Sloppy Indeed!

October 2nd, 2008

It will not have escaped notice that equities got crushed today:

Canadian stocks tumbled the most in almost eight years, led by a record drop in raw-material shares, as tighter credit, rising unemployment and lower home prices threatened to tip the U.S. into a recession.

Potash Corp. of Saskatchewan Inc. fell the most since 1989 after rival Mosaic Co. posted profit that missed analysts’ estimates and cut its sales forecast. Barrick Gold Corp. plunged the most in two decades as bullion declined on speculation the U.S. will approve a $700 billion plan to revive credit markets, reducing the metal’s appeal.

Suncor Energy Inc. touched the lowest in 15 years, leading oil and gas producers lower as crude fell below $95 a barrel and Merrill Lynch & Co. said it may drop to $50. The Standard & Poor’s/TSX Composite Index fell 7 percent to 10,900.54 in Toronto, the most since Oct. 25, 2000.

Preferreds were not immune, although the TXPR’s loss of 1.02% looks a whole better than ‘first-loss’ equities!

But the really illuminating thing about the action is just how SLOPPY this market is. I mean, look … if you want to tell me that the proper yield for preferreds in this environment is X, I’ll listen! For a while, anyway. That sort of speculation is simply market timing and I don’t put much credence in it.

But surely similar securities from the same issuer should trade somewhere around each other! But that’s not the case today … the yield curve has been getting sloppier and sloppier over the past couple of weeks and today … well, I haven’t checked, but it must be some kind of record!

Internal Spreads on
Perpetual Discount Issues
Issuer High Bid Yield Low Bid Yield High/Low
Series ID
BMO 6.62% 6.26% H, L
BNS 5.89% 5.70% N, K
CM 7.07% 6.93% E, I
GWO 6.70% 5.97% H, F
NA 6.39% 6.23% K, L
POW 6.78% 6.38% (B & D), A
PWF 6.54% 6.06% L, E
RY 6.29% 6.11% W, H
SLF 6.34% 6.24% D, B
TD 6.15% 5.84% O, (Q & R)
Issuers included in list if they have at least three issues listed in the “PerpetualDiscount” index

Speaking very generally, there appears to be some positive correlation between Average Daily Trading Value and Yield – that is, the higher the average volume, the higher the yield, which is to say: the liquidity premium is negative … which really shouldn’t happen.

This behavior is consistent with people simply reducing exposure by selling whatever’s easiest to sell, regardless of price.

The weighted mean average pre-tax bid-YTW of the PerpetualDiscount index is now 6.37%, which is about where it was on July 11 (going up) and July 28 (going down). This is equivalent to 8.92% interest at the standard conversion factor of 1.4x. Long corporates now yield about 6.7%, so the PTIE spread is now about 220bp.

SPL.A Downgraded to "D" by DBRS

October 2nd, 2008

DBRS has announced that it:

has today downgraded the Class A Shares issued by Mulvihill Pro-AMS RSP Split Share Corp. (the Company) to D from Pfd-5.

After paying offering expenses and an initial contribution to a Class B Shares forward agreement, the net proceeds from the initial offering were invested in a diversified portfolio of Canadian and U.S. equities (the Managed Portfolio), providing asset coverage of approximately 1.8 times to the Class A Shares. In addition to providing principal protection for the Class A Shares, the Managed Portfolio has been used to make fixed cumulative monthly distributions to the Class A Shares equal to 6.5% per annum and to pay annual fees and expenses. In addition to this, the Company has been making semi-annual contributions of $0.43 per Class A Share from the Managed Portfolio to a forward agreement with the Counterparty for the repayment of the Class A Shares principal on December 31, 2013 (the Termination Date).

On September 3, 2008, the Company announced that distributions to the Class A Shares would be suspended subsequent to the September 2008 distribution payment in order to provide greater certainty to the repayment of principal.

The Managed Portfolio has declined more than 90% since inception. About one-third of the decline has resulted from the semi-annual contributions to the Class A Forward Account. Based on previous contributions to the Class A Forward Account, the Counterparty has guaranteed to repay 89.8% of the Class A Shares principal amount on the Termination Date. The current net asset value (NAV) of the Managed Portfolio is $1.48 (as of September 25, 2008), which is sufficient for the Company to contribute the remaining funds necessary to secure 100% of the principal amount on the Termination Date through the forward agreement. However, there is an additional $3.41 per Class A Share in cumulative dividends still to be paid at maturity. In order for the Company to repay full principal and cumulative dividends on the Termination Date, a return of 23% per year on the Managed Portfolio is required. Once Company expenses are taken into account, the return required to meet all Class A Shares principal and dividend obligations increases to more than 40% per year. Based on the foregoing, DBRS has downgraded the rating of the Class A Shares to D.

SPL.A was last mentioned on PrefBlog when it was downgraded to Pfd-5. SPL.A is tracked by HIMIPref™ and is included in the “Scraps” index – it would be SplitShare … but there are credit concerns!

Index Performance: September 2008

October 2nd, 2008

Performance of the HIMIPref™ Indices for September, 2008, was:

Total Return
Index Performance
September 2008
Three Months
to
September 30, 2008
Ratchet N/A N/A
FixFloat -2.88% +5.09%
Floater -14.79% -14.05%
OpRet -2.01% -1.87%
SplitShare -6.97% -6.39%
Interest -4.42% -3.82%
PerpetualPremium -1.42% -1.82%
PerpetualDiscount -2.31% -1.89%
FixedReset N/A N/A
Funds (see below for calculations)
CPD -2.89% -2.72%
DPS.UN -3.70% -4.29%
Index
BMO-CM 50 -2.59% -1.88%

Claymore has published NAV and distribution data for its exchange traded fund (CPD) and I have derived the following table:

