Archive for November, 2007

DGS.PR.A Should Commence Trading Dec. 3

Wednesday, November 21st, 2007

Brompton Group has announced:

that Dividend Growth Split Corp. has filed a final prospectus in respect of an initial public offering of class A and preferred shares for a maximum offering size of $100 million. The preferred shares have been provisionally rated Pfd-2 by Dominion Bond Rating Service Limited.Dividend Growth Split Corp. has been created to provide investors with an investment in 20 large capitalization Canadian equities that have demonstrated the highest dividend growth rates over a five year period and have a current dividend yield of at least 2% per annum, utilizing a split share structure on a low cost basis.

Class A shareholders will receive the benefits of monthly cash distributions targeted to be 8.0% per annum, low management fees and the opportunity for growth in net asset value. Preferred shareholders will receive attractive quarterly distributions of 5.25% per annum supported by the high credit quality of the underlying assets.

Asset coverage is 2.5:1 at the issue price – probably less after initial fees and expenses, but I haven’t even read as far as that in the prospectus! I do see that the wind-up date is November 30, 2014, with no intervening calls, and:

No distributions will be paid on the Class A Shares if (i) the distributions payable on the Preferred Shares are in arrears, or (ii) in respect of a cash distribution, after payment of the distribution by the Company, the NAV per Unit would be less than $15.00. In addition, it is intended that the Company will not pay distributions in excess of the targeted $0.10 per month, on the Class A Shares if, after payment of the distribution, the NAV per Unit would be less than $25.00 unless the Company has to make such distributions to fully recover refundable taxes.

No decision has been made as to whether to include these in the HIMIPref™ universe; I’m going to wait until I see how much they’re able to sell.

Banks & Subordinated Debt

Wednesday, November 21st, 2007

I ran across an interesting story today on the Cleveland Fed website: Credit Spreads and Subordinated Debt by by Joseph G. Haubrich and James B. Thomson.

Subordinated debt may be counted as part of Tier 2 capital by the banks, where it is senior to preferred shares (and everything else that’s in Tier 1) but junior to deposits.

One proposed means of injecting more market discipline into the banking sector is a subordinated debt requirement. It would compel banks to issue some debt that the government does not guarantee and that is paid off only after all depositors have been satisfied. A mandatory subordinated debt requirement was one of the reforms recommended in a 1986 study commissioned by the American Bankers Association. In addition, the Financial Modernization Act of 1999 requires that large banking companies have outstanding, at all times, at least one (though not necessarily a subordinated) debt issue rated by a commercial credit-rating agency.

Some experts argue that subordinated debt is unnecessary because equity capital already gives depositors and other bank creditors a layer of protection. But banks’ equity—that is, their stock—rises when their profits increase, so the prospect of higher equity can encourage them to take greater risks. Debt is more sensitive than equity to the loss aspect of risk because it lacks the upside inducement of higher profits. Subordinated debt thus gives a bank’s depositors and general creditors the same protection from losses as equity does, without creating the incentive to assume more risk.

Evidence on credit spreads and credit spread curves suggests that these sources of information could one day become useful to bank regulatory agencies. At this time, however, the evidence is too weak to justify imposing a mandatory subordinated debt requirement, especially if its purpose is to increase market discipline on banking companies and give bank supervisors better information about banks’ changing conditions. Before supervisors add credit spreads from subordinated debt to their dashboard of early warning signals of deteriorating bank conditions, much more work must be done on extracting useful, reliable risk indicators. So, despite some encouraging results, we need considerably more evidence on the value of credit spread information to regulators and markets before deciding to impose any new rule on how banks fund themselves.

By way of example, Royal Bank’s 2006 Annual Report shows $21.5-billion in Tier 1 Capital and $8.6-billion in Tier 2 Capital; the latter figure includes $7.1-billion in sub-debt.

Update, 2007-11-22: OFHEO is attempting to use sub-debt as a control feature on the GSEs, but it isn’t working out very well:

Those tests show that the market behavior of sub debt yields has changed as negative information has emerged about the Enterprises’ management and risks. However, the nature of the change has been to link sub debt yields more closely to Treasuries. That paradoxical development is consistent with investors having greater confidence that Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac or their federal regulator would reduce the Enterprises’ default risks, with greater liquidity in the Enterprise sub debt market in recent years, or with greater confidence in the value of the implicit federal guarantee associated with Enterprise debt.

