardly a bunch of wild-eyed radicals–recently concluded that, “Large, systemically important banking institutions should be restricted in undertaking proprietary activities that present particularly high risks…and large proprietary trading should be limited by strict capital and liquidity requirements.” That’s not quite a ban, but it’s getting close.

But there is a downside. Roping off “proprietary trading” from other, closely-related activities of banks is not as easy as it sounds. For example, banks buy and sell securities, foreign exchange, and other assets for their clients all the time. Often, such buying and selling is imperfectly synchronized or leaves banks with open positions for other reasons. Does that constitute “proprietary trading”? Furthermore, market-making has obvious synergies with dealing on behalf of clients. Do we want to label all such activities as “proprietary trading”? The point is: There is no bright line. That is why Adair Turner (2009), the chairman of Britain’s FSA, concluded that “we could not proceed by a binary legal distinction—banks can do this but not that—but had to focus on the scale of position-taking and the capital held against position-taking.”

I say – yes. we do want to label all such activities as “proprietary trading”; and the fact that there is no bright line is just something we’ll have to get used to. As previously urged on PrefBlog, I suggest that there be two regulatory regimes – for investment banks and vanilla banks, the former imposing relatively heavier capital charges on long term positions, the latter imposing relatively heavier charges on short term positions. It won’t be perfect, by any stretch of the imagination; but it will allow each type of institutions to make decisions on a tactical basis, according to their marginal value.

One of the things that brought down the investment banks was that they engaged in buy-and-hold strategies, which are more properly the province of vanilla banks, which have (or should have!) the expertise and controls in place to look beyond the next portfolio flip.

Contingent Capital: Squam Lake Working Group

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

The papers of the Squam Lake Working Group , a very distinguished group of academics, are published by the Council on Foreign Relations (which seems rather strange, but there you go), who also publish the periodical Foreign Affairs, which I love but don’t have time to read any more.

The Squam Lake paper titled An Expedited Resolution Mechanism for Distressed Financial Firms: Regulatory Hybrid Securities is of great interest, albeit lamentably short on detail.

Most notably, they propose a double trigger for conversion:

A bank’s hybrid securities should convert from debt to equity only if two conditions are met. The first requirement is a declaration by regulators that the financial system is suffering from a systemic crisis. The second is a violation by the bank of covenants in the hybrid-security contract.

This double trigger is important for two reasons. First, debt is valuable in a bank’s capital structure because it provides an important disciplining force for management. The possibility that the hybrid security will conveniently morph from debt to equity whenever the bank suffers significant losses would undermine this productive discipline. If conversion is limited to only systemic crises, the hybrid security will provide the same benefit as debt in all but the most extreme periods.

Second, the bank-specific component of the trigger is also important. If conversion were triggered solely by the declaration of a systemic crisis, regulators would face enormous political pressure when deciding whether to make such a declaration. Replacing regulatory discretion with an objective criterion creates more problems because the aggregate data regulators might use for such a trigger are likely to be imprecise, subject to revisions, and measured with time lags. And, perhaps most important, if conversion depended on only a systemic trigger, even sound banks would be forced to convert in a crisis. This would dull the incentive for these banks to remain sound.

I don’t like the first trigger, the declaration by regulators that a systemic crisis exists. First, there is more than one regulator, which will lead, at the very least, to delays while simultaneous announcements are arranged and, at worst, to political kerfuffles regarding cross-border banks if there is no widespread agreement.

Secondly, it introduces an element of political uncertainty regarding conversion, which will lead to the political pressure they allude to in their discussion of the second trigger.

Thirdly, I just plain don’t trust the regulators.

It will be noted that the group skims rather lightly over the justification for the first trigger!

The group also suggests using Tier 1 Capital Ratios as a trigger:

What sort of covenant would make sense for the bank-specific trigger? One possibility, which we find appealing, would be based on the measures used to determine a bank’s capital adequacy, such as the ratio of Tier 1 capital to risk-adjusted assets.

