BCE.PR.E / BCE.PR.F Conversion Results

January 19th, 2010

BCE Inc. has announced:

that 592,772 of its 14,085,782 Cumulative Redeemable First Preferred Shares, Series AF (series AF preferred shares) have been tendered for conversion, on a one-for-one basis, into Cumulative Redeemable First Preferred Shares, Series AE (series AE preferred shares). In addition, 1,084,090 of its 1,914,218 series AE preferred shares have been tendered for conversion, on a one-for-one basis, into series AF preferred shares. Consequently, on February 1, 2010, BCE will have 1,422,900 series AE preferred shares and 14,577,100 series AF preferred shares issued and outstanding. The series AE preferred shares and the series AF preferred shares will continue to be listed on the Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbols BCE.PR.E and BCE.PR.F respectively.

The series AE preferred shares will continue to pay a monthly floating adjustable cash dividend for the five-year period beginning on February 1, 2010, as and when declared by the Board of Directors of BCE. The monthly floating adjustable dividend for any particular month will continue to be calculated using the Designated Percentage for such month representing the sum of an adjustment factor (based on the market price of the series AE preferred shares in the preceding month) and the Designated Percentage for the preceding month. The series AF preferred shares will pay on a quarterly basis, for the five-year period beginning on February 1, 2010, as and when declared by the Board of Directors of BCE, a fixed dividend based on an annual dividend rate of 4.541%.

This is a logical result (I recommended BCE.PR.F as the better of the pair), but is nevertheless unfortunate. The decline in BCE.PR.E outstanding will reduce its liquidity from already low levels and make swaps between them even harder to execute.

BCE.PR.F is tracked by HIMIPref™ but is relegated to the Scraps index on credit concerns. BCE.PR.E is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

January 18, 2010

January 18th, 2010

Econbrowser‘s James Hamilton took a look at How the Federal Reserve Earned its Profit.

There was a surprising amount of activity in the Canadian preferred share market today – considering the American holiday – with an equally surprising amount of price action. PerpetualDiscounts lost 2bp while FixedResets gained 14bp and scored a shut-out on the volume highlights table.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.5052 % 1,700.4
FixedFloater 5.78 % 3.86 % 35,307 19.20 1 1.8970 % 2,733.2
Floater 2.31 % 2.63 % 108,857 20.69 3 -0.5052 % 2,124.3
OpRet 4.85 % -0.18 % 115,727 0.09 13 -0.0767 % 2,318.0
SplitShare 6.36 % 1.26 % 184,028 0.08 2 -0.1534 % 2,111.1
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.0767 % 2,119.6
Perpetual-Premium 5.79 % 5.67 % 147,134 5.98 12 -0.1717 % 1,893.0
Perpetual-Discount 5.73 % 5.77 % 179,077 14.24 63 -0.0162 % 1,833.0
FixedReset 5.39 % 3.52 % 330,634 3.85 42 0.1367 % 2,183.0
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
HSB.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -2.32 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 22.58
Evaluated at bid price : 22.76
Bid-YTW : 5.65 %
IAG.PR.C FixedReset -1.78 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.00
Bid-YTW : 4.12 %
W.PR.J Perpetual-Discount -1.40 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 22.90
Evaluated at bid price : 23.17
Bid-YTW : 6.08 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -1.33 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 22.08
Evaluated at bid price : 22.21
Bid-YTW : 5.68 %
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -1.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 21.43
Evaluated at bid price : 21.71
Bid-YTW : 5.79 %
PWF.PR.J OpRet 1.01 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-02-17
Maturity Price : 25.75
Evaluated at bid price : 25.97
Bid-YTW : -7.78 %
MFC.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 1.27 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 20.00
Evaluated at bid price : 20.00
Bid-YTW : 5.70 %
POW.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 1.46 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 24.65
Evaluated at bid price : 25.01
Bid-YTW : 5.83 %
BAM.PR.G FixedFloater 1.90 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 18.80
Bid-YTW : 3.86 %
TD.PR.Y FixedReset 1.99 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-11-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.17
Bid-YTW : 3.70 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BAM.PR.R FixedReset 143,120 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-18
Maturity Price : 23.19
Evaluated at bid price : 25.30
Bid-YTW : 4.82 %
TRP.PR.A FixedReset 132,770 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.84
Bid-YTW : 3.07 %
TD.PR.K FixedReset 119,820 Nesbitt crossed 100,000 at 27.90.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.85
Bid-YTW : 3.55 %
PWF.PR.M FixedReset 114,390 Nesbitt crossed 100,000 at 27.25.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-02
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.25
Bid-YTW : 3.58 %
RY.PR.L FixedReset 106,620 Nesbitt crossed 100,000 at 27.25.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.25
Bid-YTW : 3.48 %
MFC.PR.D FixedReset 88,965 Desjardins crossed 59,600 at 28.10; RBC crossed 22,800 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 28.08
Bid-YTW : 3.78 %
There were 50 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