November 20, 2007

Tuesday, November 20th, 2007

I do apologize … many things came up today, so you’ll just have to do your own literature review.

PerpetualDiscounts didn’t go down today!

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 4.81% 4.81% 141,286 15.78 2 -0.1224% 1,045.2
Fixed-Floater 4.87% 4.85% 84,046 15.75 8 +0.0158% 1,044.5
Floater 4.61% 4.65% 60,679 16.04 3 +0.5426% 1,019.7
Op. Retract 4.86% 2.66% 77,191 3.46 16 -0.0549% 1,033.3
Split-Share 5.35% 5.84% 89,330 4.12 15 -0.3884% 1,012.9
Interest Bearing 6.29% 6.56% 63,891 3.51 4 -0.3029% 1,051.7
Perpetual-Premium 5.86% 5.56% 82,527 7.09 11 -0.1332% 1,006.0
Perpetual-Discount 5.60% 5.64% 335,175 14.43 55 +0.1104% 904.1
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
PIC.PR.A SplitShare -5.4125% Whoosh! It traded 10,558 shares in a range of 15.00-26, and then the bids disappeared, with Nesbitt taking out the last bids at about 3:30. Asset coverage of 1.6+:1 as of November 15, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.64% based on a bid of 14.33 and a hardMaturity 2010-11-1 at 15.00.
BAM.PR.M PerpetualDiscount -2.9491% Amazingly, it now has the same quote as the virtually identical BAM.PR.M. I know one assiduous reader who will be quite pleased with this symmetry! Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.69% based on a bid of 18.10 and a limitMaturity.
FTU.PR.A SplitShare -1.9355% Asset coverage of just over 1.8:1 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.50% based on a bid of 9.12 and a hardMaturity 2012-12-1 at 10.00.
ELF.PR.G PerpetualDiscount -1.3889% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.79% based on a bid of 17.75 and a limitMaturity.
NA.PR.K PerpetualDiscount -1.2605% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.27% based on a bid of 23.50 and a limitMaturity.
FFN.PR.A SplitShare -1.0967% Asset coverage of 2.3:1 as of November 15, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.47% based on a bid of 9.92 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00.
BAM.PR.N PerpetualDiscount +1.0045% Yes! That is indeed a “+” sign in front of a BAM.PR.N return! Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.69% based on a bid of 18.10 and a limitMaturity. See BAM.PR.M, above.
POW.PR.B PerpetualDiscount +1.0292% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.74% based on a bid of 23.56 and a limitMaturity.
POW.PR.D PerpetualDiscount +1.0550% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.75% based on a bid of 22.03 and a limitMaturity.
BNA.PR.A SplitShare +1.3598% Ex-Dividend today. Asset coverage of just under 4.0:1 as of October 31 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.18% based on a bid of 25.00 and a hardMaturity 2010-9-30 at 25.00. Compare with BNA.PR.B at 6.20% (23.00 bid, 2016-3-25 maturity) and BNA.PR.C 7.89% (18.55 bid, 2019-1-10 maturity).
CM.PR.H PerpetualDiscount +1.3636% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.43% based on a bid of 22.30 and a limitMaturity.
ELF.PR.F PerpetualDiscount +1.5625% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.90% based on a bid of 19.50 and a limitMaturity.
BAM.PR.B Floater +1.6522%  
HSB.PR.D PerpetualDiscount +1.7352% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.70% based on a bid of 22.28 and a limitMaturity.
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
GWO.PR.I PerpetualDiscount 284,750 Scotia bought 34,000 from Nesbitt at 20.20. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.69% based on a bid of 20.10 and a limitMaturity.
IQW.PR.C Scraps (would be OpRet but there are rather pressing and urgent credit concerns) 144,000 The company had to scrap a financing today, perhaps because investors kept throwing up. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 138.67% (annualized) based on a bid of 19.00 and a softMaturity 2008-2-29. Note that the soft maturity will entail some risk to the exerciser, since the common will be received and have to be exchanged. On the other hand, if you want Quebecor common – or hold some already – and you’re happy with that, it could be quite attractive. Unfortunately, it cannot be easily arbitraged, since if you short the common now, it might quintuple (hah!) between now and the time the conversion price gets set. But something must work … hmm … buy the prefs at $19, you’ll get $26 worth of common at the February price … OK! Buy the prefs at $19, short the common, buy a call on the common at 36% over current price … I think that works, and I suspect it has a good chance of profit. But check my work first!
SLF.PR.D PerpetualDiscount 87,243 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.53% based on a bid of 20.11 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.D PerpetualDiscount 81,745 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.51% based on a bid of 20.56 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.P PerpetualDiscount 80,475 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.48% based on a bid of 24.15 and a limitMaturity.
MFC.PR.C PerpetualDiscount 78,600 Nesbitt crossed 51,000 at 21.00. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.36% based on a bid of 21.00 and a limitMaturity.