I don’t like it, for reasons which have been discussed in my posts Contingent Capital: Reverse Convertible Debentures and Lloyds bank to Issue Contingent Capital with Tier 1 Ratio Trigger?. Tier 1 ratios are too easy for a bank and regulators to manipulate, do not measure the degree of investor confidence in an institution and do not provide a framework for market arbitrage. As a bank’s situation deteriorates, the price response of the hybrid should gradually become more-and-more equity-like, which suggests a market based approach rather than the binary now-it’s-debt-now-it’s-equity paradigm implied by an all-or-nothing conversion based on calculated figures. I have not seen anything yet to shake my belief that a fixed-rate conversion with a trigger based on the trading price of the common is the best solution.

The authors discuss the conversion rate:

In addition to the triggers, this new instrument will have to specify the rate at which the debt converts into equity. The conversion rate might depend, for example, on the market value of equity or on the market value of both equity and the hybrid security. Conversions based on market values, however, can create opportunities for manipulation. Bondholders might try to push the stock price down by shorting the stock, for example, so they would receive a larger slice of the equity in the conversion. Using the average stock price over a longer period, such as the past twenty days, to measure the value of equity makes this manipulation more difficult, but it opens the door for another manipulation. If the stock price falls precipitously during a systemic crisis, management might intentionally violate the trigger and force conversion at a stale price that now looks good to the stockholders. Finally, in some circumstances, a conversion ratio that depends on the stock price can lead to a “death spiral,” in which the dilution of the existing stockholders’ claims that would occur in a conversion lowers the stock price, which leads to more dilution, which lowers the price even further.

An alternative approach is to convert each dollar of debt into a fixed quantity of equity shares, rather than a fixed value of equity. There are at least two advantages of such an approach. First, because the number of shares to be issued in a conversion is fixed, death spirals are not a problem. Second, although management might consider triggering conversion (for example, by acquiring a large number of risky assets) to avoid a required interest or principal payment on the debt, this would not be optimal unless the stock price were so low that the shares to be issued were worth less than the bond payment. Thus, management would want to intentionally induce conversion only when the bank is struggling. The advantages and disadvantages of different conversion schemes are complicated, however, and will require both further study and detailed input from the financial and regulatory community.

It seems that they believe that a problem with the conversion at a fixed rate is the potential for manipulation of the trigger terms by management. This would be avoided with a market-based trigger.

Contingent Capital: Reverse Convertible Debentures

Saturday, October 31st, 2009

Mark J. Flannery Bank of America Eminent Scholar Chair of Finance at the University of Florida proposed Reverse Convertible Debentures in 2002 in his paper No Pain, No Gain? Effecting Market Discipline via “Reverse Convertible Debentures”:

The deadweight costs of financial distress limit many firms’ incentive to include a lot of (taxadvantaged) debt in their capital structures. It is therefore puzzling that firms do not make advance arrangements to re-capitalize themselves if large losses occur. Financial distress may be particularly important for large banking firms, which national supervisors are reluctant to let fail. The supervisors’ inclination to support large financial firms when they become troubled mitigates the ex ante incentives of market investors to discipline these firms. This paper proposes a new financial instrument that forestalls financial distress without distorting bank shareholders’ risk-taking incentives. “Reverse convertible debentures” (RCD) would automatically convert to common equity if a bank’s market capital ratio falls below some stated value. RCD provide a transparent mechanism for un-levering a firm if the need arises. Unlike conventional convertible bonds, RCD convert at the stock’s current market price, which forces shareholders to bear the full cost of their risk-taking decisions. Surprisingly, RCD investors are exposed to very limited credit risk under plausible conditions.

Of interest is the example of some Manny-Hanny bonds:

The case of Manufacturers Hanover (MH) in 1990 illustrates the problem. The bank had issued $85 million dollars worth of “mandatory preferred stock,” which was scheduled to convert to common shares in 1993. An earlier conversion would be triggered if MH’s share price closed below $16 for 12 out of 15 consecutive trading days (Hilder [1990]). Such forced conversion appeared possible in December 1990. In a letter to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York concerning the bank’s capital situation, MH’s CFO (Peter J. Tobin) expresses the bank’s extreme reluctance to permit conversion, or to issue new equity at current prices. At yearend 1990, MH’s book ratio of equity capital to total (on-book) assets was 5.57%, while its market equity ratio was 2.53%. The bank was also adamant in announcing that it would not omit its quarterly dividend. Despite the low market capital ratio, the Fed appeared unable to force MH to issue new equity. Chemical Bank acquired Manufacturers Hanover at the end of 1991.