December 2009 Top 10 Publication Downloads

January 18th, 2010

It’s interesting:

1. Preferred Shares and GICs

2. Perpetual and Retractible Preferred Shares

3. Corporate Bonds … or Preferred Shares?

4. Interest Bearing Preferreds

5. Why Invest in Preferred Shares?

6. A Brief Introduction to Preferred Shares

7. The Future of Money Market Fund Regulation

8. Trading Preferreds

9. Modified Duration

10. Dividends and Ex-Dates

John Hull Supports Tranche Retention, Bonus Deferral

January 16th, 2010

John Hull has published an essay titled The Credit Crunch of 2007: What Went Wrong? Why? What Lessons Can Be Learned?:

This paper explains the events leading to the credit crisis that began in 2007 and the products that were created from residential mortgages. It explains the multiple levels of securitization that were involved. It argues that the inappropriate incentives led to a short‐term focus in the decision making of traders and a failure to evaluate the risks being taken. The products that were created lacked transparency with the payoffs from one product depending on the performance of many other products. Market participants relied on the AAA ratings assigned to products without evaluating the models used by rating agencies. The paper considers the steps that can be taken by financial institutions and their regulators to avoid similar crises in the future. It suggests that companies should be required to retain some of the risk in each instrument that is created when credit risk is transferred. The compensation plans within financial institutions should be changed so that they have a longer term focus. Collateralization through either clearinghouses or two‐way collateralization agreements should become mandatory. Risk management should involve more managerial judgment and rely less on the mechanistic application of value‐at‐risk models.

With respect to tranche retention, Dr. Hull argues:

The present crisis might have been less severe if the originators of mortgages (and other assets where credit risk is transferred) were required by regulators to keep, say, 20% of each tranche created. This would have better aligned the interests of originators with the interests of the investors who bought the tranches.

The most important reason why originators should have a stake in all the tranches created is that this encourages the originators to make the same lending decisions that the investors would make. Another reason is that the originators often end up as administrators of the mortgages (collecting interest, making foreclosure decisions, etc). It is important that their decisions as administrators are made in the best interests of investors.

This idea might have reduced the market excesses during the period leading up to the credit crunch of 2007. However, it should be acknowledged that one of the ironies of the credit crunch is that securitization did not in many instances get the mortgages off the books of originating banks. Often AAA-rated senior tranches created by one part of a bank were bought by other parts of the bank. Because banks were both investors in and originators of mortgages, one might expect a reasonable alignment of the interests of investors and originators. But the part of the bank investing in the mortgages was usually far removed from the part of the bank originating the mortgages and there appears to have been little information flow from one to the other.

Assiduous Readers will not be surprised to learn that I don’t like this idea. In my role as bond trader I have never bought a securitization … I would if the spreads were high enough, but generally spreads are compressed by other buyers.

When I buy a bond, I want to know somebody’s on the hook for it. I like the idea that if the borrower is a day late or a dollar short, I can force an operating company into bankruptcy and cause great anguish and financial ill effects on the deadbeats. Securitizations tend to be highly correllated; while this is claimed to be counterbalanced by the overcollateralization (or tranche subordination, which is simply a formalization of the process) I confess I have a great preference for keeping actual bonds in my bond portfolios.

