Issue Comments

ALA.PR.A Rockets to Premium on Massive Volume

AltaGas Ltd. has announced:

it has closed its previously announced public offering of 8,000,000 Cumulative Redeemable Five-Year Rate Reset Preferred Shares, Series A (the “Series A Preferred Shares”) at a price of $25 per Series A Preferred Share (the “Offering”). The Offering resulted in AltaGas receiving gross proceeds of $200 million.

The Offering was first announced on August 10, 2010 when AltaGas entered into an agreement with a syndicate of underwriters, led by TD Securities Inc., RBC Capital Markets and CIBC World Markets Inc.
Net proceeds from the Offering will be used to reduce outstanding indebtedness under AltaGas’ credit facilities, thereby strengthening AltaGas’ balance sheet and giving it the financial flexibility to support, among other things, construction activities related to the Forrest Kerr project.

The Series A Preferred Shares will commence trading today on the Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbol ALA.PR.A.

The offering was super-sized from $150-million to $200-million, announced, August 10.

ALA.PR.A was announced as a FixedReset 5.00%+266 on August 10.

It traded 989,638 shares today in a range of 25.19-42 before closing at 25.38-44, 17×50.

Vital statistics are:

ALA.PR.A FixedReset YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.38
Bid-YTW : 4.69 %
Interesting External Papers

BoC Releases Summer 2010 Review

The Bank of Canada has released the Bank of Canada Review: Summer 2010 with articles:

  • Lessons Learned from Research on Infl ation Targeting
  • Monetary Policy and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates
  • Price-Level Targeting and Relative-Price Shocks
  • Should Monetary Policy Be Used to Counteract Financial Imbalances?
  • Conference Summary: New Frontiers in Monetary Policy Design

The Financial Imbalances article points out:

Another potentially important cost of leaning against
fi nancial imbalances stems from the difficulty of identifying them and of calibrating an appropriate response. If fi nancial imbalances are falsely identified, responding to them through monetary policy could induce undesirable economic fluctuations (Greenspan 2002; Bernanke and Gertler 1999).

The question, according to the authors, is:

Granted that appropriate supervision and regulation
are the fi rst line of defence against financial imbalances, the key question is whether they should be the only one. In this context, developing a view on whether monetary policy should lean against financial imbalances requires that we first examine the interaction between the effects of prudential tools and those of monetary policy on fi nancial imbalances that stem from various sources.

A credit-fuelled housing bubble is a particularly relevant example of a fi nancial imbalance. This section considers the case of over-exuberance in the housing sector, represented as a temporary increase in the perceived value of housing that results in a short-term surge in mortgage credit. This example is calibrated to produce housing-market dynamics that are roughly similar to those of the housing market in the United States in the run-up to the recent crisis. Specifically, the size of the shock is set at 5 per cent of the value of housing collateral; this leads to an average increase in mortgage debt in the first year of about 16 per cent, comparable with the average annual growth rate of mortgage debt over the 2003–06 period.

We evaluate the relative merits of using monetary policy to contain this imbalance and compare it with a well-targeted prudential instrument—namely, an adjustment in the mortgage loan-to-value (LTV) ratio.

The authors have the fortitude to emphasize:

As mentioned in the introduction, one important argument against using monetary policy as a tool in these situations is that fi nancial imbalances cannot be detected with certainty. This uncertainty applies not only to monetary policy, but also to prudential policy, and should play a role in determining how forcefully to react to the prospect of building financial imbalances.

By me, this is such an important consideration that it virtually negates the concept of leaning against the flow. I am in favour of a progressive surcharge on banks’ Risk Weighted Assets based on how much these have changed over the past few years, but that’s based more on management factors than economic ones.

By definition, a bubble will have lots of defenders ready to explain why it is not a bubble, as discussed recently in FRBB: Bubbles Happen. Trying to nip bubbles in bud on the basis of a bureaucrat deciding that eggs should cost $2.99 a dozen and $3.25 is too much is fraught with dangers.

Contingent Capital

BIS Proposes CoCos: Regulatory Trigger, Infinite Dilution

The Bank for International Settlement has released a Proposal to ensure the loss absorbency of regulatory capital at the point of non-viability – consultative document:

the proposal is specifically structured to allow each jurisdiction (and banks) the freedom to implement it in a way that will not conflict with national law or any other constraints. For example, a conversion rate is not specified, nor is the choice between implementation through a write-off or conversion. Any attempt to define the specific implementation of the proposal more rigidly at an international level, than the current minimum set out in this document, risks creating conflicts with national law and may be unnecessarily prescriptive.

The Basel Committee welcomes comments on all aspects of the proposal set out in this consultative document. Comments should be submitted by 1 October 2010 by email to: baselcommittee@bis.org.

However, if we define gone-concern also to include situations in which the public sector provides support to distressed banks that would otherwise have failed, the financial crisis has revealed that many regulatory capital instruments do not always absorb losses in gone-concern situations.

That’s a nice little definition of “gone concern”, giving bureaucrats the authority to ursurp the prerogatives of the legal system. One thousand years of bankruptcy law … pffffft!

The proposal will be examined clause by clause:

All non-common Tier 1 instruments and Tier 2 instruments at internationally active banks must have a clause in their terms and conditions that requires them to be written-off on the occurrence of the trigger event.

Reasonable enough.