CPD Return, 1- & 3-month, to September, 2008
Date NAV Distribution Return for Sub-Period Monthly Return
June 30 16.88 0.00    
July 31, 2008 16.50 0.00   -2.25%
August 29 16.91 0.00   +2.48%
Sept 25 16.41 0.2135 -1.69% -2.89%
Sept 30, 2008 16.21   -1.22%
Quarterly Return -2.72%

The DPS.UN NAV for October has been published so we may calculate the September returns (approximately!) for this closed end fund:

DPS.UN NAV Return, September-ish 2008
Date NAV Distribution Return for period
August 27 $20.03   +2.82%
Estimated August Stub +0.12%
Sept 24 19.64   -2.07%
Sept 26 19.3321
Estimate
0.30 -0.04%
Estimate
October 1, 2008 18.97   -1.87%
Estimated October Stub -0.25%
Estimated September Return -3.70%
CPD had a NAV of $16.89 on August 27 and $16.91 on August 29. The estimated August end-of-month stub period return for CPD was therefore +0.12%, which is added to the DPS.UN period return.
The return for the period August 27-Sept 24 was -1.95%; since the August stub period return was +0.12%, the August 29-September 24 return is estimated as -2.07%
CPD had NAVs of $16.63, 16.41 & 16.41 on September 24, 25 & 26, respectively; a distribution of $0.2135 was paid with a Sept. 25 ex-date. Total return for September 24-26 was therefore -0.04%.
CPD had a NAV of $16.17 on October 1 and $16.21 on September. The estimated October beginning of month stub period return for CPD was therefore -0.25%, which is added to the DPS.UN period return to estimate a return for the period of -1.62%.
The September return for DPS.UN’s NAV is therefore the product of three period returns, -2.07%, -0.04% and -1.62%, to arrive at an estimate for the calendar month of -3.70%

Now, to see the DPS.UN quarterly NAV approximate return, we refer to the calculations for July and August:

DPS.UN NAV Returns, three-month-ish to end-September-ish, 2008
July-ish -3.16%
August-ish +2.63%
September-ish -3.70%
Three-months-ish -4.29%

October 1, 2008

October 1st, 2008

Just imagine that there are penetrating and astute observations being made here today, OK?

European bank bail-out friction

Possible higher risk-weight for ABS in Europe

Squabbles and alleged skullduggery at Reserve Primary Fund

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30.
The Fixed-Reset index was added effective 2008-9-5 at that day’s closing value of 1,119.4 for the Fixed-Floater index.
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet N/A N/A N/A N/A 0 N/A N/A
Fixed-Floater 4.77% 4.85% 82,740 15.70 6 -0.3554% 1,077.7
Floater 5.36% 5.40% 48,769 14.87 2 -3.3543% 750.8
Op. Retract 5.08% 5.18% 126,326 3.72 14 -0.2095% 1,031.0
Split-Share 5.80% 8.01% 56,785 4.10 12 -0.1437% 968.8
Interest Bearing 6.43% 7.25% 42,707 3.77 3 -0.5934% 1,073.4
Perpetual-Premium 6.25% 6.29% 54,941 13.49 1 0.0000% 993.0
Perpetual-Discount 6.22% 6.29% 179,982 13.49 70 -0.0069% 860.6
Fixed-Reset 5.10% 4.99% 1,186,721 15.32 10 -0.1918% 1,110.8
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
BAM.PR.K Floater -6.0000% Closed at 15.51-16.74, with the tmxmoney.com reporting the size as 0x3. Volume 525 shares in the morning, nothing in the afternoon. Ho-hum, just another day of market-making at the Toronto Exchange.
BAM.PR.J OpRet -4.7064% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.18% based on a bid of 20.57 and a softMaturity 2018-3-30 at 25.00. Compare with BAM.PR.H (7.11% to 2012-3-30), BAM.PR.I (6.84% to 2013-12-30) and BAM.PR.O (8.84% to 2013-6-30); and with the perpetuals at about 7.6%.
DFN.PR.A SplitShare -2.2581% Asset coverage of just under 2.3:1 as of September 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.15% based on a bid of 9.09 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00.
POW.PR.B PerpetualDiscount -2.1359% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.67% based on a bid of 20.16 and a limitMaturity.
WFS.PR.A SplitShare -2.0000% Asset coverage of just under 1.6:1 as of September 18, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 10.39% based on a bid of 8.82 and a hardMaturity 2011-6-30. Below $9, some might find even the regular monthly retraction to be attractive.
BCE.PR.C FixFloat -1.5612%  
BCE.PR.Z FixFloat -1.4614%  
GWO.PR.I PerpetualDiscount -1.3714% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.57% based on a bid of 17.26 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.P PerpetualDiscount -1.2981% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.86% based on a bid of 22.81 and a limitMaturity.
PWF.PR.L PerpetualDiscount -1.2458% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.31% based on a bid of 20.61 and a limitMaturity.
FIG.PR.A InterestBearing -1.2245% Asset coverage of 1.7+:1 as of September 29 according to Faircourt. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.95% (mostly as interest) based on a bid of 9.68 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-31 at 10.00
BCE.PR.Y FixFloat -1.2220%  
FTN.PR.A SplitShare -1.1364% Asset coverage of just under 2.2:1 as of September 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.70% based on a bid of 8.70 and a hardMaturity 2015-12-1 at 10.00
GWO.PR.H PerpetualDiscount -1.0633% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.57% based on a bid of 18.61 and a limitMaturity.
BNA.PR.C SplitShare -1.0338% Asset coverage of 3.2+:1 as of August 31 according to the company. Coverage now of just under 2.8:1 based on BAM.A at 28.97 and 2.4 BAM.A held per preferred. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 11.68% (!) based on a bid of 14.36 and a hardMaturity 2019-1-10 at 25.00. Compare with BNA.PR.A (9.60% to 2010-9-30) and BNA.PR.B (9.54% to 2016-3-25).
BCE.PR.A FixFloat -1.0309%  
BAM.PR.H OpRet -1.0305% See BAM.PR.J, above
FBS.PR.B SplitShare +1.1957% Asset coverage of 1.6+:1 as of September 25, according to TD Securities. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.33% based on a bid of 9.31 and a hardMaturity 2011-12-15 at 10.00
CIU.PR.A PerpetualDiscount +1.2625% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.05% based on a bid of 19.25 and a limitMaturity.
HSB.PR.C PerpetualDiscount +1.3131% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.41% based on a bid of 20.06 and a limitMaturity.
GWO.PR.G PerpetualDiscount +1.6183% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.14% based on a bid of 21.35 and a limitMaturity.
BCE.PR.G FixFloat +1.9108%  
LFE.PR.A SplitShare +1.9629% Asset coverage of 2.2+:1 as of September 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.12% based on a bid of 9.35 and a hardMaturity 2012-12-1 at 10.00
W.PR.H PerpetualDiscount +2.0202% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.84% based on a bid of 20.20 and a limitMaturity.
POW.PR.A PerpetualDiscount +2.2770% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.38% based on a bid of 22.01 and a limitMaturity.
SBN.PR.A SplitShare +2.7397% Asset coverage of 2.1+:1 as of September 18, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.38% based on a bid of 9.00 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00.
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
SLF.PR.E PerpetualDiscount 84,132 Desjardins crossed 75,000 at 18.35. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.22% based on a bid of 18.24 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.E PerpetualDiscount 73,500 Nesbitt crossed 13,000 at 20.30, TD crossed 60,000 at 20.10. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.02% based on a bid of 20.01 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.M PerpetualDiscount 69,400 Nesbitt crossed 50,000 at 19.75. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.81% based on a bid of 19.73 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.D PerpetualDiscount 58,784 TD crossed 49,800 at 20.75. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.98% based on a bid of 20.66 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.R FixedReset 57,820 RBC bought 10,000 and 25,000, both lots at 24.85, both from anonymous.