Tranche retention is simply a methodology whereby securitizations become more bond-like. I object to such blurring of the lines, especially when enforced by governmental regulatory fiat. What I am being told, in a world where such retention is mandated, is that if something has been issued that I – for good reasons or bad – wish to buy and that the security originator wishes to sell, we’ll both go to jail if we consummate the transaction.

I will also point out the logical implications of tranche retention: when I sell 100 shares of SLF.PR.A, I should be forced to retain 20 of them, so that the buyer will know they’re OK. That’s crazy. The buyer should do his own damn homework and make up his own mind.

The world has learned over and over that while regulation is very nice, the only thing that works really well is caveat emptor. I do not want some 20-year old regulator with a college certificate in boxtickingology telling me what I may and may not buy.

Dr. Hull has underemphasized the heart of the matter: one of the ironies of the credit crunch is that securitization did not in many instances get the mortgages off the books of originating banks. Often AAA-rated senior tranches created by one part of a bank were bought by other parts of the bank..

In this context, I will repeat some of Sheila Bair’s testimony to the Crisis Committee:

In the mid-1990s, bank regulators working with the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (Basel Committee) introduced a new set of capital requirements for trading activities. The new requirements were generally much lower than the requirements for traditional lending under the theory that banks’ trading-book exposures were liquid, marked-to-market, mostly hedged, and could be liquidated at close to their market values within a short interval—for example 10 days.

The market risk rule presented a ripe opportunity for capital arbitrage, as institutions began to hold growing amounts of assets in trading accounts that were not marked-to-market but “marked-to-model.” These assets benefitted from the low capital requirements of the market risk rule, even though they were in some cases so highly complex, opaque and illiquid that they could not be sold quickly without loss. Indeed, in late 2007 and through 2008, large write-downs of assets held in trading accounts weakened the capital positions of some large commercial and investment banks and fueled market fears.

I see the basic problem as one that happens when traders try to be investors. Traders do not typically know a lot about the market – although they can talk a good game – and when they try their hand at actual investing, bad things will happen more often than not. It’s a totally different mindset.

I didn’t make a penny during the tech bubble – never bought any of it. I have numerous friends, however, who made out like bandits and set themselves up for life during those years. The difference between us was not the knowledge that that stuff was garbage … we all knew it was garbage. But I could not sleep at night knowing I had garbage in my portfolio; they were fine with the idea, so long as there was lots of positive chatter and prices kept going up.

A long, long time ago – so long I can’t remember the reference – I read an interview with a big wheel (perhaps the proprietor) of a small NASDAQ trading firm. The interview was interupted when one of his staff burst in with the news that another brokerage (XYZ brokers) wanted to sell a large block of stock (45,000 shares, if I remember correctly) in ABC Company and was willing to do so at a discount to market. So they look at the recent price/volume history, check the news and the deal gets done. When the interview resumed, the interviewer asked “So … what’s ABC Company?”. The trader replied, patienty and wearily: “Its something XYZ wanted to sell 45,000 shares of.”

Now that’s trading!

Despite constant interviews by the media, there is not really much correlation between trading ability and investing ability.

So anyway, I will suggest that when considering a regulatory response to the Credit Crunch, a clearer distinction between trading and investing activities is what’s required. As I have previously suggested, there should be no bright-line between investment banks and vanilla banks; but the difference should be recognized in the capital rules. Investment banks should have low capital requirements for trading inventory and higher ones for investment positions; the reverse for vanilla banks. And for heaven’s sake, make sure that there’s no jiggery-pokery with aging positions on the trading books! Hold it for thirty days, and the capital charge goes up progressively! Start trading too many “investment” positions and you’ll find your investment portfolio reclassified.

As far as bonus deferral is concerned … it’s suitable for investors, not so much for traders. Bonus deferral requires a lot of trust by the employee, trust that is all too often unjustified as exemplified by the Citigroup case discussed January 7 and, here in Canada, by the case of David Berry. The major effect of bonus deferral, I believe, will be to spawn a migration of talent to hedge funds and boutiques.