Any compensation paid to the instrument holders as a result of the write-off must be paid immediately in the form of common stock (or its equivalent in the case of non-joint stock companies).

This means that write-down structure’s like Rabobank’s would not, of themselves, qualify for inclusion. There would need to be another clause in the terms reflecting the possibility of the BIS proposal being triggered while the other trigger is waiting.

The issuing bank must maintain at all times all prior authorisation necessary to immediately issue the relevant number of shares specified in the instrument’s terms and conditions should the trigger event occur.

Well, sure.

The trigger event is the earlier of: (1) the decision to make a public sector injection of capital, or equivalent support, without which the firm would have become non-viable, as determined by the relevant authority; and (2) a decision that a write-off, without which the firm would become non-viable, is necessary, as determined by the relevant authority.

This is the dangerous part, as it gives unlimited authority to the regulators to wipe out a bank’s capital investors, with no accountability or recourse whatsoever.

The issuance of any new shares as a result of the trigger event must occur prior to any public sector injection of capital so that the capital provided by the public sector is not diluted.

This means that infinite dilution of the common received on conversion is possible.

The relevant jurisdiction in determining the trigger event is the jurisdiction in which the capital is being given recognition for regulatory purposes. Therefore, where an issuing bank is part of a wider banking group and if the issuing bank wishes the instrument to be included in the consolidated group’s capital in addition to its solo capital, the terms and conditions must specify an additional trigger event. This trigger event is the earlier of: (1) the decision to make a public sector injection of capital, or equivalent support, in the jurisdiction of the consolidated supervisor, without which the firm receiving the support would have become non-viable, as determined by the relevant authority in that jurisdiction; and (2) a decision that a write-off, without which the firm would become non-viable, is necessary, as determined by the relevant authority in the home jurisdiction.

Reasonable enough, but this could cause a lot of fun with rogue regulators and cross-default provisions.

Any common stock paid as compensation to the holders of the instrument can either be common stock of the issuing bank or the parent company of the consolidated group.

The major problem – besides the evasion of bankruptcy law – with this document is that there is no distinction drawn between Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital for conversion purposes. Tier 1 capital is supposed to provide going-concern loss absorption, but the only thing triggering conversion is the Armageddon scenario. I don’t think that sub-debt holders will be particularly pleased about that.

However, the terms of this proposal are so abusive, so antithetical to the interests of investors, that I suspect most instruments will be issued with a pre-emptive trigger, so that conversion will be triggered prior to the regulators (well … reasonable regulators, anyway) exercising their unlimited and unaccountable power.

Bloomberg notes:

The Association for Financial Markets in Europe, an industry group representing banks, said last week that failing financial companies should reduce the risk to taxpayers by using contingent capital and by converting debt into equity to fund their own rescue.

In what it termed a “bail-in,” AFME said bank bond holders should see their securities convert into common shares in the event an institution’s capital ratios fall below a pre-set level, the group said in a discussion paper on Aug. 12.

Update: The AFME discussion paper, The Systemic Safety Net: Pulling failing firms back from the edge is very vague and relies on assertions, rather then evidence and argument, to make its point. It might also be dismissed as intellectually dishonest, in that it takes no account of any other proposals or academic work.

Of some interest is their view on the market-based triggers I endorse:

A trigger based on market metrics or a determination of impending systemic risk (made by a regulator) would not be effective. In addition to creating marketability issues, a trigger based on share price or market capitalisation is subject to manipulation and will almost certainly foreclose a proactive capital raise because it may fail to move the firm a safe enough distance from the trigger, which in turn will generate further negative price spirals. A trigger based on a determination of systemic risk is also unattractive, partly because it could not be used in cases of idiosyncratic risk. Waiting until firm‐specific risk has spiralled into systemic risk is destabilising.

Their preference is for a trigger based on capital ratios:

A trigger based on a core capital ratio set above the minimum core tier 1 capital requirements under the re‐invigorated Basel III capital standards would meet these criteria. Firms should have the discretion to set the trigger in accordance with their own objectives to achieve the optimal balance between prudential and economic considerations. Factors the issuer might consider in setting the trigger are:

a. To receive treatment as going concern capital the trigger should activate before any breach of the firm’s minimum regulatory capital requirements, or any other circumstances giving rise to regulatory intervention.

b. The probability of breach needs to be low enough to attract a credit rating as debt and, as such, near to subordinated debt for purposes of pricing.

I have grave difficulties with their view that market prices will be manipulated, but capital levels won’t. Additionally, as an investor, I have grave reservations about tying my investment to a capital ratio definition that will almost certainly be changed in the life of the instrument.

Market Action

August 18, 2010

The Barclays settlement of allegations they did business with bad people and covered it up was criticized here yesterday. I am pleased to see it has hit a roadblock:

A federal judge refused to endorse a settlement between the U.S. and a bank for a third time in a year, calling a proposed $298 million fine of Barclays Plc for trading with Iran, Cuba and Sudan “a sweetheart deal.”

U.S. District Judge Emmet Sullivan in Washington scheduled a hearing for today to address the question he asked prosecutors yesterday: “Why isn’t the government getting tough with the banks?” U.S. District Judge Ellen Huvelle in Washington on Aug. 16 likewise held up a $75 million settlement between the Securities and Exchange Commission and Citigroup Inc., lawyers in the case said.