There were seventeen other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

Synthetic Extended Deposit Insurance – the Critique

October 1st, 2008

Maximizing deposit insurance coverage is a favourite topic with my friends at Financial Webring Forum – see, for example, the thread Multiple RRSP accounts advisable when reach $100k?, and that’s only the first one I found. People go into endless loving detail about how to maximize coverage through use of separate accounts for spouses, joint accounts, trust accounts, multiple institutions … in the States, there’s an outfit called Promontory that handles all that for a fee.

I mentioned Promontory briefly yesterday:

There has been some criticism of a diversification service which allows large deposits to be distributed amongst many banks and be entirely insured:

“When I first saw Promontory, I was amazed that the regulators would let it fly,” says Sherrill Shaffer, a former chief economist at the New York Federal Reserve Bank. “It undermines a lot of the safeguards around the FDIC deposit fund. I’m astounded that the FDIC has not picked up on that and tried to shut down that loophole.”

The loophole Promontory exploits is the FDIC rule that allows an individual to open up federally insured accounts of up to $100,000 at an unlimited number of banks.

Edward Kane, senior fellow of the FDIC’s Center for Financial Research, says CDARS intercepts FDIC premiums.

“It’s portrayed as a public-spirited way to help customers as opposed to a way to game the system,” he says. “They’ve decided there’s a loophole that they’re in charge of.”

… which I confess I don’t understand. The only legitimate criticism I have been able to come up with is that it exploits the minimum and therefore deprives the financial system as a whole of the due diligence that would arise from a large depositor being worried about the soundness of the bank he uses. But this concern is not consistent with the criticism in the article, or with the level of disdain for the process expressed.

However, I have had some discussion with specialists in the field; the concern is that the FDIC is insuring all deposits anyway – the Wachovia deal – and should get paid for it. Infinite deposit insurance! Now there’s a moral hazard issue if ever there was one. Problems at IndyMac & WaMu and the subsequent wipe-out of common shareholders were brought to a head by a run on deposits … it seems to me that infinite deposit insurance will allow banks to ignore the hazards of losing confidence.

So, when you don’t understand something, you ask a question, right? It saves a lot of time. I sent an eMail to Prof. Sherrill Shaffer:

You are quoted in the captioned story at [Bloomberg] as saying ““When I first saw Promontory, I was amazed that the regulators would let it fly. It undermines a lot of the safeguards around the FDIC deposit fund. I’m astounded that the FDIC has not picked up on that and tried to shut down that loophole.”

I regret that I do not understand your criticism. If we can accept that FDIC premia are computed rationally and based on insured deposits, then Promontory is simply engaged in an exchange of value.

The only criticism I have been able to come up with is that when a large depositor’s assets are diversified amongst banks in this manner, the system as a whole is deprived of the due diligence that he might otherwise do if the bulk of the deposit was uninsured. But the Bloomberg story does not bring up this critique.

I would be very grateful if you could help me understand your concern.

Dr. Shaffer was kind enough to respond at length and to grant permission to be quoted.

You are correct that extended deposit insurance coverage (whether statutory or synthesized) does tend to reduce the degree of market discipline exerted by large depositors.

The more market discipline that’s in place, the better it is for everybody … although it should be noted that I am referring to market discipline that is rational. The excesses of irrational (or uninformed) market discipline is what causes perfectly good banks to suffer runs in the first place, which is why the discount window was invented. The Panic of 1907 is the classic example, but there is also the Panic of 1825 and the events following the collapse of Overend and Gurney.

It should be noted, however, that evidence of rational market discipline of banks is a little hard to come by. In the post Banks and Subordinated Debt, I highlighted the Cleveland Fed’s mostly vain attempt to extract useful information from credit spreads. Given that it is institutional investors who will determine these spreads – and FIXED INCOME institutional investors at that, who are well known to be both much smarter and better looking than the equity guys – I suggest that hopes for market discipline exerted by large retail depositors is more of an expression of piety than the foundation of successful regulation.