Dr. Hull suggests:

One idea is the following. At the end of each year a financial institution awards a “bonus accrual” (positive or negative) to each employee reflecting the employee’s contribution to the business. The actual cash bonus received by an employee at the end of a year would be the average bonus accrual over the previous five years or zero, whichever is higher. For the purpose of this calculation, bonus accruals would be set equal to zero for years prior to the employee joining the financial institution (unless the employee manages to negotiate otherwise) and bonuses would not be paid after an employee leaves it. Although not perfect, this type of plan would motivate employees to use a multi-year time horizon when making decisions.

One problem I have with that is vesting. Is the vesting of this bonus iron-clad or not? Is it held by a mutually agreed-upon third party in treasury bills? And what happens if the employee leaves the firm and somebody else starts trading his book? Who takes any future losses then?

Another problem, of course, is trust (assuming the vesting is not iron-clad). When a relationship turns sour – or somebody gets greedy – things can turn nasty in a hurry. It should always be remembered that the purpose of regulation is not to protect anybody. The purpose of regulation is to ensure that everybody is guilty of something.

I have twice been offered jobs with the stupidest incentive scheme in the world. Not only would my bonus be determined by how well the firm did – putting me on the hook for decisions made by people I didn’t even know – but because of deferral, up-front transfers and discretion, I could have worked there for five years and paid them for the privilege. Those negotiations didn’t take long!

January 15, 2010

January 15th, 2010

Mary Schapiro of the SEC testified to the Crisis Committee. It’s lightweight bureaucratic fluff, especially when compared to Sheila Bair’s testimony, which was a joy to read since it contained actual arguments.

The previously mocked HAMP is looking more sickly by the minute:

About 25 percent of homeowners who received trial loan modifications through President Barack Obama’s main foreclosure prevention plan are failing to keep up with their new reduced payments, the Treasury Department said.

At least 196,000 borrowers have missed some or all of their required payments, according to comments Treasury officials made on a conference call today and calculations from government data. An additional 115,000 homeowners who started trial repayment plans last year have either dropped out or been kicked out of Obama’s Home Affordable Modification Program, the officials said.

Turning around the U.S. housing market is one of Obama’s top priorities, Lawrence Summers, the president’s top economic adviser, told reporters yesterday. The administration has put off restructuring federally controlled mortgage-finance companies Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac while they are administering the mortgage- modification program.

PerpetualDiscounts had a nothing day on the Canadian preferred share market, losing a quarter of a beep, but FixedResets bounced back strongly, gaining 13bp. Volume was heavy.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.4882 % 1,709.1
FixedFloater 5.89 % 3.95 % 35,508 19.08 1 1.0959 % 2,682.3
Floater 2.30 % 2.63 % 109,631 20.71 3 0.4882 % 2,135.1
OpRet 4.84 % -3.74 % 116,926 0.09 13 0.1034 % 2,319.8
SplitShare 6.35 % -4.00 % 184,077 0.08 2 0.0219 % 2,114.3
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1034 % 2,121.2
Perpetual-Premium 5.78 % 5.63 % 145,233 2.26 12 -0.1286 % 1,896.2
Perpetual-Discount 5.73 % 5.74 % 178,385 14.28 63 -0.0025 % 1,833.3
FixedReset 5.40 % 3.56 % 329,303 3.85 42 0.1264 % 2,180.1
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
TD.PR.Y FixedReset -1.69 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2018-11-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.66
Bid-YTW : 4.26 %
ENB.PR.A Perpetual-Premium -1.56 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-02-14
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.30
Bid-YTW : -0.85 %
W.PR.J Perpetual-Discount -1.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 23.20
Evaluated at bid price : 23.50
Bid-YTW : 5.99 %
BAM.PR.B Floater 1.01 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 15.06
Evaluated at bid price : 15.06
Bid-YTW : 2.63 %
BAM.PR.G FixedFloater 1.10 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 18.45
Bid-YTW : 3.95 %
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.57 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 21.61
Evaluated at bid price : 21.95
Bid-YTW : 5.72 %
GWO.PR.J FixedReset 1.57 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.74
Bid-YTW : 3.15 %
TRP.PR.A FixedReset 2.03 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.58
Bid-YTW : 3.28 %
HSB.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 2.06 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 23.09
Evaluated at bid price : 23.30
Bid-YTW : 5.51 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BAM.PR.R FixedReset 288,715 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 23.19
Evaluated at bid price : 25.30
Bid-YTW : 4.88 %
MFC.PR.A OpRet 192,570 RBC crossed 190,000 at 26.75.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-07-19
Maturity Price : 26.25
Evaluated at bid price : 26.50
Bid-YTW : 2.60 %
TRP.PR.A FixedReset 147,424 RBC bought 10,000 from Nesbitt at 26.60.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.58
Bid-YTW : 3.28 %
BAM.PR.P FixedReset 96,780 Nesbitt crossed 68,700 at 27.20.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.18
Bid-YTW : 5.04 %
SLF.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 61,813 RBC crossed 50,000 at 19.40.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 19.37
Evaluated at bid price : 19.37
Bid-YTW : 5.80 %
IAG.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 50,360 RBC crossed 49,400 at 20.30.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-15
Maturity Price : 20.26
Evaluated at bid price : 20.26
Bid-YTW : 5.73 %
There were 46 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