When Manufacturers’ Hanover confronted a possible conversion of preferred stock in late 1990 (see footnote 6), they considered redeeming the issue using cash on hand. Such a “plan” only works if a supervisor will accept it. Under a market value trigger, such redemption would have to be financed by issuing equity; otherwise, the redemption would further lower the capital ratio. Another important feature of the MH convertible preferred issue was that the entire issue converted if common share prices were even $.01 too low over the specified time interval.

Flannery proposes the following design parameters for RCD:

RCD would have the following broad design features:

  • 1. They automatically convert into common equity if the issuer’s capital ratio falls below a pre-specified value.
  • 2. Unless converted into shares, RCD receive tax-deductible interest payments and are subordinated to all other debt obligations.
  • 3. The critical capital ratio is measured in terms of outstanding equity’s market value. (See Section III.)
  • 4. The conversion price is the current share price. Unlike traditional convertible bonds, one dollar of debentures (in current market value) would generally convert into one dollar’s worth of common stock.
  • 5. RCD incorporate no options for either investors or shareholders: conversion occurs automatically when the trigger is tripped.
  • 6. When debentures convert, the firm must promptly sell new RCD to replace the converted ones.

An example of RCD conversion is provided:

The bank in Figure 1 starts out at t = 0 with a minimally acceptable 8% capital ratio, backed by RCD equal to an additional 5% of total assets. With ten shares (“N”) outstanding, the initial share price (“PS”) is $0.80. By t = ½, the bank’s asset value has fallen to $97, leaving equity at $5.00 and the share price at $0.50. The bank is now under-capitalized ($5/$97 = 5.15% < 8%). Required capital is $7.76 (= 8% of $97). The balance sheet for t = 1 shows that $2.76 of RCD converted into equity to restore capital to 8% of assets. Given that PS = $0.50 at t = ½, RCD investors receive 5.52 shares in return for their $2.76 of bond claims. These investors lose no principal value when their debentures convert: they can sell their converted shares at $0.50 each and use the proceeds to re-purchase $2.76 worth of bonds. The initial shareholders lose the option to continue operating with low equity, because they must share the firm’s future cash flows with converted bondholders.

The critical part of this structure is that the triggering capital ratio values outstanding equity at market prices, rather than book. Additionally, not all – not necessarily even all of one issue – gets converted. Flannery suggests that issues be converted in the order of their issuance; first-in-first-out.

A substantial part of the paper consists of a defense of this market value feature, which I shall not reproduce here.

Flannery repeatedly touts a feature of the plan that I consider a bug:

Triggered by a frequently-evaluated ratio of equity’s market value to assets, RCD could be nearly riskless to the initial investors, while transmitting the full effect of poor investment outcomes to the shareholders who control the firm.

I don’t like the feature. I believe that a fixed-price conversion with a fixed-price trigger will aid in the analysis of this type of issue and make it easier for banks to sell equity above the trigger point – which is desirable! It is much better if the troubled bank can sell new equity to the public at a given price than to have the RCDs convert – Flannery worries about a requirement that the banks replace converted RCDs in short order, which is avoided if the trigger is avoided. If new equity prospects are not aware of their possible dilution if bad times become even worse, they will be less eager to buy.

Additionally, I am not enamoured of the use of regulatory asset weightings as a component of the trigger point. The last two years have made it very clear that there is a very wide range of values that may be assigned to illiquid assets; honest people can legitimately disagree, sometimes by amounts that are very material.

Market trust in the quality of the banks’ mark-to-market of its assets will be reflected, at least to some degree, by the Price/Book ratio. So let’s re-work Flannery’s Table 1 for two banks; both with the same initial capitalization; both of which mark down their assets by the same amount; but one of which maintains its Price/Book ratio (investors trust bank management) while the other’s P/B ratio declines (investors don’t trust bank management, or for some other reason believe that the end of the write-downs is yet to come).

Note that Flannery’s specification for the Market Ratio:

The market value equity ratio is the market value of common stock divided by the sum of (the book value of total liabilities plus the market value of common stock).