There were thirty-three other index-included $25.00-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

BCE.PR.Y / BCE.PR.Z Conversion Results Announced

Tuesday, November 20th, 2007

BCE has announced:

that 6,991,775 of its 8,852,620 Cumulative Redeemable First Preferred Shares, Series Z (“Series Z Preferred Shares”) have been tendered for conversion, on a one-for-one basis, into Cumulative Redeemable First Preferred Shares, Series Y (“Series Y Preferred Shares”). In addition, 12,825 of its 1,147,380 Series Y Preferred Shares have been tendered for conversion, on a one-for-one basis, into Series Z Preferred Shares. Consequently, on December 1, 2007, BCE will have 8,126,330 Series Y Preferred shares and 1,873,670 Series Z Preferred shares issued and outstanding.

The Series Y Preferred Shares will pay a monthly floating adjustable cash dividend for the five-year period beginning on December 1, 2007, as and when declared by the Board of Directors of BCE. The Series Z Preferred Shares will
pay on a quarterly basis, for the five-year period beginning on December 1, 2007, as and when declared by the Board of Directors of BCE, a fixed dividend based on an annual dividend rate of 4.331%.

Under and subject to the terms and conditions of the Definitive Agreement entered into by BCE Inc. in connection with its acquisition by an investor group led by Teachers’ Private Capital, the private investment arm of the Ontario Teachers’ Pension Plan, Providence Equity Partners Inc. and Madison Dearborn Partners, LLC, the purchaser has agreed to purchase all outstanding Series Y Preferred Shares for a price of $25.50 per share, together with accrued but unpaid dividends to the Effective Date (as such term is defined in the Definitive Agreement). The purchaser has also agreed, on and subject to the terms and conditions of the Definitive Agreement, to purchase all outstanding Series Z Preferred Shares for a price of $25.25 per share, together with accrued but unpaid dividends to the Effective Date.

 

 

PFD.PR.A (Index Fund) to Redeem 38% of Holdings

Tuesday, November 20th, 2007

A press release states:

JovFunds Management Inc., the manager of Charterhouse Preferred Share Index Corporation (the “Company”) (PFD.PR.A: TSX), announced today that the Company has received requests for redemption in respect of a total of 844,498 PSI Preferred Shares (“Shares”), representing approximately 38% of the outstanding Shares. Redeeming shareholders will be entitled to receive an amount equal to the net realized proceeds from that portion of the Index Portfolio that is sold to fund the redemption, together with any other net assets of the Company as at November 30, 2007. The redemption payment will be made on or before the tenth business day of the December, 2007.

I reviewed Charterhouse as part of my review of closed end funds.

Now … let’s work it out. 844,000 preferred shares outstanding … 38% are being redeemed … let’s say the NAV approximates the market price, say $20 …. that’s selling pressure of about maybe six to six-and-a-half million. Good thing it’s not a big fund!

Update: Oops! 844,000 preferred shares REPRESENTS 38% of the outstanding. So at $20, total selling pressure comes to about $16.9-million. This is much more serious!

TFS.PR.A to be Redeemed 2008-3-31

Tuesday, November 20th, 2007

The board of Thirty-Five Split Inc. has announced:

The Capital Shares and Preferred Shares will be redeemed by the Company on March 31, 2008 (the “Redemption Date”) in accordance with the redemption provisions of the shares. Pursuant to these provisions, the Preferred Shares will be redeemed at a price per share equal to the lesser of $25.00 and the Net Asset Value per Unit.