“Courts are wrestling with what they see as a disparity between the way in which the conduct is being characterized as serious and the penalties that are being imposed,” said James Doty, former SEC general counsel who is now a partner at Baker Botts LLP in Washington.

U.S. agencies and prosecutors, taking note of the decisions, will begin trying harder to deliver the executives responsible for misconduct, Doty said.

I’ll believe it when I see it. Imposing fines on the shareholders is an accepted part of the game, but going after individuals will be a threat to the regulators’ club membership.

And at the same time, New Jersey is in the spotlight:

New Jersey settled claims that it misled investors in $26 billion of municipal bonds by masking underfunding of its two biggest pension plans, in the first Securities and Exchange Commission case to target a state.

New Jersey agreed to settle the SEC case without admitting or denying the agency’s findings. The state consented to a cease-and-desist order, and wasn’t required to pay any civil fines or penalties.

So what did happen? The SEC explains:

The SEC’s order requires the State of New Jersey to cease and desist from committing or causing any violations and any future violations of Sections 17(a)(2) and 17(a)(3) of the Securities Act of 1933. New Jersey consented to the issuance of the order without admitting or denying the findings. In determining to accept New Jersey’s offer to settle this matter, the Commission considered the cooperation afforded the SEC’s staff during the investigation and certain remedial acts taken by the state.

So basically it was a bureaucrats cuddle-fest. Fabulous Fabio … eat your heart out.

Inflationistas will be pleased to see that UK inflation exceeded 3.1% in July, which the BoE attributes to tax increases, oil prices and the decline of Sterling. HM Treasury has promised to tighten the fiscal screws further. The BoE’s views on inflation were last discussed August 11.

There was continued heavy volume in the Canadian preferred share market today, with PerpetualDiscounts gaining 34bp, while FixedResets lost 4bp.

PerpetualDiscounts now yield 5.79%, equivalent to 8.11% interest at the standard conversion factor of 1.4x. Long Corporates are now pretty close to 5.35%, so the pre-tax interest equivalent spread (also called the Seniority Spread) is about 270bp, down marginally – and perhaps spuriously – from the 275bp reported August 11.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1057 % 2,058.2
FixedFloater 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1057 % 3,118.0
Floater 2.54 % 2.16 % 36,886 21.96 4 0.1057 % 2,222.3
OpRet 4.91 % 0.54 % 107,960 0.20 9 -0.2365 % 2,345.8
SplitShare 6.06 % -21.87 % 69,600 0.09 2 0.9031 % 2,324.3
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.2365 % 2,145.1
Perpetual-Premium 5.77 % 5.23 % 92,482 5.58 7 0.3045 % 1,961.1
Perpetual-Discount 5.75 % 5.79 % 185,976 14.08 71 0.3352 % 1,886.2
FixedReset 5.30 % 3.32 % 295,966 3.38 47 -0.0362 % 2,239.9
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
SLF.PR.F FixedReset -3.70 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.78
Bid-YTW : 4.27 %
BAM.PR.O OpRet -2.13 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Option Certainty
Maturity Date : 2013-06-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.70
Bid-YTW : 4.23 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.06 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.57
Evaluated at bid price : 21.87
Bid-YTW : 5.79 %
BNS.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 20.65
Evaluated at bid price : 20.65
Bid-YTW : 5.51 %
RY.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.45
Evaluated at bid price : 21.45
Bid-YTW : 5.51 %
BNA.PR.D SplitShare 1.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-09-17
Maturity Price : 26.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.55
Bid-YTW : -21.87 %
BMO.PR.L Perpetual-Premium 1.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2017-06-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.90
Bid-YTW : 5.19 %
RY.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 1.43 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 20.50
Evaluated at bid price : 20.50
Bid-YTW : 5.46 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.62 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 18.80
Evaluated at bid price : 18.80
Bid-YTW : 6.19 %
NA.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.69 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.71
Evaluated at bid price : 21.71
Bid-YTW : 5.63 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
RY.PR.Y FixedReset 81,526 TD crossed blocks of 30,000 and 40,000, both at 27.95.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-12-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.93
Bid-YTW : 3.20 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet 70,300 Nesbitt crossed blocks of 40,000 and 27,300, both at 26.15.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.05
Bid-YTW : 4.88 %
BMO.PR.M FixedReset 56,245 Nesbitt crossed 19,800 at 26.60. TD crossed two blocks of 10,000 each at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-09-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.60
Bid-YTW : 2.73 %
HSB.PR.E FixedReset 54,579 TD crossed 40,000 at 27.98.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.94
Bid-YTW : 3.67 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 51,766 RBC crossed 24,000 at 21.13.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.17
Evaluated at bid price : 21.17
Bid-YTW : 5.73 %
MFC.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 45,093 TD crossed 15,300 at 18.15.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 18.15
Evaluated at bid price : 18.15
Bid-YTW : 6.21 %
There were 57 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
Issue Comments

FIG.PR.A Holders to Vote on Merger / Exchange

Faircourt Asset Management has announced:

that it will hold securityholder meetings on September 13, 2010 for Faircourt Income & Growth Split Trust (“FIG”) and Faircourt Split Trust (“FCS”, and together with FIG, the “Funds”). At the meetings, holders of units (“Unitholders”) and holders of preferred securities (“Preferred Securityholders”) of FIG will be asked to consider the proposed merger (the “Merger Proposal”) of FIG into FCS, to create a single trust (the “Continuing Trust”). Preferred Securityholders of FIG will also be asked to consider the proposed exchange (the “Exchange”) of FIG preferred securities for a new class of preferred securities of the Continuing Trust which, if approved, is expected to occur shortly following approval. FCS Unitholders and FCS Preferred Securityholders will also be asked to consider various amendments to the FCS declaration of trust and FCS trust indenture (the “FCS Proposals”).