Two banks: t=0
Trusty Bank
Assets Liabilities
100 87 Deposits
5 RCD
8 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.80, Price = $1.20;
Market Ratio = 12/(87+5+12) = 11.5%
Sleazy Bank
Assets Liabilities
100 87 Deposits
5 RCD
8 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.80, Price = $1.20;
Market Ratio = 12/(87+5+12) = 11.5%

This is basically the same as Flannery’s example; however, he uses a constant P/B ratio of 1.0 to derive a Market Ratio of 8%. In addition, I will assume that the regulatory requirement for the Market Ratio is 10% – the two banks started with a cushion.

Disaster strikes at time t=0.5, when asset values decline by 3%. Trusty Bank’s P/B remains constant at 1.5, but Sleazy Bank’s P/B declines to 0.8.

Two banks: t=0.5
Trusty Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
5 RCD
5 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.50, Price = $0.75;
Market Ratio = 7.50 / (87+5+7.5) = 7.54%
Sleazy Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
5 RCD
5 Equity
N = 10, Book = $0.50, Price = $0.40;
Market Ratio = 4.00 / (87+5+4) = 4.17%

In order to get its Market Ratio back up to the 10% regulatory minimum that is assumed, Trusty Bank needs to solve the equation:

[7.5+x] / [87 + (5-x) + (7.5 + x)] = 0.10

where x is the Market Value of the new equity and is found to be equal to 2.45. With a stock price of 0.75, this is equal to 3.27 shares

Sleazy Bank solves the equation:

[4.0+x] / (87 + (5-x) + (4.0 +x)) = 0.10

and finds that x is 5.60. With a stock price of 0.40, this is equal to 14.00 shares.

Two banks: t=1.0
Trusty Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
2.55 RCD
7.45 Equity
N = 13.27, Book = $0.56, Price = $0.75;
Market Ratio = (13.27*0.75)/(87+2.55+(13.27*0.75)) = 10%
Sleazy Bank
Assets Liabilities
97 87 Deposits
-0.60 RCD
10.60 Equity
N = 24.00, Book = $0.44, Price = $0.40;
Market Ratio = (24*0.4)/(87-0.6+(24*0.4)) = 10%

Sleazy Bank doesn’t have the capital on hand – as shown by the negative value of balance sheet RCD at t=1 – so it goes bust instead. In effect, there has been a bank run instigated not by depositors but by shareholders.

Note that in the calculations I have assumed that the price of the common does not change as a result of the dilution; this alters the P/B ratio. Trusty Bank’s P/B moves from 1.50 to 1.34; Sleazy Bank’s P/B (ignoring the effect of the negative value of the RCDs) moves from 0.8 to 0.91. Whether or not the assumption of constant market price is valid in the face of the dilution is a topic that can be discussed at great length.

I will note that the Price/Book ratio of Japanese banks in early 2008 was 0.32:1 and Citigroup’s P/B ratio is currently 0.67:1.

While Dr. Flannery’s idea has its attractions, I am very hesitant about the idea of mixing book and market values. From a theoretical viewpoint, capital is intended to be permanent, which implies that once the bank has its hands on the money, it doesn’t really care all that much about the price its capital trades at in the market.

Using a fixed conversion price, with a fixed market price trigger keeps the separation of book accounting from market pricing in place, which offers greater predictability to banks, investors and potential investors in times of trouble.

Update 2009-11-1: Arithmetical error corrected in table.

It should also be noted that the use of market value of equity in calculating regulatory ratios makes the proposal as it stands extremely procyclical.

Lloyds Bank to Issue Contingent Capital with Tier 1 Ratio Trigger?

Friday, October 30th, 2009

Lloyds Banks has announced:

Lloyds Banking Group (Lloyds) notes recent media speculation regarding its proposed potential participation in the Government Asset Protection Scheme (GAPS). Lloyds is in advanced discussions with HM Treasury, UK Financial Investments and the Financial Services Authority regarding alternatives to participation in GAPS.

Lloyds believes that any alternative proposals to GAPS would be likely to include a substantial capital raising of core tier 1 and contingent core tier 1 capital to increase the Group’s capital ratios to an appropriate level of strength and flexibility, and would provide a strong capital base for the future stability and success of the Group. The alternative proposals would also meet the FSA’s requirements for stressed economic conditions.