Excess Reserves at Fed: Another Cross-Current

January 15th, 2010

Excess bank reserves at the Fed were last discussed on PrefBlog when reviewing a New York Fed working paper titled Why are banks holding so many excess reserves?.

The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland has released the Econotrends, January 2010 with an interesting article by John B. Carlson and John Lindner titled Treasury Deposits and Excess Bank Reserves:

An interesting development on the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet is a decline in excess bank reserves. Th is decline has occurred despite an increase in the overall size of the Fed’s balance sheet. Th e key factor accounting for the decline in excess reserves is a substantial increase in U.S. treasury deposits at the Fed, which were made as a consequence of having issued new debt. When the treasury issues debt to the public and deposits the proceeds at the Fed in its general account, bank reserves decline. In normal times, the treasury typically holds some proceeds in Treasury Tax and Loan accounts at commercial banks, which keeps reserves in the banking system. Th is arrangement helps maintain a steady supply of reserves—a desirable outcome for when the Fed sought to keep the fed funds rate near a target rate.

Following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, the Federal Reserve instituted a number of policies that sharply increased bank reserves in excess of required levels. Initially, the Fed sought to absorb most of the new reserves in order to keep the fed funds rate near its target rate. To help in this eff ort, the treasury issued short-term debt at special auctions (called the Supplementary Financing Program or SFP) and placed the proceeds in a new supplemental treasury account at the Federal Reserve. Still, the amount of reserves absorbed could not keep up with the amount of bank reserves that were being created with the Fed’s new credit policies. Subsequently, the fed funds target was lowered to zero, and the immediate need to absorb reserves abated.

In late 2009 the total level of treasury debt approached the limit authorized by Congress. As the SFP issues matured, the SFP deposits were used to redeem them, and excess reserves increased. In December Congress raised the debt ceiling, allowing the treasury to issue new debt. Th is time, the treasury deposited much of the proceeds into its general account with the Fed, which caused the observed decline in excess reserves.


Click for big

Hull & White on AAA Tranches of Subprime

January 15th, 2010

John Hull and Alan White have published a working paper titled The Risk of Tranches Created from Residential Mortgages:

This paper examines, ex-ante, the risk in the tranches of ABSs and ABS CDOs that were created from residential mortgages between 2000 and 2007. Using the criteria of the rating agencies, it tests how wide the AAA tranches can be under different assumptions about the correlation model and recovery rates. It concludes that the AAA ratings assigned to the senior tranches of ABSs were not totally unreasonable. However, the AAA ratings assigned to tranches of Mezz ABS CDOs cannot be justified. The risk of a Mezz ABS CDO tranche depends critically on the correlation between mortgage pools as well as on the correlation model and the thickness of the underlying BBB tranches. The BBB tranches of ABSs cannot be considered equivalent to BBB bonds for the purposes of subsequent securitizations.