The Merger Proposal and FCS Proposals are being proposed in response to expected changes in the taxation of income funds. As a result of these changes, there are now an insufficient number of “income funds” for FIG and FCS to continue to meet their investment restrictions. Consequently, the Manager has proposed that the investment mandate of the Continuing Trust be expanded to remedy this situation. The Manager believes that these amendments will also benefit Securityholders by allowing the Continuing Trust to invest in a broader range of securities and giving the Continuing Trust the flexibility to adjust its portfolio in the future as and when required to respond to market movements.

The meetings of Unitholders and Preferred Securityholders will be held on September 13, 2010 at Stikeman Elliott LLP, 199 Bay Street, 51st Floor, Toronto Ontario, M5L 1B9 and details regarding the Merger Proposal, FCS Proposals and the Exchange will be contained in a joint management information circular (the “Circular”) which will be mailed to Unitholders and Preferred Securityholders later in August. The Circular will also then be posted on Faircourt’s website and on the SEDAR website at www.sedar.com. The record date for the special meetings is August 13, 2010. If no quorum is present for any meeting of Unitholders, such meeting(s) will be adjourned until September 27, 2010. If no quorum is present for any meeting of Preferred Securityholders, such meeting(s) will be adjourned until September 20, 2010. Unitholders and Preferred Securityholders are encouraged to attend the meetings or complete the proxy forms or voting instruction forms (as described in the Circular) in order that their units and preferred securities can be voted at the meetings.

Pretty skimpy information and there’s nothing on the website. Yield? Tax status of future distributions? Asset Coverage? Portfolio Manager? We’ll just have to wait.

FIG.PR.A was last mentioned on PrefBlog when distributions to the Capital Unitholders were suspended. FIG.PR.A is tracked by HIMIPref™ but is relegated to the Scraps index due to credit concerns.

Update 2010-8-20: FIG.PR.A has been put on Review – Developing by DBRS

Interesting External Papers

BoC Studies Capital Ratio Cost/Benefits

The Bank of Canada has released:

a comprehensive assessment of the potential impact on the Canadian economy of new global capital and liquidity standards, which are to be finalized later this year by the G-20.

The study is titled Strengthening International Capital and Liquidity Standards: A Macroeconomic Impact Assessment for Canada:

While this country boasts a strong financial sector, it too was buffeted by financial shocks from abroad. Our economy could not escape the spillover effects of the ensuing global economic downturn. Canadian economic output fell by more than 3 per cent during the crisis, and more than 400,000 jobs disappeared.

This looks like mistake number one, according to me – it assumes that the damage caused during the Panic of 2007 was all attributable to the financial crisis itself, which I think is a load of hooey.

Recessions are good things; a recession is nature’s way of telling us we’re doing things wrong. Most of the harm experienced in Canada during the Panic may be ascribed to the auto industry … hands up everybody who thinks that there were no problems in the auto industry prior to the crisis! Didn’t think so … the Panic brought things to light and forced the decision makers to address a problem … it didn’t actually cause the problem.

Financial crises are damaging because they bring a lot of problems to light all at the same time.

But for the first time, I see official acknowledgement that higher capital ratios are not automatically good:

The benefits of higher capital and liquidity standards must be weighed against their potential costs to the Canadian economy. Over time, it is expected that banks will seek to pass on the cost of higher capital and liquidity requirements through higher lending rates to borrowers. The cost of higher capital is higher lending spreads, which the Bank calculates would increase by about 14 basis points for every percentage-point increase in bank capital requirements. This figure was then used as an input to the Bank’s macroeconomic models to gauge the impact on economic output. New liquidity requirements also present costs for the Canadian economy. These requirements are estimated to add roughly an additional 14 basis points to lending spreads, and thus are equivalent in impact to an additional 1-percentage-point increase in bank capital requirements. Consequently, the cost of a 2-percentage-point increase in capital requirements, in conjunction with the new liquidity standards, should be an increase in lending spreads of about 42 basis points.

However, they show more than just a little political influence with:

In the wake of the crisis, the Bank of Canada cut its target for the overnight rate to a historic low of one-quarter of one per cent, and decades of progress in improving Canada’s fiscal position suffered a setback as fiscal support for the Canadian economy pushed federal and provincial government budgets back into substantial deficits.

The GST cut and elimination of the structural surplus had nothing to do with it, so vote Conservative!

The regulators have been busy:

To assess the potential economic implications of these reforms, the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and the BCBS conducted two international studies that assessed (i) the longer-run macroeconomic benefits and costs (the LEI report) and (ii) the shorter-term transition costs (the MAG report) associated with adopting the new standards. (footnote) The reports are: “An Assessment of the Long-Term Economic Impact of the New Regulatory Framework” (the LEI report), and “Assessing the Macroeconomic Impact of the Transition to Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements – Interim Report “ (the MAG report). Both are available at http://www.bis.org.