TFS.PR.A is tracked by HIMIPref™, but is not included in the SplitShare index due to volume concerns.

IQW.PR.C Probably Won't be Redeemed for Cash; Credit Review Negative

Tuesday, November 20th, 2007

Quebecor has announced:

that it was withdrawing its refinancing plan involving an offer of approximately Cdn$250 million of its equity shares, an offer on a private placement basis of an aggregate of $500 million of new debt securities and amendments to the Company’s secured credit facilities.  The Company has decided to withdraw the refinancing plan due to adverse current financial market conditions.

The previously noted potential redemption of IQW.PR.C, which was conditional on successful financing, will presumably not take place.

DBRS has announced it has:

placed the Long-Term and Preferred Share ratings of Quebecor World Inc. (Quebecor World or the Company) Under Review with Negative Implications.

This action follows an announcement by the Company that it has withdrawn the aggregate $750 million refinancing plan that was announced on November 13, 2007. The Company’s inability to implement its refinancing plan raises additional concerns with Quebecor World’s liquidity position and near-term financial flexibility. DBRS believes Quebecor World’s liquidity issues remain significant and could increase in severity should the Company fail to refinance all or portions of its existing credit facilities in the first half of 2008.

At Pfd-5, there’s not much further IQW.PR.C / IQW.PR.D can go! They were last downgraded October 5.

Update, 2007-11-23: Moody’s has put Quebecor World:

on review for possible downgrade and downgraded the company’s speculative grade liquidity rating to SGL-4 (indicating poor liquidity).

With the refinancing transaction having been cancelled, the company’s financing arrangements require prompt attention in order to assure ongoing orderly operations, and Moody’s considers near term default risk and, therefore, QWI’s long term debt ratings, to be inextricably linked to the company’s ability to normalize its financing arrangements (refer to Moody’s credit opinion for further commentary). Moody’s intends to review the company’s financing/liquidity plans in short order, with any resulting rating action being based on likely effectiveness and prospects for timely execution. With QWI appearing to be on the verge of generating modest positive cash flow as the cash drain related to its extensive retooling exercise nears completion, presuming that the company’s financing/liquidity plans are viable, Moody’s would affirm the existing B3 corporate family rating (CFR) and Caa1 instrument ratings. Should this not be the case, downwards ratings actions are likely.

November 19, 2007

Monday, November 19th, 2007

Gary Stern, President of the Minneapolis Fed, gave a speech in Singapore titled “Credit Market Developments: Lessons for Central Banking, which has provoked sharp disagreement from Yves Smith of Naked Capitalism

The theme of Mr. Stern’s speech is that there are no easy answers:

certainly some situations are far from resolved, and thus identification of principal lessons learned from the disruption will necessarily be incomplete and probably prioritized inadequately as well. Nevertheless, I think we can say something meaningful about potential reforms and about the tradeoffs inherent in their adoption. These are important matters; if I am right about tradeoffs, then some reforms might impose significant costs and contribute to outcomes we would prefer to avoid.

Policymakers will certainly find opportunities to improve current regulations and practices; the status quo will need to change in some areas. But, as we will see, and as foreshadowed previously, tradeoffs suggest that policymakers will want to be extraordinarily careful in addressing perceived inadequacies in the current environment.

This seems reasonable enough, but Mr. Smith says:

How do you want to count the damage that we need to count on one side of this tradeoff? Let’s see, we have subprimes at anywhere from $150 to $500 billion. We have the train wreck that is just starting in commercial real estate, which may be a mere $100 to $150 billion. Then we have losses and writeoffs on collateralized debt obligations, which we have said could add up to $750 billion (although some of that is already included in subprime losses). Of we could simply rely on the forecast by Goldman chief economist Jan Hatzius that home foreclosures could reach $400 billion and will trigger a $2 trillion reduction in lending, which in turn will trigger a “substantial recession.”

Even though regulation entails costs in terms of reduced efficiency and reduced profitability, the scale of the damage argues for incurring those costs. Yet, incredibly, Stern is arguing against meaningful change despite overwhelming evidence of serious problems.