This paper won’t be popular amongst the Credit Ratings Agencies Are Evil crowd!

Credit derivatives models often assume that the recovery rate realized when there is a default is constant. This is less than ideal. As the default rate increases, the recovery rate for a particular asset class can be expected to decline. This is because a high default rate leads to more of the assets coming on the market and a reduction in price.

As is now well known, this argument is particularly true for residential mortgages. In a normal market, a recovery rate of about 75% is often assumed for this asset class. If this is assumed to be the recovery rate in all situations, the worst possible loss on a portfolio of residential mortgages given by the model would be 25%, and the 25% to 100% senior tranche of an ABS created from the mortgages could reasonably be assumed to be safe. In fact, recovery rates on mortgages have declined in the high default rate environment experienced since 2007.

The evaluation of ABSs depends on a) the expected default rate, Q, for mortgages in the underlying pool, b) the default correlation, ρ, for mortgages in the pool, and c) the recovery rate, R. Data from the 1999 to 2006 period suggest a value of Q less than 5% assuming an average mortgage life of 5 years. But, as has been mentioned, a different macroeconomic environment could be anticipated over the next few years. It would seem to be more prudent to use an estimate of 10%, or even higher. We will present results for values of Q equal to 5%, 10%, and 20%. The Basel II capital requirements are based on a copula correlation of 0.15 for residential mortgages.6 We will present results for values of ρ between 0.05 and 0.30. As already mentioned, a recovery rate of 75% is often assumed for residential mortgages, but this is probably optimistic in a high default rate environment. We will present results for the situation where the recovery rate is fixed at 75% and for the situation where the recovery rate model in the previous section is used with Rmin=50% and Rmax=100%.

ABS CDOs also depend on the parameter, α. Loosely speaking, this measures the proportion of the default correlation that comes from a factor common to all pools. A value of α close to zero indicates that investors obtain good diversification benefits from the ABS CDO structure. In adverse market conditions some mezzanine tranches can be expected to suffer 100% losses while others incur no losses. However, a value of α close to one indicates that all mezzanine tranches will tend to sink or swim together. We do not know what estimates rating agencies made for α. (Ex post of course, we know that it was high.) We will therefore present results based on a wide range of values for this parameter.

The meat of the matter – at least as far as the CRAs are concerned – is:

Table 2 shows that when a 20% default rate is combined with a high default correlation, and a stochastic recovery rate model, the AAA ratings that were made seem a little high. Also, the ratings are difficult to justify when the most extreme model (double t copula, stochastic recovery rate) is used. But overall the results in Table 2 indicate that the AAA ratings that were assigned were not totally unreasonable.

Very bad things happened to CDOs created from the mezzanine tranches of the structures – and here the CRAs can be faulted:

It should be noted that a CDO created from the triple BBB tranches of ABSs is quite different from a CDO created from BBB bonds. This is true even when the BBB tranches have been chosen so that their probabilities of default and expected losses are consistent with their BBB rating. The reason is that the probability distribution of the loss from a BBB tranche is quite different from the probability distribution of the loss from a BBB bond.

The authors conclude:

Contrary to many of the opinions that have been expressed, the AAA ratings for the senior tranches of ABSs were not unreasonable. The weighted average life of mortgages is about five years. The probability of loss and expected loss of the AAA-rated tranches that were created were similar to or better than those of AAA-rated five-year bonds.

The AAA ratings for Mezz ABS CDOs are much less defensible. Scenarios where all the underlying BBB tranches lose virtually all their principal are sufficiently probable that it is not reasonable to assign a AAA rating to even a quite thin senior tranche. The risks in Mezz ABS CDOs depend critically on a) the width of the underlying BBB tranches, b) the correlation between pools, c) the tail default correlation, and d) the relationship between the recovery rate and the default rate. An important point is that the BBB tranche of an ABS cannot be assumed to be similar to a BBB bond for the purposes of determining the risks in ABS CDO tranches.