You are also correct that Promontory would be engaged in a simple exchange of value if the FDIC premia were computed on the basis of insured deposits. However, FDIC premia are instead computed as a fraction of (essentially) total domestic deposits, not merely insured deposits. (The exact assessment base is total deposits, less foreign deposits, less cash & due from depository institutions, less pass-through reserve balances, less a few smaller exclusions – please see pages 2-3 of the attached file.) Under this current system, any means of extending deposit insurance coverage to a larger fraction of total domestic deposits does not directly result in larger premium payments to the FDIC.

I have uploaded the file regarding FDIC assessments.

I hadn’t been aware of that. I am open to correction, but it seems to me that establishing deposit insurance premia based on total deposits rather than insured deposits rather undermines the policy objective of market discipline:

  • The FDIC will be on the moral defensive should it wish to enforce the limit at the expense of uninsured depositors
  • There is no advantage to the insured institution, in terms of premia, to establish a reputation for soundness that will attract uninsured deposits.
  • There is less room than there might otherwise be for institutions to offer higher rates for uninsured deposits, rewarding depositors for the (perceived) additional risk

Rather, the banking industry as a whole is assessed higher premium rates in years when the FDIC’s fund drops below the Designated Reserve Ratio spelled out in federal law. To the extent that Promontory member banks impose larger losses on the FDIC when they fail, non-Promontory banks help pay the tab to the same extent as Promontory banks, and thus cross-subsidize the extra coverage provided to Promontory banks.

So the first problem caused by CDARS is that the FDIC is not compensated for the additional risk ex ante, and any ex post compensation involves an element of cross-subsidization from non-CDARS banks. This is the “unpriced risk” concern.

I agree, all this follows from the fact that premia are charged on uninsured deposits at the same rate as insured ones.

A second problem is that, if our policy makers desired to extend deposit insurance coverage to larger accounts, doing so by statute would avoid the overhead costs (data base costs, marketing costs, administrative and executive costs, etc.) associated with a synthesized coverage such as CDARS. Those overhead costs therefore represent a deadweight loss, paid directly by CDARS banks but ultimately passed on to society. This is the “efficiency concern.”

This is a familiar argument that is seen in virtually everything that can be construed as a “public good” – medicare, toll-roads, transit, you-name-it – not just deposit insurance. One’s views on this question will be heavily influenced by idealogy; there’s no need to go into it in detail here.

There’s not enough information, either! If there was, in fact, a two-tiered deposit system in which the market clearly differentiated between insured and uninsured deposits, then we could start dissecting the data to determine where the line between the two should be drawn. But there ain’t, so we won’t.

A third problem, more philosophical in nature, is that Congress has periodically re-visited the question of whether $100,000 is an appropriate ceiling on FDIC coverage, and thus far has rejected the alternative of raising that cap (although that may change soon). By achieving a much larger cap of $50 million for participating banks, CDARS legally circumvents the expressed intent of Congress. Equivalently, we can view CDARS as extending to all depositors the same protection accorded to depositors in “too-big-to-fail” banks – a protection that Congress has explicitly sought to limit, as in some provisions of the 1991 FDIC Improvement Act. Thus, the effect of CDARS runs contrary to the spirit, though not the letter, of federal law.

On the other hand, one might consider CDARS as being a simple diversification mechanism … like a mutual fund in many ways, although the big difference is that the “diversification” is simply a mechanism to achieve concentration in FDIC’s credit strength. I will suggest that a great deal of this problem would be solved if Congress applied the same limit to premium calculation as it does to insurance coverage.

*********************

There are other cross-currents in the mix. I have briefly mentioned (most recently on May 16) the Fed’s decade-long drive to pay interest on reserves; the idea being that increasing the attractiveness to banks of reservable deposits will assist the Fed to transmit its monetary policy to the broader economy. And we have recently witnessed the bizarre occurance of Treasury writing Credit Default Swaps on MMFs (see September 19) … it’s totally unclear to me what long-term influence that might have, and whether policy will change to require banks to hold capital against branded MMFs.

As far as I know, the CDIC charges premia based on insured deposits only:

Premiums are based on the total amount of insured deposits held by members as of April 30th each year, calculated in accordance with the CDIC Act and its Differential Premiums By-law, which classifies member institutions into one of four premium categories.

Classification is based on a mix of quantitative and qualitative factors. Premium rates in effect for the 2006 premium year, unchanged from 2005, were as follows:
• Category 1—1/72nd of 1% of insured deposits
• Category 2—1/36th of 1% of insured deposits
• Category 3—1/18th of 1% of insured deposits
• Category 4—1/9th of 1% of insured deposits

Note that 2007 “saw 98 percent of its members ranked in the best rated premium categories”. So much for this great-sounding differential premia song-and-dance!

These are strange times and the public demands the right never to lose money on short term investments, particularly the ones that pay higher interest than stinky old T-Bills. But I want to thank Dr. Shaffer again for taking the time to respond in such detail to my eMail.

Update 2008-10-3 Dr. Shaffer has read this post and comments:

Although I haven’t yet begun to dwell on such possibilities, much of the problem would be solved if the FDIC’s premium rate structure could be revised to charge banks in proportion to their insured deposits rather than their total domestic deposits.

A further option could be considered under such a revision: Banks could perhaps be given their choice of what level of coverage to receive (and pay for), whether $100,000 or some larger amount. As long as the pricing was actuarially fair, any such choices would be revenue-neutral to the FDIC on average.

Of course, choosing a larger level of coverage would tend to undermine market discipline, as you corrected noted. But recent events have indicated that the existing market discipline was already inadequate to constrain risk-taking at many institutions, even with the post-1980
$100,000 limit.

The idea of letting the banks themselves decide where to the draw the line is an attractive free-market solution, but I’m not convinced (yet!) that such a move would be in the public interest.

