Archive for the ‘Contingent Capital’ Category

Dudley of FRBNY Supports Contingent Capital

Wednesday, October 14th, 2009

The British government indicated interest in a debt security that would convert to capital in times of stress, as discussed in the post HM Treasury Responds to Turner Report.

Such an instrument is of interest to preferred share investors since preferred shares are the natural basis for the first wave of such instruments. For example, a preferred share issued at a time when the bank’s common equity was trading at $50 might have a provision that, should the common price fall below $25 for a specific period of time (say, the Volume Weighted Average Price for any given period of twenty consecutive trading days), then the preferred would automatically convert into common, receiving its full face value of common valued at $25 per share.

Now William C Dudley, President and Chief Executive Officer of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, has delivered a speech titled Some Lessons from the Financial Crisis indicating support for the general idea:

the introduction of a contingent capital instrument seems likely to hold real promise. Relative to simply raising capital requirements, contingent capital has the potential to be more efficient because the capital arrives as equity only in the bad states of the world when it is needed. It also has the benefit of improving incentives by creating two-way risk for bank managements and shareholders. If the bank encounters difficulties, triggering conversion, shareholders would be automatically and immediately diluted. This would create strong incentives for bank managements to manage not only for good outcomes on the upside of the boom, but also against bad outcomes on the downside.

Conceptually, contingent capital instruments would be debt instruments in “good” states of the world, but would convert into common equity at pre-specified trigger levels in “bad” states of the world. In principle, these triggers could be tied to deterioration in the condition of the specific banking institution and/or to the banking system as a whole.

There are many issues that would need to be worked out regarding how best to design such instruments, including how to determine their share of total capital as well as how to configure and publicly disclose the conversion terms and trigger. But, in my view, allowing firms to issue contingent capital instruments that could be used to augment their common equity capital during a downturn may be a more straightforward and efficient way to achieve a countercyclical regulatory capital regime compared to trying to structure minimum regulatory capital requirements (or capital buffers above those requirements) that decline as conditions in the financial sector worsen.

So what might such a contingent capital instrument look like? One possibility is a debt instrument that is convertible into common shares if and only if the performance of the bank deteriorates sharply. While, in principal, this could be tied solely to regulatory measures of capital, it might work better tied to market-based measures because market-based measures tend to lead regulatory-based measures. Also, if tied to market-based measures, there would be greater scope for adjustment of the conversion terms in a way to make the instruments more attractive to investors and, hence, lower cost capital instruments to the issuer. The conversion terms could be generous to the holder of the contingent capital instrument. For example, one might want to set the conversion terms so that the debt holders could expect to get out at or close to whole – at par value. This is important because it would reduce the cost of the contingent instrument, making it a considerably cheaper form of capital than common equity.

Consider the advantages that such an instrument would have had during this crisis. Rather than banks clumsily evaluating whether to cut dividends, raise common equity and/or conduct exchanges of common equity for preferred shares and market participants uncertain about the willingness and ability of firms to complete such transactions and successfully raise new capital, contingent capital would have been converted automatically into common equity when market triggers were hit.

He also had some things to say about dividends:

In times of stress, banks may have incentives to continue to pay dividends to show they are strong even when they are not. This behavior depletes the bank’s capital and makes the bank weaker. To correct this shortcoming in our system, we should craft policies that either incent or require weak and vulnerable firms to cut dividends quickly in order to conserve capital. This would introduce a dampening mechanism into our system.

I don’t know about this. It gives a lot of discretion to the regulators – or requires the imposition of rules that will of necessity be so complex as to be useless during the next crisis – and the regulators have shown they are not up to the task.

Now that the moment has passed, they are getting tough on banks that are already mostly nationalized, but throughout the crisis they have routinely approved the redemption of sub-debt, which is particularly galling since the sub-debt was virtually all resetting to yields less than that required to issue new senior debt.

It would have been the easiest thing in the world for regulators to have announced that the required approval for subordinated debt redemption would be withheld in cases where this would have reduced the total capital ratio below – say – 12%. Such an announcement would have been transparent, recognized as being arguably justified and not to be considered a regulatory judgement on the soundness of any particular bank.

But they muffed it, rubber-stamped their approvals and blew their credibility.

HM Treasury Responds to Turner Report

Monday, September 28th, 2009

The Turner Report on Financial Regulation was reported on PrefBlog in March. The government has now taken some time off from its regularly scheduled banker-bashing to address the issues raised.