… which doesn’t strike me as being a particularly useful response. There are certainly Bad Things happening, but this doesn’t mean that the system is not working as it should. As has so often been reiterated, markets exist in order that risks might be transferred. The fact that sometimes those risks have large effects – perhaps unforseen effects – is not sufficient to justify a full-court press on the regulatory front. Most importantly, before implementing regulatory changes, it is necessary to have a pretty good idea that rule changes will, in fact, be a net benefit … which is all that Mr. Stern is saying.

Mr. Stern’s first example is the “Originate and Distribute” model that results in so much asset securitization:

Because of the many hand-offs in the process—and the terms of the contracts between at least some of the firms—a number of the firms involved in the process did not have a clear stake in the longer-run performance of the mortgage. The incentives in this model, then, may have encouraged large-scale production of low-quality mortgages.

And the alternative—the originate to distribute model—has a core and fundamental economic advantage propelling it: specialization. Over time, firms have developed that specialize in the distinct steps of the lending process, from originating the loan to funding it. Such specialization contributes importantly to cost efficiencies, innovation, and a broadening of access to financial capital.  Another advantage of the model is diversification; the originate to distribute process allows a firm to significantly diversity the asset side of its balance sheet.

… to which Mr. Smith replies …

Ahem, don’t the 15% to 20% fall in housing prices, a falling dollar, and the recession that Hatzius and his colleagues increasingly predict represent an “adverse consequence for living standards’?

And Stern seeks to scare his audience into submission with a false dichotomy: you either accept the originate to distribute model as is, or you go back to having banks hold loans on their balance sheets. There is no willingness to consider methods to improve incentives or information flow, or more clearly define liability, that may reduce the bad outcomes of this system while keeping many of its virtues.

Mr. Smith’s suggestion for incremental improvement of the system is:

All residential mortgage brokers will be subject to Federal reporting and oversight (presumably at least along the lines of the requirements for brokers employed by regulated banks, although those may need to be toughened too).

… which is more than just a little vague. Federal reporting of what? oversight of what? you qualify for a license how? what do you need to do to lose it? Mr. Smith does not provide any argument for mortgage broker registration, merely the assertion that Rules Will Make Life Better.

According to a study released in 2005:

Among the findings for 2004 are these: there are 53,000 operating brokerages and they accounted for 68% of last year’s total origination activity; the mean firm originated $34.5 million with a mean of 7.9 employees; employment at the nation’s brokerages totaled 418,700; subprime and Alt-A loans accounted for 42.7% of brokerage’s total production volume; the average LO originated 26 loans in 2004; the average brokerage used a mean of 13 wholesale lenders; and average gross income per loan was 170 bp.

It’s a pretty big industry! What’s more, there is a host of existing laws and regulatory authorities at the State level already extant. What benefits are intended by federal regulation? What problems would these seek to correct?

Remember: it is not enough to say ‘there is a problem’. A solid argument that the proposed fix would be of net benefit is also necessary. It should also be remembered that the archetypal sub-prime borrower is not a Dickensian poor but honest family of four. The archetypal sub-prime borrower is a speculator, who put up the minimum downpayment while thinking of it as an “option to buy” more than anything else. I alluded to this on October 10 and a looking at data that is in this speech:

A first finding is that recent foreclosures have been disproportionately related to multifamily dwellings. In Middlesex County, Massachusetts, multi-family properties accounted for approximately 10 percent of all homes, but 27 percent of foreclosures in 2007. This highlights a potentially serious problem for tenants, who may not have known that the owner might be in a precarious financial position.

Yes, I know it’s not the most conclusive evidence that may be generalized! If anybody has any good data on the speculator/poor-but-honest-homeowner split amongst defaulting sub-prime, let me know!

Mr. Stern next addresses the Credit Ratings Agency issue in a manner that warms the cockles of my heart:

To be specific, it could be exceptionally costly for each investor to build the infrastructure required to conduct serious credit analysis, and these costs need to be weighed against the losses suffered by investors in the current regime. Moreover, were the agencies unique in underestimating the losses in, say, the subprime mortgage market?  It is not obvious that a different infrastructure will produce better results.
         