I perceive deposit insurance to serve the purpose of:

  • To aid the economy by letting Mom and Pop know that they are perfectly safe in keeping a cash float at the bank
  • To reduce the risk of self-feeding runs on the banks that might otherwise occur if Mom & Pop decide that their emergency stash is not safe
  • As a public service, so that Mom & Pop don’t have to read and understand a bank’s annual report prior to depositing the weekly paycheque

If everybody was a professional fixed income analyst, there would be no need for deposit insurance at all. And therefore, I say, a variable cut-off (however attractive theoretically) is simply too complicated. Let Mom & Pop know that if they invest their tuppence wisely in the bank it will be safe and sound; and any bank has the same magic number to remember. Simply because of the policy objective to simplify the process.

Incidentally, I think the $100,000 limit is far too high to begin with. Given my views on the proper policy objective, I think that something along the lines of “median household annual income, rounded up to next $10,000, reviewed every five years” is much better. If you have more than that (in cash!) … well, sorry guys, either diversify your banks or buy a money market fund.

Update #2, 2008-10-3: In accordance with legislation passed today, the limit is now $250,000 until Dec. 31, 2009, according to the FDIC.

The Savings & Loan Crisis

October 1st, 2008

I started hunting for a good reference after reading Assiduous Reader lystgl‘s quotation in the comments to September 30.

Timothy Curry and Lynn Shibut of the FDIC wrote a paper for the FDIC Banking Review, The Cost of the Savings and Loan Crisis: Truth and Consequences.

It seems, not surprisingly, that there are a lot of estimates of the cost, which I assume are influenced by political considerations:

Over time, misinformation about the cost of the crisis has been widespread; some published reports have placed the cost at less than $100 billion, and others as high as $500 billion.

Some numbers which provide perspective – and will, I assume, not be particularly controversial – are provided in Table 1. From 1986-1989, there were 296 failures with assets of $125-billion addressed by the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation; from 1989-1995 there were 747 failures with assets of $394-billion addressed by Resolution Trust Corp.

As of year-end 1986, 441 thrifts with $113 billion in assets were book insolvent, and another 533 thrifts, with $453 billion in assets, had tangible capital of no more than 2 percent of total assets. These 974 thrifts held 47 percent of industry assets.

One of the problems with estimating the costs of this mess is ‘what to do about interest charges’:

During the FSLIC and RTC eras, the industry contributed $38.3 billion sometimes in partnership with the Treasury) in funding for the cleanup. Special government-established financing entities (FICO and REFCORP) raised these funds by selling long-term bonds in the capital markets. The Treasury contributed another $99 billion, 14 some or all of which was also borrowed because the federal government was experiencing large budget deficits during the period. When some analysts tabulated the costs of the cleanup, they included not only the principal borrowed but also interest costs for periods of up to 30 to 40 years on some or all of the borrowings.

Including the financing costs in addition to principal could easily double or triple the estimates of the final cost of the cleanup. However, in our view, including financing costs when tallying the costs of the thrift crisis is methodologically incorrect. It is invalid because, in present value terms, the amount borrowed is equal to the sum of the interest charges plus debt repayment. Adding the sum of interest payments to the amount borrowed would overstate the true economic cost of resolving the crisis.

The authors present their calculations with admirable clarity – I don’t know how much dispute there still might be over the total figure, but their tables look like a very good place to start reconciling differences – and conclude:

The savings and loan crisis of the 1980s and early 1990s produced the greatest collapse of U.S. financial institutions since the Great Depression. Over the 1986–1995 period, 1,043 thrifts with total assets of over $500 billion failed. The large number of failures overwhelmed the resources of the FSLIC, so U.S. taxpayers were required to back up the commitment extended to insured depositors of the failed institutions. As of December 31, 1999, the thrift crisis had cost taxpayers approximately $124 billion and the thrift industry another $29 billion, for an estimated total loss of approximately $153 billion. The losses were higher than those predicted in the late 1980s, when the RTC was established, but below those forecasted during the early to mid-1990s, at the height of the crisis.

HIMIPref™ Index Rebalancing: September 2008

October 1st, 2008
HIMI Index Changes, September 30, 2008
Issue From To Because
SBN.PR.A SplitShare Scraps Volume
DF.PR.A SplitShare Scraps Volume
STW.PR.A Scraps InterestBearing Volume

There were the following intra-month changes:

HIMI Index Changes during September 2008
Issue Action Index Because
BNS.PR.R Add FixedReset New Issue
CM.PR.K Add FixedReset New Issue
TD.PR.A Add FixedReset New Issue
RY.PR.I Add FixedReset New Issue
IQW.PR.D Delete Scraps Price

The Fixed-Reset Index was inaugurated and previously extant but untracked issues added to the database on a backdated basis; the 9/30 position has been uploaded.

September 30, 2008

September 30th, 2008

The Irish Government has announced its own bailout:

The Government has decided to put in place with immediate effect a guarantee arrangement to safeguard all deposits (retail, commercial, institutional and interbank), covered bonds, senior debt and dated subordinated debt (lower tier II), with the following banks: Allied Irish Bank, Bank of Ireland, Anglo Irish Bank, Irish Life and Permanent, Irish Nationwide Building Society and the Educational Building Society and such specific subsidiaries as may be approved by Government following consultation with the Central Bank and the Financial Regulator. It has done so following advice from the Governor of the Central Bank and the Financial Regulator about the impact of the recent international market turmoil on the Irish Banking system. The guarantee is being provided at a charge to the institutions concerned and will be subject to specific terms and conditions so that the taxpayers’ interest can be protected. The guarantee will cover all existing aforementioned facilities with these institutions and any new such facilities issued from midnight on 29 September 2008, and will expire at midnight on 28 September 2010.

Guaranteeing sub-debt is breathtaking!

Dexia got a massive European bail-out … equity based:

Belgium and France threw Dexia SA a 6.4 billion-euro ($9.2 billion) lifeline and ousted the chairman and chief executive officer as the widening financial crisis forced governments to prop up institutions across Europe.