The response was released on July 8 with the admission:

There were many causes of the financial crisis:

  • first and foremost, failures of market discipline, in particular of corporate governance, risk management, and remuneration policies. Some banks, boards and investors did not fully understand the complexities of their own businesses;
  • second, regulators and central banks did not sufficiently take account of the excessive risks being taken on by some firms, and did not adequately understand the extent of system-wide risk; and
  • third, the failure of global regulatory standards to respond to the major changes in the financial markets, which have increased complexity and system-wide risk, or to the tendency for system-wide risks to build up during economic upswings.

… which is a lot more balanced than what they spout for the benefit of the man in the street.

The British firm Barrow, Lyde & Gilbert has prepared a precis of the government response; there are, however, two proposals in the full-length report worthy of highlighting for preferred share investors:

Box 6.C: New international ideas for improving access to funding markets

Two ideas to improve banks access to capital during downturns or crises are being aired in academic and policy circles. Both have merits although how they could be applied in practice is yet to be determined.

Capital insurance:Banks essentially face an insurance problem: when faced with a shortage of capital, rather than having to raise new capital at a high market cost it would be more efficient if banks were delivered capital at a pre-agreed (lower) price though a pre-funded insurance policy. Paying the insurance premium in an expansion would be one method of providing some cost to the expansion of credit in an upturn. However, in a systemic crisis the insurance policy would need to pay out to several banks together. In order to ensure that these obligations could always be met, the insurance would probably need to be run by the state sector.

Debt-equity conversion: When banks are forced to raise new equity capital the initial benefits are shared with the existing debt holders as they have a senior claim over equity in the event of liquidation. One solution would be to make some of the debt (perhaps the subordinated debt tranche only) convertible into equity in the event of a systemic crisis and on the authority of the financial regulator. This would immediately inject capital into the bank and reduce the need to raise any new equity capital. The holders of the debt would also have more incentive to impose market discipline on the banks.

The reference supplied for the second option is “Building an incentive-compatible safety net”, C. Calomiris, in Journal of Banking and Finance, 1999; this article is available for purchase from Science Direct and is freely available in HTML form from the American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. Assuming that the AEI transcript is reliable, though, I see very little support for the idea in the Calomiris paper (Calomiris’ ideas are frequently discussed on PrefBlog, but I certainly don’t remember seeing this one).

Regardless of origin, I consider this a fine idea at bottom, although I am opposed to the idea that the triggering mechanism be a ruling by regulatory authorities. I suggest that greater certainty for investors, regulators and issuers could be achieved with little controversy if conversion were to be triggered instead by the trading price of the bank’s common.

In such a world, regulators approving a preferred share for inclusion in Tier 1 Capital would require a forced conversion at some percentage of the current common price if the volume-weighted trading price for a calendar month (quarter?) was below that conversion price. Thus, assuming the chosen percentage was 50%, if RY were to issue preferreds at $25 par value at a time when its common was trading at $50, there would be forced conversion of prefs into common on a 1:1 basis if the common traded below $25 for the required period.

This could bring about interesting arbitrage plays with options – so much the better!

One effect would be that as the common traded lower – presumably in response to Bad Things happening at the company – the preferred share would start behaving more and more like an equity itself – which is precisely what we want.

We shall see, but I hope this idea gains some traction in the halls of power.

Update: Dr. Calomiris has very kindly responded to my query:

Yes, the citation of my work is relevant to the proposal, although it takes a little explaining to see the connection. I have been advocating the use of some form of uninsured debt requirement as part of capital requirements for a long time. The conversion of hybrid idea is a new version of that, which has the advantages of my proposal and also some additional advantages that Mark Flannery and others have pointed to. I like the idea of requiring a minimal amount of “contingent capital” which would take the form of sub debt that converts into equity in adverse circumstances.

You may quote me.

Treasury Announces Bank Capitalization Wish-List

Thursday, September 3rd, 2009

Treasury has announced:

the core principles that should guide reform of the international regulatory capital and liquidity framework to better protect the safety and soundness of individual banking firms and the stability of the global financial system and economy.

There are eight of these core principles given a brief explanation in the detailed announcement:

Core Principle #1: Capital requirements should be designed to protect the stability of the financial system (as well as the solvency of individual banking firms).

Among other things, a macro-prudential approach to regulation means: (i) reducing the extent to which the capital and accounting frameworks permit risk to accumulate in boom times, exacerbating the volatility of credit cycles; (ii) incorporating features that encourage or force banking firms to build larger capital cushions in good times; (iii) raising capital requirements for bank and non-bank financial firms that pose a threat to financial stability because of their combination of size, leverage, interconnectedness, and liquidity risk (Tier 1 FHCs) and for systemically risky exposure types; and (iv) improving the ability of banking firms to withstand firm-specific and system-wide liquidity shocks that can set off deleveraging spirals.