More positively, the rating agencies represent one way of economizing on the production of information on credit instruments. And by charging issuers, they also try to address the public nature of this information for, once the information is produced, there is almost no cost to distributing it and hence it is otherwise difficult to get paid. Absent these charges, there could be too little credit information produced.  Overall then, reforms that might compromise the viability of the agencies or discourage use of ratings present the tradeoff of potentially raising costs and ultimately requiring another solution to the issues the agencies help to address.

Now, I would like to hear more information about the proposal to lift the exemption from Regulation FD that now applies. But Mr. Stern admirably summarizes the major issue.

The next section is “Excess Liquidity”; I won’t re-hash the arguments about whether central banks should target asset prices here. In the conclusion to this section, Mr. Stern states:

Interestingly, the excesses in asset prices perceived in recent years seem related, at least casually, to innovation. Consider the run-up in prices of technology stocks in the late 1990’s and this year’s turbulence linked to pricing of structured financial products and subprime mortgages.  It may be costly to try to address these situations ex ante if, in fact, such actions would inhibit the underlying innovation. Common to all of these concerns is the difficulty of appropriately valuing financial assets.  It is quite plausible that, in pursuing preemptive action, the unintended consequences rival or exceed the desired outcomes.

which attracts the ire of Mr. Smith, who appears somewhat confused:

Similarly, his argument about innovation is specious. Innovation is not a virtue like faith or charity. A particular innovation is not valuable by virtue of merely being innovative (if so, virtually every venture capital proposal would be funded and become a barn-burning success); the measure of the value of an innovation is whether on balance it is beneficial. The jury is out on subprimes, but is it already clear that a lot of the so-called innovations, like no-doc loans, teasers, and high LTV loans, particularly in combination, weren’t innovations, but simply bad ideas.

Big Pharma is full of examples of promising drugs that never made it to market. Why? Either they failed to show sufficient efficacy, meaning they didn’t offer a compelling benefit, or they had potentially dangerous side effects. Why should the world of financial services innovation be any different? Their so-called innovations often deliver limited user benefits (but are more attractive for the producer) and in the case of products like subprime loans, came with toxic side effects, like bankruptcy.

It is not apparent how Mr. Smith would test financial innovation prior to putting it on the marketplace.

Mr. Stern’s concluding example is with respect to government support. He suggests:

In fact, by taking steps to reduce the threat that the failure of a large bank, or decline in asset values in one market, will spillover to other institutions or markets, policymakers can actually increase market discipline and simultaneously achieve greater financial stability.

… which suggests to me that if policy makers have sufficiently guarded against contagion to ensure that one failure won’t topple the system, they will be a lot more willing to allow that one failure; knowing this, banks will strive more carefully to ensure that they don’t become that isolated example; and creditors will strive more carefully to ensure they’re not (overly) exposed to that one example. It seems perfectly clear – but not to Mr. Smith:

“Limiting the size of losses” means “intervening earlier.” The lower the downside for taking risk, the greater the incentive to be reckless. How could this possibly increase moral hazard?

No, Mr. Smith, “Limiting the size of losses” does not necessarily mean “intervening earlier”. It may also mean “limiting contagion”. Mr. Stern made that clear.

All in all, a rather bland speech by Mr. Stern, a violent over-reaction by Mr. Smith.

Stephen Cecchetti was briefly mentioned here on August 27, and has now written another piece for VoxEU: Preparing for the Next Financial Crisis. He is apparently conducting a campaign to force as much financial trading as possible to occur on organized (and regulated!) exchanges; a previous essay that I missed was the topic of another Naked Capitalism post.

The core of Prof. Cecchetti’s argument is:

In order to reduce the risk that it faces, the clearinghouse requires parties to contracts to maintain deposits whose size depends on the details of the contracts. And at the end of every day, the clearinghouse posts gains and losses on each contract to the parties that are involved – positions are marked to market.

Since margin accounts act as buffers against potential losses, they serve the same role as capital does in a bank.   And marking to market creates a mechanism for the continuously monitoring the level of each participants capital.

It is important to realise that because they reduce risk in the system as a whole, clearinghouses are good for everyone. They are what economists refer to as “public goods”.