They do acknowledge a major problem:

No allowance is made for the possibility that households and firms may find cheaper alternative sources of financing in the longer run that would reduce the impact of the new rules on the economy.

If loan rates increase 42bp, I would consider that a certainty. Private mortgages will take off and I’m wondering about the potential to start a private mortgage fund myself. What’s more, this will siphon off the good business from the banks and leave them with the dregs … but there’s no allowance for it.

Specifically, assuming a starting probability of a crisis of 4.5 per cent in any given country, the LEI report found that an increase of 2 percentage points in bank capital ratios reduced the probability of a financial crisis by 2.9 percentage points, while increases in capital ratios of 4 and 6 percentage points reduced the probability of a financial crisis by 3.6 and 4 percentage points, respectively. These calculations assume a combined effect from increases in capital as well as from new liquidity rules.

When these reductions in the probability of a crisis (e.g., 2.9 percentage points for a 2-percentage-point increase in capital ratios) are multiplied by the cumulative cost of crises (63 per cent of GDP), the benefits to annual economic output are potentially large, in the order of 2 per cent of GDP

If, as I assert, the bulk of the costs experienced during financial crises are simply reflections of structural problems that are merely brought to light by the crisis, then this calculation is … er … inoperable.

For example, following the approach used by the United Kingdom Financial Services Authority (U.K. FSA) and described in Barrell et al. (2009), the annual probability of a domestic financial crisis was estimated based on several domestic factors, including the unweighted capital ratio of banks, their liquid assets as a share of total assets, and house prices expressed in real terms. This approach suggests a 1.7 per cent probability of a financial crisis occurring in Canada (implying that a financial crisis occurs, on average, every 60 years or so). This figure is substantially lower than the LEI report’s 4.5 per cent likelihood of a foreign financial crisis (approximately once every 22 years).

Since the banks nearly blew themselves in the late eighties with the MBA crisis, I guess that means we’ve got about forty years to go.

As indicated in Annex 1, most Canadian banks appear to be well placed to meet the new Liquidity Coverage Ratio requirement, since they carry a large stock of residential mortgages that could be converted at a small cost to federal government-guaranteed National Housing Act Mortgage-Backed Securities that would qualify as eligible liquid assets under the new rules.

Great! Wave a magic wand, and suddenly you get to recategorize existing assets. This part really gives me a lot of confidence, you know?

Given the current exceptionally low level of bank deposit rates and the cost of bank debt funding more generally, it is also assumed that the wider interest margins will effectively result in higher interest rates (lending spreads) on bank loans to households, firms, and other sectors of the economy. It is further assumed that the higher lending spreads will be passed along to all bank borrowers, and not just to certain subgroups, such as households or small and medium-sized businesses (SMEs), because all banks in Canada and abroad will be affected by the higher capital and liquidity requirements.

Apparently, Dr. Pangloss had a hand in this report. As noted above, increased spreads will increase the opportunity for shadow banks to move in … there will be a lot of business borrowing at prime (or prime+) who are going to find the commercial paper market (either directly or via BAs) and short-term bond issuance to be a whole lot more attractive if spreads increase 42bp.

Don’t get me wrong! I’m very happy to see that, at last, there is some official acknowledgment that increased capital standards will have a cost. But I think some of the embedded assumptions are more than just a little bit suspect and I look forward to seeing academic attacks on this paper.

A related post is Elliott: Quantifying the Effects on Lending of Increased Capital Requirements

Market Action

August 17, 2010

The Nanex explanation of the Flash Crash was discussed on August 9. It now appears that the mechanism is considered plausible by the CFTC:

What this delay means is that, hypothetically, at the same real time, there could be two different price quotes: the real time NYSE price quote feed that had most stocks falling rapidly and the delayed consolidated price quote feed where the prices had not yet fully reflected the downward movement. Therefore, an algorithmic computer program, which would use high-frequency or flash trading and is written to sense price differences, could submit buy and sell orders to arbitrage between the two prices. The algo program could buy at the lower price from the NYSE feed and immediately sell on another exchange portal using the delayed consolidated price quote feed. This could be done is large quantities, repeatedly. Here is what we know: there was a delay between the premium and the consolidated price quote feeds. What we do not know yet is if some algorithmic trading took advantage of that situation.

We had our Technology Advisory Committee in this room last month and I asked the experts if this type of thing was possible or if it was just a conspiracy theory. Four of the panelists assured me that this could take place. In fact, they even acknowledged that some algorithmic programs were geared to not only take advantage of market circumstances, but could be used to instigate certain market conditions in order to then initiate their own program of buying or selling.

Therefore, I urge the staffs of the CFTC and the SEC to not leave this and any other stones unturned as they continue to investigate the flash crash. Did algo price pirates seek false profits on May 6th? Inquiring minds want to know.

Pirates? Sounds like he’s got a solution and is just waiting for a plausible problem.

A Barclay’s settlement illustrates all I find confusing about financial regulation:

Barclays PLC agreed to pay $298 million to settle charges by U.S. and New York prosecutors that the U.K. bank altered financial records for more than a decade to hide hundreds of millions of dollars in payments flowing into the U.S. from Cuba, Libya, Iran and other sanctioned countries.

The bank plans to pay $298 million to settle claims by U.S. prosecutors that it altered financial records for more than a decade to hide hundreds of millions of dollars that flowed to the U.S. from nations like Cuba, Libya and Iran.