Capital raising options currently under consideration include a combination of raising immediately available core tier 1 capital by way of a rights issue and generating contingent core tier 1 and/or core tier 1 capital through the exchange of certain existing Group capital securities.

Media speculation, indeed! Wealth Bulletin reports (note that the WSJ credits Duncan Kerr of Financial News for this interview):

Owen Murfin, global fixed-income manager at BlackRock in London, said that Lloyds’ plan to generate contingent capital through an exchange would only work at “attractive levels” but that if the transaction does go well, “it will probably form the template of the future of hybrid bank capital, or certainly the shape of capital going forward”.

Murfin added that for investors to get fully behind it, some key issues needed to be addressed, such as what will be used as the triggers, and who or what will decide when these measures have been breached.

He said: “Core tier-one is probably going to be the most likely trigger used. The existing regulatory minimum is around 4%, so the level would probably have to be above that and somewhere around 5%. Core tier-one capital would then be replenished at a far higher level as a result of the conversion.

Reuters also suggests a Tier 1 Ratio Trigger, but with no attribution:

The conversion trigger needs to be set low enough that it is unlikely to be reached, but high enough that it provides help before a bank hits crisis point. That could see it triggered when the Core Tier 1 equity falls below 5 or 6 percent, depending on new industry standards under discussion.

FT Alphaville quotes JPM analysts Carla Antunes da Silva and Amit Goel musing that:

What are the challenges? Several uncertainties surround these instruments including (i) setting appropriate trigger points; (ii) pricing the instruments such that they are attractive to both investors and the issuing institutions; and (iii) market treatment in terms of share count/equity.

I have real problems with using Tier 1 Capital Ratios as a trigger for conversion. Accrued Interest points out:

Look at Lehman. They had a Tier 1 ratio of 11 just weeks before they were bankrupt. Their problem was part their funding mix which was very reliant on repo and prime brokerage, and part the fact that the market didn’t believe their valuations on some illiquid assets. Maybe had either of those circumstances been different, i.e, the same leverage and assets but a more stable funding mix, they would have survived. Regardless, a regulator scheme based on leverage ratios never would have caught Lehman before it was too late. Nominally, they had plenty of capital.

This is why the idea of contingent capital makes so much sense to me. A bank has a ready set of equity investors whenever its needed. It instills market discipline, as the current stock price would reflect the potential for dilution, but the falling stock price wouldn’t prevent a capital raise. In effect, this is a little like a standard bankruptcy, where bond holders take control of a company, except that instead of the company actually going through such a disruptive process, ownership just transfers (in part) to the contingent capital bondholders automatically.

More generally than the anecdotal Lehman example, the IMF looked at various bail-out predictors in Chapter 3 of the April 09 GFSR:

The results in Table 3.1 show the following:

  • • Capital adequacy ratios were unable to clearly identify institutions requiring intervention. In fact, contrary to the common belief that low capital adequacy ratios would signal weakness for a FI, all four capital adequacy ratios examined for intervened commercial banks were significantly higher than (or similar to) the nonintervened commercial banks as a whole (Figure 3.1). There are, of course, regional differences among nonintervened commercial banks. During 2005:Q1–2007:Q2, the capital-to-assets ratio for nonintervened commercial banks in Asia and the euro area were higher than for intervened commercial banks. However this was not the case for FIs in the noneuro area. This suggests that regional differences can make direct comparisons problematic.
  • • Several basic indicators of leverage appear to be informative in identifying the differences in the institutions, although the reasons for this deserve further examination. The higher ratios of debt to common equity, and short term debt to total debt in the intervened commercial banks and intervened investment banks, all indicate that these measures of leverage are especially informative about the differences (Figure 3.2).
  • • Traditional liquidity ratios are not very indicative of the differences between intervened and nonintervened institutions. In part, this is because these liquidity ratios may not be able to fully measure wholesale funding risks.
  • • Asset quality indicators show a mixed picture. Similar to the capital adequacy ratios, the ratio of nonperforming loans (NPL) to total loans for the intervened commercial banks has been lower than for the nonintervened commercial banks, indicating that NPL ratios are not very reliable indicators of the deterioration in asset quality. However, the lower provisions for the loan-losses-to-total-loans ratio for the nonintervened commercial banks suggests that this is a better indicator
    than the NPL ratio.