Well … I don’t buy it, although I would like to see further argument. If a particular security is 20 bid, 90 offered right now on the OTC market, I can think of all kinds of reasons why it will probably be 10 bid, par offered on a public exchange. The major effect of such a change will be to add a lot of instruments to the publicly quoted market that will be an awful lot like preferred shares … sure, you can trade small amounts through open outcry, but to get a big piece done you’ve got to call up a dealer who (if you’re lucky) will get busy and set up a cross.

Mainly, what you’re going to get is another big bureaucracy and 100,000 listed intruments with ludicrous spreads and no volume. Better pricing? Maybe sometimes. But Malachite Aggressive Preferred Fund has a section in the offering memorandum about pricing … if I don’t like the posted bid and offer, I can substitute my best guess (within limits!). I have seen lots of instruments quoted with no bid; many quoted with no offer; and lots quoted at spreads that make your eyes go pop. And believe me, prefs trade a lot more often than a lot of corporate bonds.

Mr. Ceccetti goes on to say:

On the information side, it is important that less-sophisticated investors realise the importance of sticking with exchange-traded products.  The treasurer who manages the short-term cash balances for a small-town government should not be willing to purchase commercial paper, or any security, that is not exchange traded. 

It is not and should not be the exclusive purpose of financial regulation to make life safer for the little guy. The treasurer in this example – and we shall assume for the moment that he’s just another wage-slave accountant, making a good faith effort to Do The Right Thing, but without the experience or the available time to be considered a market professional – should not purchase commercial paper at all. As I’ve pointed out before … there are plenty of institutional money market funds out there, available for 10bp per annum – if that – that provide all the good things regular mutual funds do for Joe Lunchbucket: instant diversification and professional management.

Mr. Cecchetti does not make clear just what problems exist in the current system that will be fixed – with net benefit – by a move to exchange trading. More information is urgently required!

There is good news today! Michael Mendelson (ex-president of Portus Asset Management) has been convicted of fraud. Hurrah!

What a strange day in the preferred share markets today! As far as I can tell, there is a “flight to brand-names” going on – sell everything that doesn’t have an ad on television!