The capital infusion for Brussels- and Paris-based Dexia comes two days after Belgium, the Netherlands and Luxembourg agreed to inject 11.2 billion euros into Fortis, the largest Belgian financial-services company. Britain seized Bradford & Bingley Plc, the U.K.’s biggest lender to landlords, while Germany bailed out Hypo Real Estate Holding AG.

And as if poor old Fortis didn’t have enough problems, it looks like they have problems with an asset sale.

Writing in VoxEU, Daniel Gros & Stefano Micossi want to go even further and establish a permanent bail-out authority:

Europe’s largest banks are highly leveraged and thus vulnerable, as Fortis showed. But some of these banks are both too large to fail and too big to be rescued by a single government. The EU should: (1) urgently pass legislation to cover banks with significant cross-border presence and empower the ECB to provide direct support, and (2) create an EU-level rescue fund managed by an existing institution like the European Investment Bank.

And in a familiar scenario, UniCredit’s stock price has plunged because they might need to sell some:

UniCredit SpA, Italy’s biggest bank and the owner of Germany’s HVB Group, tumbled more than 10 percent for the second day in Milan trading amid concern the company may need to raise money to strengthen its finances.

UniCredit fell a record 38 cents, or 13 percent, to 2.60 euros, giving the bank a market value of about 34 billion euros ($48 billion). The stock, at its lowest since Dec. 4, 1997, has fallen 55 percent this year, compared with the 41 percent slide in the 69-member Bloomberg Europe Banks and Financial Services Index.

The fun isn’t confined to the banking sector: Jefferson County’s up against it:

Jefferson County, Alabama, faces a deadline today to reach a new agreement with creditors to avoid defaulting on bonds sold by its municipal sewer system that have pushed the state’s most populous county toward bankruptcy.

The county has won agreements since April with JPMorgan Chase & Co., bond insurers and other creditors to postpone full interest and principal payments on the $3.2 billion of debt it amassed building its sewers. The current agreement, which Governor Bob Riley brokered last month, expires today.

It’s a great time to be desperately in need of money, ain’t it? But don’t worry: Obama’s got a plan:

Barack Obama, the Democratic presidential nominee, today proposed increasing the Federal Deposit Insurance Corp. limit to $250,000 from the current level of $100,000.

In proposing an increase, Obama noted that the current $100,000 limit was set 28 years ago and hasn’t been adjusted for inflation.

Utter craziness. $100,000 in the bank is comfortably in excess of what anybody should have for their day to day needs; small businesses and investors will just have to do their due diligence on their bank of choice if they need to hold more in a single bank. At that level of deposit, it is more than reasonable that bank customers be expected to understand the concept of diversification.

However, the decision appears to be unanimous: both presidential candidates and the FDIC itself want a deposit insurance limit of $250,000.

There has been some criticism of a diversification service which allows large deposits to be distributed amongst many banks and be entirely insured:

“When I first saw Promontory, I was amazed that the regulators would let it fly,” says Sherrill Shaffer, a former chief economist at the New York Federal Reserve Bank. “It undermines a lot of the safeguards around the FDIC deposit fund. I’m astounded that the FDIC has not picked up on that and tried to shut down that loophole.”

The loophole Promontory exploits is the FDIC rule that allows an individual to open up federally insured accounts of up to $100,000 at an unlimited number of banks.

Edward Kane, senior fellow of the FDIC’s Center for Financial Research, says CDARS intercepts FDIC premiums.

“It’s portrayed as a public-spirited way to help customers as opposed to a way to game the system,” he says. “They’ve decided there’s a loophole that they’re in charge of.”

… which I confess I don’t understand. The only legitimate criticism I have been able to come up with is that it exploits the minimum and therefore deprives the financial system as a whole of the due diligence that would arise from a large depositor being worried about the soundness of the bank he uses. But this concern is not consistent with the criticism in the article, or with the level of disdain for the process expressed.

However, I have had some discussion with specialists in the field; the concern is that the FDIC is insuring all deposits anyway – the Wachovia deal – and should get paid for it. Infinite deposit insurance! Now there’s a moral hazard issue if ever there was one. Problems at IndyMac & WaMu and the subsequent wipe-out of common shareholders were brought to a head by a run on deposits … it seems to me that infinite deposit insurance will allow banks to ignore the hazards of losing confidence.

Rumours certain to get the Internuts into a lather are going around: Fair Value Accounting might be getting an overhaul … it’s the endless struggle … expected cash flows vs. market price …

… and the rumours proved true! There is an SEC press release offering “clarifications”:

When an active market for a security does not exist, the use of management estimates that incorporate current market participant expectations of future cash flows, and include appropriate risk premiums, is acceptable.

Further, in some cases using unobservable inputs (level 3) might be more appropriate than using observable inputs (level 2); for example, when significant adjustments are required to available observable inputs it may be appropriate to utilize an estimate based primarily on unobservable inputs.

Broker quotes may be an input when measuring fair value, but are not necessarily determinative if an active market does not exist for the security.

when markets are less active, brokers may rely more on models with inputs based on the information available only to the broker.

The results of disorderly transactions are not determinative when measuring fair value.

Transactions in inactive markets may be inputs when measuring fair value, but would likely not be determinative.

In general, the greater the decline in value, the greater the period of time until anticipated recovery, and the longer the period of time that a decline has existed, the greater the level of evidence necessary to reach a conclusion that an other-than-temporary decline has not occurred.

The last sentence is a classic of the genre.

And that’s all she wrote for September, 2008!