  • • The standard measures of earnings and profits show a mixed picture. While return on assets (ROA) for the intervened institutions are much higher than those in the nonintervened commercial banks, suggesting that elevated risks are associated with higher returns, return on equity (ROE) has not captured any major differences between the FIs that were intervened or not (Figure 3.3). This contrast between the effectiveness in ROA and ROE may reflect the high leverage ratio of intervened FIs, which typically rely on higher levels of debt to produce profits.
  • • Stock market indicators are able to capture some differences. The price-to-earnings ratios, earning per share, and book value per share of the intervened investment banks have been generally higher than those in the nonintervened commercial banks, which suggest that the higher equity prices and earnings do not necessarily reflect healthier institutions, but perhaps concomitant higher risks.

I confess that I don’t understand the last point very well. Book value per share? Earnings per share? Surely these simply reflect the number of shares issued against the size of the bank. If they discussed Price-to-Book ratios, that would be one thing, but they don’t. They do, however, include Price/Earnings ratio in the various tests and find it does not discriminate between bailed-out and non-bailed-out banks.

My objection to using Capital Ratios as a trigger point is simply that they haven’t worked very well in this crisis: all the failed banks met the capital tests before being bailed out. This does not mean that I disdain Capital Ratios. On the contrary, I think they’re the single most valuable metric for quantifying the strength of a bank. “Single most”, however, has a different meaning from “Only required”. It is now accepted that a blunt leverage ratio – in Canada, the Assets to Capital multiple – is a very useful additional tool; I will not be at all surprised to see a metric based on liquidity introduced at some point.

Why do bank runs happen? Confidence. During the crisis, nobody trusted capital ratios because they are dependent upon the degree to which markdowns on bad assets had been taken; if you did not trust the accounting, you did not trust the capital ratio and – critically – you sold the stock.

I continue to believe that the most appropriate trigger is simply the common stock’s trading price. As I stated in my commentary on the HM Treasury response to the Turner Report, this has the advantage of being known in advance; no judgement by the regulatory authorities is required and therefore, in a crisis, there won’t be the chance of the market attempting to second-guess just what the authorities’ decision really means. The advantage of known conversion triggers will also allow a certain amount of arbitrage, which will boost liquidity for these instruments at a time when we may assume that such liquidity will be sorely needed.

For instance, to take my basic idea of a new issue of contingent-equity preferreds, issued at $25 at a time when the common is trading (for convenience in referring to the exchange ratio) at $50. The preferred converts to common on a one-to-one basis if the monthly (quarterly?) volume-weighted-average-price of the common dips below $25; that being the exchange price, set to one-half of the common’s price at the time when the preferred was issued.

Should bad times come and the common starts trading in the high twenties, it may well be imagined that puts on the common with a $25 strike will become very popular, going some way towards transferring the income from the prefs into the hands of speculators who don’t mind taking a chance. The preferreds will trade more and more like equity, in a smooth and transparent manner, as the equity price declines. Isn’t this exactly what the doctor ordered?

It should also be noted that the bank bailouts resulted in Tier 1 Capital NEVER falling below regulatory minima, although I have no figures on how close it got. This was a deliberate feature of the plan – the fiscal authorities didn’t want the banks to get shut down. However, this raises the spectre of the potential for a bank to be bailed out before the conversion trigger is reached, which would be a Bad Thing. Conversion is much more likely to be triggered by a decline in the price of the common.

We’ll see how it all turns out. But I think that Tier 1 Ratio triggers are simply a Bad Idea for contingent capital.

I will note that Bernanke mentioned contingent capital in passing near the end of his testimony to the House Committee on Financial Services, 2009-10-1:

In addition, we are working with our fellow regulatory agencies toward the development of capital standards and other supervisory tools that would be calibrated to the systemic importance of the firm. Options under consideration in this area include requiring systemically important institutions to hold aggregate levels of capital above current regulatory norms or to maintain a greater share of capital in the form of common equity or instruments with similar loss-absorbing attributes, such as “contingent” capital that converts to common equity when necessary to mitigate systemic risk.