In practice Mezz ABS CDOs accounted for about 3% of all mortgage securitizations. Our conclusion is therefore that the vast majority of the AAA ratings assigned to tranches created from mortgages were reasonable, but in a small minority of the cases they cannot be justified.

I think it’s fair to conclude that the problems of the sub-prime crisis were not with the rating agencies or, to a small degree, with investors who plunked down their money. The problem lay in concentration: the banks took the view that if one is good, two is better … and went the way of all those who fail to diversify sufficiently.

Update: For a review of what participants were thinking at the time, see Making sense of the subprime crisis. For more on subprime default experience, see Subprime! Problems forseeable in 2005?. I will admit, though, that what I’m really waiting for is an accounting of realized losses on subprime paper.

January 14, 2010

January 14th, 2010

Comrade Peace-Price made the punitive taxation of vilified institutions official:

“My commitment is to recover every single dime the American people are owed,” Obama said in a statement released this morning. “My determination to achieve this goal is only heightened when I see reports of massive profits and obscene bonuses at the very firms who owe their continued existence to the American people.”

The levy would be based on bank liabilities and be imposed starting June 30 on companies such as Citigroup Inc., American International Group Inc. and Bank of America Corp. The administration estimates it will raise $90 billion over a minimum of 10 years, said an administration official, who briefed reporters on the condition of anonymity.

As discussed yesterday, the bulk of TARP costs have been for carmakers and individuals, but since when have facts influenced a demagogue?

The SEC has released a Concept Release on Equity Market Structure:

The Securities and Exchange Commission (“Commission”) is conducting a broad review of the current equity market structure. The review includes an evaluation of equity market structure performance in recent years and an assessment of whether market structure rules have kept pace with, among other things, changes in trading technology and practices. To help further its review, the Commission is publishing this concept release to invite public comment on a wide range of market structure issues, including high frequency trading, order routing, market data linkages, and undisplayed, or “dark,” liquidity. The Commission intends to use the public’s comments to help determine whether regulatory initiatives to improve the current equity market structure are needed and, if so, the specific nature of such initiatives.

Meanwhile, the Fed has released a Report to Congress on the Case for a Role for the Federal Reserve in Bank Supervision:

Besides the experience at the Federal Reserve, international developments suggest that a central bank role in supervision can be important. For example, many have suggested that the problems with Northern Rock in the United Kingdom were compounded by a lack of clarity regarding the distribution of powers, responsibilities, and information among the Bank of England, the U.K. Financial Services Authority, and the U.K. Treasury. In response, the Bank of England was given statutory responsibilities in the area of financial stability, its powers to collect information from banks were augmented, and many have called for it to be given increased supervisory authority. In the European Union, a new European Systemic Risk Board is being established under which national central banks and the European Central Bank will play a central role in efforts to protect the financial system from systemic risk. More broadly, in most industrial countries today the central bank has substantial bank supervisory authorities, is responsible for broad financial stability, or both.