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30.
The Fixed-Reset index was added effective 2008-9-5 at that day’s closing value of 1,119.4 for the Fixed-Floater index.
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet N/A N/A N/A N/A 0 N/A N/A
Fixed-Floater 4.75% 4.83% 85,008 15.73 6 -0.2484% 1,081.5
Floater 5.18% 5.19% 49,223 15.16 2 +1.8867% 776.8
Op. Retract 5.07% 5.09% 128,690 3.73 14 -0.3651% 1,033.2
Split-Share 5.81% 7.93% 51,972 4.27 14 +0.4417% 970.2
Interest Bearing 6.60% 7.61% 51,656 5.16 2 +0.4330% 1,079.9
Perpetual-Premium 6.25% 6.28% 55,818 13.49 1 -0.1996% 993.0
Perpetual-Discount 6.22% 6.29% 181,483 13.49 70 -0.0111% 860.7
Fixed-Reset 5.09% 4.98% 1,216,819 15.34 10 +0.1173% 1,112.9
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
SBN.PR.A SplitShare -7.7895% Asset coverage of 2.1+:1 as of September 18, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.91% based on a bid of 9.50 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00. This thing must trade in Toronto … closing quote of 8.76-9.78, 8×3, volume for the day of a big fat zero. Boy … am I glad I don’t have to put a price on this to evaluate quarter end returns!
BAM.PR.J OpRet -4.7064% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.70% based on a bid of 21.26 and a softMaturity 2018-3-30 at 25.00. Compare with BAM.PR.H (6.76% to 2012-3-30), BAM.PR.I (7.06% to 2013-12-30) and BAM.PR.O (8.84% to 2013-6-30).
POW.PR.D PerpetualDiscount -3.3924% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.58% based on a bid of 19.08 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.D PerpetualDiscount -2.8436% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.03% based on a bid of 20.50 and a limitMaturity.
POW.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -2.4878% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.63% based on a bid of 21.95 and a limitMaturity.
W.PR.H PerpetualDiscount -2.3669% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.98% based on a bid of 19.80 and a limitMaturity.
POW.PR.B PerpetualDiscount -2.2770% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.52% based on a bid of 20.60 and a limitMaturity.
HSB.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -2.1256% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.49% based on a bid of 19.80 and a limitMaturity.
ALB.PR.A SplitShare -2.0833% Asset coverage of 1.7+:1 as of September 25 according to Scotia Managed Companies. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.12% based on a bid of 23.03 and a hardMaturity 2011-2-28 at 25.00
GWO.PR.I PerpetualDiscount -2.0157% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.48% based on a bid of 17.50 and a limitMaturity.
BMO.PR.K PerpetualDiscount -1.6317% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.31% based on a bid of 21.10 and a limitMaturity.
LBS.PR.A SplitShare -1.1543% Asset coverage of just under 2.1:1 as of September 25 according to Brompton Group. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.59% based on a bid of 9.42 and a hardMaturity 2013-11-29 at 10.00.
BCE.PR.I FixFloat -1.0309%  
BAM.PR.I OpRet -1.0165% See BAM.PR.J, above.
CM.PR.P PerpetualDiscount +1.0050% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.86% based on a bid of 20.10 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.A FixedReset +1.0142%  
BAM.PR.H OpRet +1.0833%  
SLF.PR.A PerpetualDiscount +1.0938% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.17% based on a bid of 19.41 and a limitMaturity.
NA.PR.M PerpetualDiscount +1.1929% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.19% based on a bid of 24.60 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.H PerpetualDiscount +1.2815% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.04% based on a bid of 23.71 and a limitMaturity.
LFE.PR.A SplitShare +1.3260% Asset coverage of 2.2+:1 as of September 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.65% based on a bid of 9.17 and a hardMaturity 2012-12-1 at 10.00
ELF.PR.F PerpetualDiscount +1.4456% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.70% based on a bid of 17.30 and a limitMaturity.
ELF.PR.G PerpetualDiscount +1.5334% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.44% based on a bid of 16.05 and a limitMaturity.
FBS.PR.B SplitShare +1.5453% Asset coverage of 1.6+:1 as of September 25, according to TD Securities. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.73% based on a bid of 9.20 and a hardMaturity 2011-12-15 at 10.00
SLF.PR.E PerpetualDiscount +1.5495% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.18% based on a bid of 18.35 and a limitMaturity.
SLF.PR.D PerpetualDiscount +1.7778% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.12% based on a bid of 18.32 and a limitMaturity.
CU.PR.B PerpetualDiscount +2.0408% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.07% based on a bid of 25.00 and a limitMaturity.
WFS.PR.A SplitShare +2.2727% Asset coverage of just under 1.6:1 as of September 18, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.55% based on a bid of 9.00 and a hardMaturity 2011-6-30. Below $9, some might find even the regular monthly retraction to be attractive.
CM.PR.J PerpetualDiscount +2.4450% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.73% based on a bid of 16.76 and a limitMaturity.
DFN.PR.A SplitShare +2.8761% Asset coverage of just under 2.3:1 as of September 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.70% based on a bid of 9.30 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00.
BAM.PR.K Floater +3.0606%  
BNA.PR.A SplitShare +4.4444% Asset coverage of 3.2+:1 as of August 31 according to the company. Coverage now of 2.7+:1 based on BAM.A at 28.69 and 2.4 BAM.A held per preferred. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.94% (!) based on a bid of 23.50 and a hardMaturity 2010-9-30 at 25.00. Compare with BNA.PR.B (9.64% to 2016-3-25) and BNA.PR.C (11.53% to 2019-1-10).
FFN.PR.A SplitShare +4.5296% Asset coverage of just under 1.8:1 as of September 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.35% based on a bid of 9.00 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00. Note that according to the prospectus, October is the Special Annual Concurrent Retraction month, so things could get interesting!
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
NTL.PR.F Scraps (Would be Ratchet, but there are credit concerns) 255,195 CIBC crossed 200,000 at 4.11.
NTL.PR.G Scraps (Would be Ratchet, but there are credit concerns) 134,584 CIBC crossed 69,100 at 3.80.
TD.PR.O PerpetualDiscount 58,605 Nesbitt crossed 50,000 at 20.55. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.00% based on a bid of 20.60 and a limitMaturity.
MFC.PR.C PerpetualDiscount 42,017 CIBC bought two blocks of 10,000 from Nesbitt, both at 18.75. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.14% based on a bid of 18.51 and a limitMaturity.
PWF.PR.H PerpetualDiscount 32,800 CIBC crossed 30,000 at 23.90. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.12% based on a bid of 23.90 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.R FixedReset 21,225  
RY.PR.I FixedReset 20,798  

There were eleven other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

DPS.UN: Retraction Season!