The document refers to Tier 1 FHCs quite often, raising the disquieting potential that this status will officially bestowed, which is the wrong thing to do. Instead, it would be far superior to (i) assign a progressive surcharge onto Risk-Weighted Assets as the firm gets larger; e.g., if RWA=$250-billion, no surcharge; 10% surcharge on the next $50-billion; 20% on the next $50-billion; and so on. A dual-track regime (one for Tier 1 FHCs, another for also-rans) is just going to create problems; and (ii) eliminate the favoured status of bank paper in the risk-weighting, so that banks in general hold less of each other’s paper.

Core Principle #2: Capital requirements for all banking firms should be higher, and capital requirements for Tier 1 FHCs should be higher than capital requirements for other banking firms.

See above

Core Principle #3: The regulatory capital framework should put greater emphasis on higher quality forms of capital.

For these reasons, during good economic conditions, common equity should constitute a large majority of a banking firm’s tier 1 capital, and tier 1 capital should constitute a large majority of a banking firm’s total regulatory capital. In addition, the inclusion in regulatory capital of deferred tax assets and non-equity hybrid and other innovative securities should be subject to strict, internationally consistent qualitative and quantitative limits.
We also consider it important that voting common equity represent a large majority of a banking firm’s tier 1 capital.

In other words, they don’t like the extent to which preferred shares and Innovative Tier 1 Capital have been used and they really dislike sub-debt.

Core Principle #4: Risk-based capital requirements should be a function of the relative risk of a banking firm’s exposures, and risk-based capital ratios should better reflect a banking firm’s current financial condition.

Among other things, we must reduce to the extent possible the vulnerabilities that may arise from excessive regulatory reliance on internal banking firm models or ratings from credit rating agencies to measure risk.
Risk weights should be a function of the asset-specific risk of the various exposure types, but they also should reflect the systemic importance of the various exposure types. From a macro-prudential perspective, exposure types that exhibit a high correlation with the economic cycle, or whose prevalence is likely to contribute disproportionately to financial instability in times of economic stress, should attract higher risk-based capital charges than other exposure types that have the same level of expected risk. One of the key examples of a systemically risky exposure type during the recent crisis was the structured finance credit protection purchased by many banking firms from AIG, the monoline insurance companies, and other thinly capitalized special purpose derivatives products companies.

I think that this is as close as Treasury will every get to admitting it goofed big-time on allowing uncollateralized leverage credit protection to offset cash positions.

Core Principle #5: The procyclicality of the regulatory capital and accounting regimes should be reduced and consideration should be given to introducing countercyclical elements into the regulatory capital regime.

The regulatory capital and accounting frameworks should be modified in several ways to reduce their procyclicality. First, the regulatory capital regime should require banking firms to hold a buffer over their minimum capital requirements during good economic times (to be available for drawing down in bad economic times).

There’s a possibility that good times and bad times might become something of a political football, isn’t there? We should not forget that one reason why the FDIC has to increase rates charged to banks right now is because Congress gave a long contribution holiday for political reasons.

I am gratified to see:

Finally, we should examine the merits of providing favorable regulatory capital treatment for, or requiring some banking firms (such as Tier 1 FHCs) to issue, appropriately designed contingent capital instruments – including (i) long-term debt instruments that convert to equity capital in stressed conditions; or (ii) fully secured insurance arrangements that pay out to banking firms in stressed conditions.

See my essay on insurers’ risk transformation.

Core Principle #6: Banking firms should be subject to a simple, non-risk-based leverage constraint.

To mitigate potential adverse effects from an overly simplistic leverage constraint, the constraint should at a minimum incorporate off-balance sheet items.

They couldn’t get the Europeans to agree to the leverage ratio last time, and now they’re MAD!

Core Principle #7: Banking firms should be subject to a conservative, explicit liquidity standard.

The liquidity regime should be independent from the regulatory capital regime. The liquidity regime should make both individual banking firms and the broader financial system more resilient by limiting the externalities that banking firms can create by taking on imprudent levels and forms of funding mismatch. Introducing strict but flexible liquidity regulations would reduce the chances of destabilizing runs by enhancing the ability of debtor banking firms to withstand withdrawals of short-term funding and by making creditor banking firms less likely to withdraw short-term funding from other firms.

Much of this would be addressed by eliminating the favourable risk-weighting applied to inter-bank holdings, as noted above.

Core Principle #8: Stricter capital requirements for the banking system should not result in the re-emergence of an under-regulated non-bank financial sector that poses a threat to financial stability.

Money market mutual funds will be subject to tighter regulation, including tighter regulation of their credit and liquidity risks.

Basically, they want to regulate everything that moves, which will have bad effects on the economy. They should spend more time properly regulating the boundary between banks and non-banks, so that shadow-bank collapses will not have a severe effect on the highly regulated core banking system.