A federal court filing said Barclays “accepts and acknowledges responsibility for its conduct and that of its employees.” U.S. officials said the bank altered payment messages or deleted information about sanctioned countries.

In other cases, Barclays returned payments out of fear they would be detected by U.S. officials, sending fax cover sheets that said: “Payments to U.S.A. must NOT contain the word listed below.” Prosecutors said payments often were re-sent after references to the sanctioned countries, which included Sudan and Myanmar, were omitted.

OK, so they pay a fine. Good. But it doesn’t say anywhere that anyone’s been banned from the industry. They altered records! They had a protocol for hiding transfers! That shows deliberate intent to break the law, with a policy set somewhere by somebody who thought about it … and nobody’s been banned from the industry? And yet they’re going after a dumbass salesman at Goldman who did his job and did it well? I don’t get it.

It was a good day on the Canadian preferred share market, with PerpetualDiscounts up 24bp and FixedResets gaining 3bp on high volume. Sadly, FixedResets did not set a new yield low today – in fact, the median weighte average YTW actually increased fractionally.

MFC issues continue to be prominent in the highlights.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0661 % 2,056.0
FixedFloater 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0661 % 3,114.7
Floater 2.54 % 2.16 % 38,385 21.96 4 0.0661 % 2,220.0
OpRet 4.90 % -1.58 % 99,970 0.20 9 -0.0301 % 2,351.4
SplitShare 6.02 % -7.77 % 64,403 0.08 2 0.4379 % 2,303.5
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.0301 % 2,150.1
Perpetual-Premium 5.79 % 5.41 % 92,663 5.59 7 0.3963 % 1,955.1
Perpetual-Discount 5.77 % 5.84 % 183,119 14.07 71 0.2395 % 1,879.8
FixedReset 5.29 % 3.32 % 274,579 3.39 47 0.0346 % 2,240.7
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
MFC.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -1.31 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 18.06
Evaluated at bid price : 18.06
Bid-YTW : 6.24 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -1.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 18.50
Evaluated at bid price : 18.50
Bid-YTW : 6.29 %
RY.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.03 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 20.56
Evaluated at bid price : 20.56
Bid-YTW : 5.44 %
RY.PR.H Perpetual-Premium 1.04 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2017-06-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.35
Bid-YTW : 5.42 %
BMO.PR.K Perpetual-Discount 1.11 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 23.56
Evaluated at bid price : 23.76
Bid-YTW : 5.54 %
BAM.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 1.15 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 19.41
Evaluated at bid price : 19.41
Bid-YTW : 6.22 %
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 21.52
Evaluated at bid price : 21.52
Bid-YTW : 5.89 %
TD.PR.C FixedReset 1.33 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-02
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.36
Bid-YTW : 2.82 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 114,947 RBC bought 11,500 from Nesbitt at 18.50; TD crosed 40,000 at 18.60. RBC crossed 13,200 at 18.69.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 18.50
Evaluated at bid price : 18.50
Bid-YTW : 6.29 %
BMO.PR.P FixedReset 60,781 RBC crossed blocks of 17,000 and 33,000 at 27.25.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-03-27
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.20
Bid-YTW : 3.28 %
MFC.PR.E FixedReset 59,063 RBC crossed 15,200 at 26.25.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.15
Bid-YTW : 4.27 %
RY.PR.I FixedReset 56,912 National bought 10,700 from anonymous at 26.45; RBC crossed 24,300 at 26.36.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.30
Bid-YTW : 3.38 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 55,141 RBC crossed 24,000 at 21.05.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 21.06
Evaluated at bid price : 21.06
Bid-YTW : 5.76 %
GWO.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 52,786 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-17
Maturity Price : 21.87
Evaluated at bid price : 22.21
Bid-YTW : 5.93 %
There were 55 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
Market Action

August 16, 2010

The FDIC is looking for comments:

The FDIC and the other federal banking agencies are requesting comment on alternative standards of creditworthiness to replace the use of credit ratings in the risk-based capital requirements. The comment period for the attached Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (ANPR) will be 60 days after its publication in the Federal Register.

They’ll get a lot of comments … but I don’t know how many useful ones!

Fans of Judge Jed Rakoff can add another bubble-gum card to their collection – Judge Ellen Segal Huvelle:

A federal judge refused to approve the Securities and Exchange Commission’s $75 million settlement with Citigroup Inc. over the bank’s disclosure of subprime-mortgage problems, saying she is “baffled” by the proposed pact.

The move by U.S. District Judge Ellen Segal Huvelle represents another challenge for the SEC as it tries to punish financial institutions blamed for the financial crisis.

Judge Ellen Segal Huvelle said she didn’t have “sufficient information.”

The judge, striking a frustrated tone, fired several questions at the SEC, among them why it pursued only two individuals in the case and why Citigroup shareholders should have to pay for the alleged sins of bank executives.

“I look at this and say, ‘Why would I find this fair and reasonable?'” the judge told both sides at a 90-minute hearing. “You expect the court to rubber-stamp, but we can’t.”

Part of freedom is an independent judiciary – which is why politicians and bureaucrats avoid them whenever possible.

New York Congressman Peter King stated on the weekend that he agrees with Sarah Palin, Newt Gingrich, other Republicans and Al-Qaeda that there is some kind of religious war going on:

“President Obama is wrong,” said King in an e-mailed statement. “The right and moral thing for President Obama to have done was to urge Muslim leaders to respect the families of those who died and move their mosque away from Ground Zero.”