September 30th, 2008

Assiduous Readers will remember that I laid at least part of the blame for preferred shares’ appalling performance in October 2007 on forced-sales to meet retractions by DPS.UN:

Diversified Preferred Share Trust (fully described at www.sentryselect.com) is a closed-end preferred share fund trading on the Toronto Stock Exchange. In October, many of its shareholders decided that they’d had enough bad news for one year, thank you very much, and exercised their retraction rights over one-sixth of the portfolio holdings. And therefore, preferred shares worth $40-million hit the market on a “must-sell” basis.

Well … it’s October again! (very nearly)

On September 24, DPS.UN had a NAVPS of 19.64 and has gone ex-Dividend for $0.30.

We can estimate a total return for the intervening period of -1.24%, using figures for CPD ($16.63 on Sep 24, $16.21 on Sep 30, ex-Dividend of $0.2135).

With this in hand, we may estimate a NAVPS of $19.10 for DPS.UN as of the close Sep. 30. The market was 18.67-75, 10×8, last 18.67. At the bid, therefore, we can estimate a discount of 2.2%.

This is in the same region as the discount at this time last year … the discount later changed to around 4.5% at around October 10/11 and there were mass redemptions which – regardless of the actual effect on the market – created selling pressure in issues held by DPS.UN.

So … what’s going to happen this time? I don’t have any fearless predictions … does anybody?

Risk Transfer, Zombie Firms and the Credit Crunch

September 30th, 2008

Edward Kane of Boston College managed a rare accomplishment last April; he wrote an essay on the economics of regulation and moral hazard that is both entertaining and informative.

The paper is Extracting Nontransparent Safety-Net Subsidies by Strategically Expanding and Contracting a Financial Institution’s Accounting Balance Sheet.

He argues that the complexity of (what the Bank of England calls) Large Complex Financial Institutions is not a natural consequence of size and success, but is achieved in a deliberate (if, perhaps unconcious) effort to maximize implicit government subsidies:

… value maximization leads them to trade off diseconomies from becoming inefficiently large or complex against the safety-net benefits that increments in scale or scope can offer them. Arguably, Citigroup has been the poster child for this kind of behavior.

Along with investments in political clout, an institution can obtain and hold TDFU [Too Difficult to Fail and Unwind] and TBDA [Too Big to Discipline Adequately] status by: (1) moving highly leveraged loss exposures formally off their accounting balance-sheet, and (2) maintaining an aggressive program of mergers and acquisitions. Over time, either strategy makes a large institution ever more gigantic, ever more complex, and ever more politically influential. The profitability of undertaking these dialectical responses to FDICIA [FDIC Improvement Act] tells us that the current wave of financial-institution consolidation and convergence is not just an efficiency-enhancing Schumpeterian long-cycle response either to past overbanking or to secularly improving technologies of communication, contracting, and record-keeping. Mergers that involve a TDFU or TBTDA organization have been shown to increase the capitalized value of the implicit government credit enhancements imbedded in their capital structure (Kane, 2000; Penas and Unal, 2004; Brewer and Jagtiani, 2007).

This thesis is then particularized:

It is a mistake to characterize the current turmoil as a liquidity crisis caused by fire-sale pricing and to try to cure the turmoil by auctioning off central-bank loans. In practice, multiple-tranche securitization (and resecuritization) of highly leveraged loans has revealed itself to be less about risk transfer than about risk shifting: i.e., undercompensating counterparties for the risks they assume. TBFU originators of leveraged loans and TBFU sponsors of securitization conduits transformed traditional default and interest-rate risks into hard-to-understand counterparty and funding risks that in distressed times pass back for reputational reasons from securitization vehicles. The critical point is that off-balance-sheet vehicles that booked complex swaps and structured securitizations created reputation-driven loss exposures for sponsors that managers and accountants knew lacked transparency for supervisors and creditors. The victims were investors who accepted inflated estimates of the credit quality of the instruments they purchased and the safety-net managers and taxpayers who now have to clean up the mess.

Besides confusing investors, complex forms of structured finance expand risk-shifting possibilities by making it easy for authorities to neglect the safety-net implications these positions generate and to exempt complex loss exposures from appropriate capital discipline.

I can certainly testify that the dealer community just loves to repackage risk and charge a high price for it. Back in the old days – by which I mean the late 1980’s – it was enormously profitable in Canada simply to strip the coupons from a government bond and and sell them individually – surely one of the simpler mechanisms of creating a synthetic. And I cannot count the number of times I’ve been offered some kind of hideously complex product that has left me puzzled for hours about the methodology of pricing it, let alone actually doing the pricing! These usually came with some kind of underhanded deal in which the purchasing portfolio manager could make a bet outside his mandate – currency speculation, say – while holding something that could plausibly be called a bond.

And, of course, they took their cut!

Dr. Kane concludes:

To minimize the costs of rehabilitating a damaged firm, a private rescuer begins by poring over its books to establish a solid knowledge of unrealized losses and continuing loss exposures. Armed with that knowledge, private rescuers (whose behavior can be typified by capital assistance provided by JP Morgan-Chase and sovereign investment funds during the current turmoil) force rescued stockholders to accept a deal that gives the rescuer a claim to the incremental future profits that the rescue might generate. This tells us that to control moral hazard, government rescuers must insist that the rights of shareholders in TDFU zombie firms undergo severe dilution. To see that taxpayers receive fair compensation for their preservation efforts, government rescuers must be made accountable for establishing for their agency (and ultimately for taxpayers) an appropriately large equity or warrant position on the upside of the rescued firm.

This is a big step up from Bagehot, but Dr. Kane is referring to zombie firms – those that are insolvent. Bagehot applies only to problems of illiquidity.