Contingent Capital has been discussed often on PrefBlog of late:

OFSI Joins Contingent Capital Bandwagon

Tarullo Confronts ‘Too Big To Fail’

Dudley of FRBNY Supports Contingent Capital

HM Treasury Responds to Turner Report

OSFI Joins Contingent Capital Bandwagon

Wednesday, October 28th, 2009

The Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions (OSFI) has released a speech by Julie Dickson to the C.D. Howe Institute titled Considerations along the Path to Financial Regulatory Reform.

The most important part was the section on contingent capital:

Explore the use of contingent capital. This refers to sizeable levels of lower quality capital that could convert into high quality capital at pre-specified points, and clearly before an institution could receive government support. Such conversions could make use of triggers in the terms of a bank’s lower quality capital, while the bank remains a going-concern. This would add market discipline for even the largest banks during good times (as common shareholders could be significantly diluted in an adverse scenario), while stabilizing the situation by recapitalizing such banks if they fall on hard times. Boards and management of these recapitalized banks could be replaced. Issues to be studied to make such a proposal operational include grandfathering of existing lower quality securities, and/or transitioning towards new features in lower quality securities, considering capital markets implications of changing the terms of lower quality capital and the selection of triggers, and determining the amounts and market for such instruments.

Contingent capital was first proposed in such a form – as far as I know! – in HM Treasury’s response to the Turner Report.

Under the heading Making Failure a Viable Option, she advocates:

More control of counterparty risk via capital rules and limits, so that imposing losses on major institutions who are debt holders in a failed financial institution does not prove fatal.

It is possible that this might be an attack on the utterly ridiculous Basel II risk weighting of bank paper according to the credit rating of the bank’s supervisor; that is, paper issued by a US bank is risk-weighted according to the credit rating of the US, which is perhaps the most difficult thing to understand about the Basel Rules. If the regulators are serious about reducing systemic risk, then paper issued by other financial institutions should attract a higher risk weighting than that of a credit-equivalent non-financial firm, not less.

I have often remarked on the Bank of Canada’s attempts to expand its bureaucratic turf throughout the crisis; two can play at that game!

one could try to experiment and adjust capital requirements up or down based on macro indicators. But, the challenge will be how to make a regime which ties macro indicators to capital effective. Indeed, in upturns in the domestic market where capital targets are increased due to macro factors, companies would have the option to obtain loans from banks in countries with less robust economic conditions, as banks in that country will have lower requirements. Thus, an increase in capital in the domestic market might not have the desired impact of slowing things down.

Alternatively, because many countries have well developed financial sectors, borrowers can go beyond the regulated financial sector to find money, as regulated financial institutions are not the only game in town.

Umm … hello? The objective of varying credit requirements is to strengthen the banks should there be a possible downturn; the Greenspan thesis is that it is extremely difficult to tell if you’re in a bubble while you’re in the middle of it (and therefore, you do more damage by prevention than is done by cure) has attracted academic support (as well as being simple common sense; if a bubble was obvious, it wouldn’t exist).

Most authorities agree that Central Banks have the responsibility for “slowing things down” via monetary policy; OSFI should stick to its knitting and concentrate on assuring the relative health of the regulated financial sector it regulates.

Of particular interest is her disagreement with one element of Treasury’s wish-list:

Yes, regulators should try to assess systemic risk. But no, we should not try to define systemically important financial institutions.

The IMF work on identifying systemic institutions rightly points out that what is systemic in one situation may not be in another, and that there is considerable judgement involved.

Ms. Dickson also made several remarks about market discipline, which should not be taken seriously.

Update: I’ve been trying to find the “IMF work” referred to in the last quoted paragraph; so far, my best guess is Chapter 3 of the April ’09 Global Financial Stability Report:

Cascade effects. Another use of the joint probability distribution is the probability of cascade effects, which examines the likelihood that one or more FIs in the system become distressed given that a specific FI becomes distressed. It is a useful indicator to quantify the systemic importance of a specific FI, since it provides a direct measure of its effect on the system as a whole. As an example, the probability of cascade effects is estimated given that Lehman or AIG became distressed. These probabilities reached 97 percent and 95, respectively, on September 12, 2008, signaling a possible “domino” effect in the days after Lehman’s collapse (Figure 3.10). Note that the probability of cascade effects for both institutions had already increased by August 2007, well before Lehman collapsed.