I hadn’t realized there was a religious crusade going on; I thought it was simply some harrassment of the civilized world by a rag-tag pack of psychopaths. But it’s nice to see the US Republicans agree with Al-Qaeda on something; it gives hope for the brotherhood of man.

There was good volume in the Canadian preferred share market today as PerpetualDiscounts gained 9bp and FixedResets were up 9bp. The win by FixedResets took their median weighted average yield down to 3.318%, just a hair off the all-time low of 3.314% set on March 26.

MFC was again prominent on the highlight reel.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0000 % 2,054.7
FixedFloater 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0000 % 3,112.6
Floater 2.55 % 2.16 % 38,454 21.97 4 0.0000 % 2,218.5
OpRet 4.90 % -1.56 % 99,153 0.20 9 -0.3000 % 2,352.1
SplitShare 6.05 % -2.62 % 64,157 0.08 2 0.2299 % 2,293.5
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.3000 % 2,150.8
Perpetual-Premium 5.81 % 5.55 % 93,684 5.65 7 -0.1301 % 1,947.4
Perpetual-Discount 5.78 % 5.83 % 180,241 14.07 71 0.0865 % 1,875.4
FixedReset 5.30 % 3.32 % 272,788 3.39 47 0.0921 % 2,239.9
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
MFC.PR.D FixedReset -1.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.91
Bid-YTW : 4.34 %
MFC.PR.A OpRet -1.18 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2015-12-18
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.03
Bid-YTW : 4.02 %
RY.PR.T FixedReset 1.05 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-09-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.84
Bid-YTW : 3.26 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
TRP.PR.A FixedReset 155,470 RBC crossed blocks of 100,000 and 40,000 at 26.05.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.02
Bid-YTW : 3.76 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 85,589 Nesbitt crossed blocks of 20,000 and 40,000 at 18.80.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-16
Maturity Price : 18.70
Evaluated at bid price : 18.70
Bid-YTW : 6.22 %
TD.PR.R Perpetual-Discount 60,830 Desjardins crossed 15,400 at 24.75; CIBC bought 13,000 from National at 24.78.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-16
Maturity Price : 24.52
Evaluated at bid price : 24.75
Bid-YTW : 5.70 %
TRP.PR.C FixedReset 55,030 RBC crossed 49,100 at 25.35.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-16
Maturity Price : 23.22
Evaluated at bid price : 25.30
Bid-YTW : 3.74 %
GWO.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 54,800 Desjardins crossed 25,000 at 20.85; Nesbitt crossed 25,000 at 20.86.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-16
Maturity Price : 20.85
Evaluated at bid price : 20.85
Bid-YTW : 5.91 %
TRP.PR.B FixedReset 39,241 Nesbitt crossed 25,000 at 25.05.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-16
Maturity Price : 24.97
Evaluated at bid price : 25.02
Bid-YTW : 3.62 %
There were 35 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
Interesting External Papers

FRBB: Bubbles Happen

The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston has released a discussion paper by Kristopher S. Gerardi, Christopher L. Foote, and Paul S. Willen titled Reasonable People Did Disagree: Optimism and Pessimism About the U.S. Housing Market Before the Crash:

Understanding the evolution of real-time beliefs about house price appreciation is central to understanding the U.S. housing crisis. At the peak of the recent housing cycle, both borrowers and lenders appealed to optimistic house price forecasts to justify undertaking increasingly risky loans. Many observers have argued that these rosy forecasts ignored basic theoretical and empirical evidence that pointed to a massive overvaluation of housing and thus to an inevitable and severe price decline. We revisit the boom years and show that the economics profession provided little such countervailing evidence at the time. Many economists, skeptical that a bubble existed, attempted to justify the historic run-up in housing prices based on housing fundamentals. Other economists were more uncertain, pointing to some evidence of bubble-like behavior in certain regional housing markets. Even these more skeptical economists, however, refused to take a conclusive position on whether a bubble existed. The small number of economists who argued forcefully for a bubble often did so years before the housing market peak, and thus lost a fair amount of credibility, or they make arguments fundamentally at odds with the data even ex post. For example, some economists suggested that cities where new construction was limited by zoning regulations or geography were particularly “bubble-prone,” yet the data shows that the cities with the biggest gyrations in house prices were often those at the epicenter of the new construction boom. We conclude by arguing that economic theory provides little guidance as to what should be the “correct” level of asset prices —including housing prices. Thus, while optimistic forecasts held by many market participants in 2005 turned out to be inaccurate, they were not ex ante unreasonable.

I’ll admit I was undecided about whether to highlight this paper in its own post, or simply to mention it in today’s market update … until I read the following:

It is instructive to read the logic of non-economists who looked at house price data in the same period. Paolo Pellegrini and John Paulson, whose wildly successful 2006 bet against subprime mortgages is now the stuff of Wall Street legend, made the following argument, as chronicled in Zuckerman (2009). First, they noted that house prices had deviated from trend:

Those facts are indisputable, but the logic that followed would have earned the two investors a zero on an undergraduate finance exam:

Ha-ha! I hope this gets quoted extensively by Fabulous Fabio and Alan Greenspan as they defend themselves against the charges that they bear personal responsibility for the Panic of 2007.