There was not a lot of price action in the preferred share market today, at it seems to have found some kind of level after the large gains of early January: PerpetualDiscounts were down 8bp, while FixedResets gained 4bp, on reasonable volume. The day was enlivened by the successful launch of BAM.PR.R.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.5103 % 1,700.8
FixedFloater 5.96 % 4.01 % 35,621 19.01 1 -0.8152 % 2,653.2
Floater 2.31 % 2.65 % 109,498 20.64 3 0.5103 % 2,124.7
OpRet 4.85 % -0.57 % 118,176 0.09 13 -0.0177 % 2,317.4
SplitShare 6.36 % 0.34 % 186,248 0.08 2 0.3519 % 2,113.9
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.0177 % 2,119.0
Perpetual-Premium 5.78 % 5.66 % 142,923 2.26 12 0.0132 % 1,898.7
Perpetual-Discount 5.73 % 5.75 % 180,123 14.26 63 -0.0821 % 1,833.4
FixedReset 5.41 % 3.59 % 330,911 3.85 42 0.0374 % 2,177.3
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -1.28 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 21.61
Evaluated at bid price : 21.61
Bid-YTW : 5.83 %
W.PR.H Perpetual-Discount -1.11 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 22.57
Evaluated at bid price : 23.24
Bid-YTW : 5.92 %
RY.PR.P FixedReset -1.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.65
Bid-YTW : 3.77 %
BAM.PR.B Floater 1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 14.91
Evaluated at bid price : 14.91
Bid-YTW : 2.65 %
ELF.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.77 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 18.43
Evaluated at bid price : 18.43
Bid-YTW : 6.49 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BAM.PR.R FixedReset 614,165 New issue settled today.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 23.17
Evaluated at bid price : 25.26
Bid-YTW : 4.89 %
RY.PR.L FixedReset 133,433 Nesbitt crossed 120,000 at 27.22.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.20
Bid-YTW : 3.53 %
TD.PR.R Perpetual-Premium 74,160 RBC crossed 72,000 at 24.90.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 24.54
Evaluated at bid price : 24.76
Bid-YTW : 5.67 %
GWO.PR.J FixedReset 72,492 RBC bought two blocks of 25,000 shares and one of 20,100 shares from anonymous, all at 27.34.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.31
Bid-YTW : 3.59 %
CM.PR.A OpRet 56,911 Desjardins crossed 27,500 at 26.28 and sold 16,500 to Nesbitt at 26.29. I want a commission!
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-02-13
Maturity Price : 25.25
Evaluated at bid price : 26.30
Bid-YTW : -42.29 %
BNS.PR.P FixedReset 45,108 RBC crossed 24,900 at 26.40.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-05-25
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.40
Bid-YTW : 3.17 %
There were 35 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

BAM.PR.R Achieves Solid Premium on Heavy Volume

January 14th, 2010

BAM.PR.R, the new FixedReset 5.40%+230 announced January 5 closed today and was able to close well above par on heavy volume. The issue traded 614,165 shares in a range of 24.95-30 before closing at 25.26-30, 8×61.

Vital statistics are:

BAM.PR.R FixedReset YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-01-14
Maturity Price : 23.17
Evaluated at bid price : 25.26
Bid-YTW : 4.89 %

BAM.PR.R is tracked by HIMIPref™. It has been added to the FixedResets subindex.

DBRS Releases Global Bank Rating Methodology

January 14th, 2010

DBRS has released its Global Methodology for Rating Banks and Banking Organisations that has some snippets of interest for preferred share investors:

DBRS notes that the regulatory focus on Tier 1 capital is evolving with increased focus on core Tier 1 capital that excludes hybrids. We will adjust our methodology in the future to reflect any changes in emphasis or requirements.

To assess leverage, another capital measure that we employ is the ratio of Tier 1 capital to tangible assets. This ratio, or a variation of it, is applied to banks in a number of countries. It is generally more constraining than the Basel ratios, as assets are not risk-adjusted, although no adjustment is made for off-balance sheet exposures. We anticipate that there is likely to be pressure for adoption of some variation on this leverage ratio in more countries in the aftermath of the crisis.

Taking advantage of the regulatory risk weightings, DBRS considers the ratio of tangible common equity to RWA. Refl ecting DBRS’s preference for equity over hybrids as a cushion for bondholders and other senior creditors, this ratio excludes the hybrid securities that are given full weight by the regulators, up to certain limits.

In the light of Sheila Bair’s testimony to the Crisis Committee, the following extract is interesting:

By their nature, however, these businesses, if poorly run with inadequate risk management, can detract from a bank’s strengths and constrain its ratings. It is worth noting again that while banks had extraordinary losses in their trading businesses in this cycle, most of the losses were concentrated in few business lines, primarily in certain areas of fi xed income, related to origination, structuring and packaging various forms of credit and more complex securities. Risk management of trading activities was predominantly successful in helping banks generate revenues and earnings across many of their trading businesses. The analysis focuses on the trading and other capital markets businesses, but does not ignore other exposures to market risk.