The IMF Country Report No. 09/229 – United States: Selected Issues points out:

It remains to be seen how the Federal Reserve, in consultation with the Treasury, will draw up rules to guide the identification of systemic firms to be brought under its purview, and how the FSOC will ensure that remaining intermediaries are monitored from a broader financial stability perspective. Although the criteria for Tier 1 FHC status appropriately include leverage and interconnectedness as well as size, identifying systemic institutions ex ante will remain a difficult task (cf., AIG).

I have sent an inquiry to OSFI asking for a specific reference.

Update, 2009-11-9: OSFI’s bureaucrats have not seen fit to respond to my query, but the Bank for International Settlements has just published the Report to G20 Finance Ministers and Governors: Guidance to Assess the Systemic Importance of Financial Institutions, Markets and Instruments: Initial Considerations which includes the paragraph:

The assessment is likely to be time-varying depending on the economic environment. Systemic importance will depend significantly on the specifics of the economic environment at the time of assessment. Structural trends and the cyclical factors will influence the outcome of the assessment. For instance, under weak economic conditions there is a higher probability that losses will be correlated and failures in even relatively unimportant elements of the financial sector could become triggers for more general losses of confidence. A loss of confidence is often associated with uncertainty of asset values, and can manifest in a contagious “run” on short-run liabilities of financial institutions, or more generally, in a loss of funding for key components of the system. The dependence of the assessment on the specific economic and financial environment has implications about the frequency with which such assessments should take place, with the need for more frequent assessments to take account of new information when financial systems are under stress or where material changes in the environment or the business and risk profile of the individual component have taken place.

It is regrettable that OSFI does not have a sufficiently scholarly approach to its work to provide references in the published version of Julie Dickson’s speeches – or that she would not insist on such an approach. It is equally regrettable that OSFI is unable to answer a simple question regarding such a reference within a day or so.

Tarullo Confronts 'Too Big to Fail'

Friday, October 23rd, 2009

Daniel K Tarullo, Member of the Board of Governors of the US Federal Reserve System, has delivered a speech to the Exchequer Club, Washington DC, 21 October 2009:

Generally applicable capital and other regulatory requirements do not take account of the specifically systemic consequences of the failure of a large institution. It is for this reason that many have proposed a second kind of regulatory response – a special charge, possibly a special capital requirement, based on the systemic importance of a firm. Ideally, this requirement would be calibrated so as to begin to bite gradually as a firm’s systemic importance increased, so as to avoid the need for identifying which firms are considered too-big-to-fail and, thereby, perhaps increasing moral hazard.

While very appealing in concept, developing an appropriate metric for such a requirement is not an easy exercise. There is much attention being devoted to this effort – within the U.S. banking agencies, in international fora, and among academics – but at this moment there is no specific proposal that has gathered a critical mass of support.

I support the idea of assessing a progressive surcharge on risk-weighted assets such that, for instance, RWA in excess of $250-billion wiould be increased by 10% for capital calculation purposes, RWA in excess of $300-billion another 10% on top of that, and so on. Very few formal ideas have been proposed in this line; the US Treasury wish-list does not mention such an idea but endorses a special regime for those institutions deemed too big to fail.

A second kind of market discipline initiative is a requirement that large financial firms have specified forms of “contingent capital.” Numerous variants on this basic idea have been proposed over the past several years. While all are intended to provide a firm with an increased capital buffer from private sources at the moment when it is most needed, some also hold significant promise of injecting market discipline into the firm. For example, a regularly issued special debt instrument that would convert to equity during times of financial distress could add market discipline both through the pricing of newly issued instruments and through the interests of current shareholders in avoiding dilution.

I heartily endorse this idea, which was first proposed by HM Treasury in its response to the Turner report and endorsed by William Dudley of the New York Fed. It looks like this idea is gaining some traction!

To my gratification, he does not forget to mention the systemic risk posed by money market funds:

Of course, financial instability can occur even in the absence of serious too-big-to-fail problems. Other reform measures – such as regulating derivatives markets and money market funds – are thus also important to pursue.