The authors don’t spare Krugman:

Krugman’s thesis seems to hinge on the idea that scarce coastal land is valuable and bubbles can only happen when assets are in short supply, but the whole point about bubbles is that the fundamentals of supply and demand do not matter. Thus, there is no reason why land in places where it is easy to build could not experience bubbles. Ex post, as we will explore at length, the places in the United States where the housing market most resembled a bubble were Phoenix and Las Vegas. According to recent research, both locations are characterized by relatively high housing-supply elasticities; unlike certain coastal areas, the two cities have an abundance of surrounding land on which to accommodate new construction.

The authors’ purpose is clear:

Ultimately, our paper argues that the academic research available in 2006 was basically inconclusive and could not convincingly support or refute any hypothesis about the future path of asset prices. Thus, investors who believed that house prices were going to fall could find evidence to support their position, while those who wanted to believe that house prices would continue to rise could not be dissuaded either. There were reasonable arguments on both sides.

One of the bubbleistas was Baker:

In addition to the divergence between rents and prices in the U.S. housing market, Baker also called attention to changes in demographic trends that could put additional downward pressure on house prices. He noted that during the 1970s and early 1980s, housing grew from about 17 percent of consumption to more than 25 percent, in large part due to increased demand for housing from the first baby boom cohorts, who were then entering adulthood. From the early 1980s to the mid-1990s, the housing share of consumption remained relatively constant, consistent with the modest demographic changes taking place in the United States at that time. In the future, Baker argued, as the baby boomers entered retirement, housing demand—and hence prices—would likely fall.

This argument has been taken up by some researchers at BIS, as discussed on August 4.

Baker also supplied contemporary arguments against the Greenspan-dunnit thesis:

As we will
discuss in more detail below, many economists pointed to low interest rates as justifying higher housing prices, but Baker was skeptical of this claim. Nominal interest rates were indeed low in the early 2000s, as the Federal Reserve had adopted a loose monetary policy to combat the effects of the 2001 recession. However, Baker pointed out that nominal rates could not explain the divergence of housing prices from fundamentals, as it is the real interest rate (the difference between the nominal rate and expected inflation) that should influence prices.

Another very interesting point is:

The evolving landscape of mortgage lending is also relevant to an ongoing debate in the literature about the direction of causality between reduced underwriting standards and higher house prices. Did lax lending standards shift out the demand curve for new homes and raise house prices, or did higher house prices reduce the chance of future loan losses, thereby encouraging lenders to relax their standards? Economists will debate this issue for some time. For our part, we simply point out that an in-depth study of lending standards would have been of little help to an economist trying to learn whether the early-to-mid 2000s increase in house prices was sustainable. If one economist argued that lax standards were fueling an unsustainable surge in house prices, another could have responded that reducing credit constraints generally brings asset prices closer to fundamental values, not farther away.

Another good point is:

If we have learned anything from this crisis, it is that large declines in house prices are always a possibility, so regulators and policymakers must take them into account when making decisions. A 30 percent fall in house prices over three years may be very difficult, if not impossible, to generate in any plausible econometric model, but a truly robust financial institution must be able to withstand one. The fact that so many professional investors as well as individual households ignored this possibility, even in 2006, suggests that we cannot allow investors to try to time market collapses.

All in all, most interesting and well balanced. Related posts on PrefBlog include:

As for me … I’ve always disclaimed any ability or interest in forecasting macroeconomic trends. But what I have said is … bad investments will hurt you. Concentration will kill you.

The Panic of 2007 wasn’t caused by Merrill Lynch et al. buying sub-prime paper. It was caused by the fact that they levered it up big time.

PrefLetter

August Edition of PrefLetter Released!

The August, 2010, edition of PrefLetter has been released and is now available for purchase as the “Previous edition”. Those who subscribe for a full year receive the “Previous edition” as a bonus.

The August edition contains an appendix reviewing the theory of FixedReset pricing and presenting two related models that shown good explanatory power since April 2009.

As previously announced, PrefLetter is now available to residents of Alberta, British Columbia and Manitoba, as well as Ontario and to entities registered with the Quebec Securities Commission.

Until further notice, the “Previous Edition” will refer to the August 2010, issue, while the “Next Edition” will be the September, 2010, issue, scheduled to be prepared as of the close September 10 and eMailed to subscribers prior to market-opening on September 13.

PrefLetter is intended for long term investors seeking issues to buy-and-hold. At least one recommendation from each of the major preferred share sectors is included and discussed.

Note: The PrefLetter website has a Subscriber Download Feature. If you have not received your copy, try it!

Note: PrefLetter, being delivered to clients as a large attachment by eMail, sometimes runs afoul of spam filters. If you have not received your copy within fifteen minutes of a release notice such as this one, please double check your (company’s) spam filtering policy and your spam repository – there are some hints in the post Sympatico Spam Filters out of Control. If it’s not there, contact me and I’ll get you your copy … somehow!

Note: There have been scattered complaints regarding inability to open PrefLetter in Acrobat Reader, despite my practice of including myself on the subscription list and immediately checking the copy received. I have had the occasional difficulty reading US Government documents, which I was able to resolve by downloading and installing the latest version of Adobe Reader. Also, note that so far, all complaints have been from users of Yahoo Mail. Try saving it to disk first, before attempting to open it.