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 4.84% 4.77% 145,945 15.79 2 +0.1023% 1,046.5
Fixed-Floater 4.87% 4.85% 83,516 15.76 8 -0.0506% 1,044.4
Floater 4.63% 4.67% 60,369 15.99 3 -0.9632% 1,014.2
Op. Retract 4.86% 2.52% 77,119 3.25 16 +0.1538% 1,033.9
Split-Share 5.32% 5.73% 89,076 4.10 15 -0.4516% 1,016.9
Interest Bearing 6.28% 6.32% 64,052 3.50 4 +0.3268% 1,054.9
Perpetual-Premium 5.85% 5.46% 81,522 7.11 11 -0.0939% 1,007.3
Perpetual-Discount 5.61% 5.65% 331,508 14.43 55 -0.0989% 903.1
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
ELF.PR.F PerpetualDiscount -4.8563% I don’t see any news. Do you see any news? It’s still rated P-2(high) by S&P. Still rated Pfd-2(low) by DBRS. The common’s about 15% off its highs, but so is everything else. So what gives? Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.01% based on a bid of 19.20 and a limitMaturity.
WFS.PR.A SplitShare -3.1000% Asset coverage of just over 2.0:1 as of November 8, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.51% based on a bid of 9.69 and a hardMaturity 2011-6-30 at 10.00. Hmm… it must be the word “financial” in its name!
BAM.PR.B Floater -2.7484% I’m beginning to detect a pattern! This one has the word “Asset” in its name!
FTU.PR.A SplitShare -2.6178% Asset coverage of just under 2.0:1 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.03% based on a bid of 9.30 and a hardMaturity 2012-12-1 at 10.00. Hah! You see? US Financial 15 Split! I think we’re on to something here!
SLF.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -2.1535% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.60% based on a bid of 21.20 and a limitMaturity.
BNA.PR.C SplitShare -2.0997% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.00% based on a bid of 18.65 and a hardMaturity 2019-1-10. We may compare this with 6.71% for BNA.PR.A (maturing 2010-9-30) and 6.23% for BNA.PR.B (maturing 2016-3-25). But does it make any difference?
BAM.PR.N PerpetualDiscount -1.5925% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.76% based on a bid of 17.92 and a limitMaturity.
SLF.PR.B PerpetualDiscount -1.5801% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.58% based on a bid of 21.50 and a limitMaturity.
FIG.PR.A InterestBearing -1.4056% Asset coverage of 2.1+:1 as of November 16, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.77% (mostly as interest) based on a bid of 9.82 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-31 at 10.00.
ELF.PR.G PerpetualDiscount -1.1532% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.70% based on a bid of 18.00 and a limitMaturity. See ELF.PR.F, above, for expressions of disbelief.
HSB.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -1.1183% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.62% based on a bid of 22.99 and a limitMaturity.
NA.PR.K PerpetualDiscount -1.0806% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.18% based on a bid of 23.80 and a limitMaturity.
PIC.PR.A SplitShare +1.0000% Asset coverage of just under 1.7:1 as of November 8 according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.52% based on a bid of 15.15 and a hardMaturity 2010-11-1 at 15.00.
BNA.PR.B SplitShare +1.0865% Asset coverage of 3.8+:1 as of July 31, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.23% based on a bid of 23.26 and a hardMaturity 2016-3-25 at 25.00. You weren’t expecting to see this issue in THIS section of the price moves, were you? But it’s only coming back a bit from the bid disappearance yesterday … those poor, naive, non-PrefBlog-reading souls who look only at close/close will be somewhat shocked, since it’s down $1.31 today, trading 240 shares in three lots in a nine-cent range.
PWF.PR.D OpRet +1.6551% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of -10.62% based on a bid of 26.41 and a call 2007-12-19 at 26.00. Presumably, those investors who check anything at all are checking the softMaturity 2012-10-30 at 25.00, which yields 4.01%, but who knows?
BSD.PR.A InterestBearing +2.7624% Asset coverage of just under 1.7:1 as of November 16 according to Brookfield Funds. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.50% (mostly as interest) based on a bid of 9.30 and a hardMaturity 2015-3-31 at 10.00.
POW.PR.D PerpetualDiscount +2.7817% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.81% based on a bid of 21.80 and a limitMaturity.
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
GWO.PR.I PerpetualDiscount 357,831 Nesbitt crossed 330,000 for Delayed Delivery. Not, presumably, a dividend capture/avoidance trade predicated on the exDate 2007-11-29, since it was done inside the day’s range at 20.11. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.72% based on a bid of 20.00 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.P PerpetualDiscount 331,313 Recent inventory blow-out. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.50% based on a bid of 24.05 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.M PerpetualDiscount 116,240 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.45% based on a bid of 20.85 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.I PerpetualDiscount 94,550 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.48% based on a bid of 21.60 and a limitMaturity.
SLF.PR.E PerpetualDiscount 93,100 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.48% based on a bid of 20.50 and a limitMaturity.

There were thirty other index-included $25.00-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices : August 2003

Monday, November 19th, 2007

All indices were assigned a value of 1000.0 as of December 31, 1993.

HIMI Index Values 2003-8-29
Index Closing Value (Total Return) Issues Mean Credit Quality Median YTW Median DTW Median Daily Trading Mean Current Yield
Ratchet 1,393.1 1 2.00 -0.12% 0.08 121M 3.25%
FixedFloater 2,080.2 8 2.00 3.36% 17.5 57M 5.31%
Floater 1,773.3 7 2.00 3.60% 17.9 59M 3.90%
OpRet 1,666.4 27 1.45 3.96% 4.2 133M 5.00%
SplitShare 1,639.5 9 1.78 3.87% 2.0 37M 5.39%
Interest-Bearing 2,026.3 9 2.00 4.88% 1.1 153M 7.57%
Perpetual-Premium 1,292.8 28 1.64 5.27% 6.5 175M 5.58%
Perpetual-Discount 1,484.2 3 2.00 5.57% 14.3 118M 5.51%

Index Constitution, 2003-08-29, Pre-rebalancing

Index Constitution, 2003-08-29, Post-rebalancing

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices : July 2003

Monday, November 19th, 2007

All indices were assigned a value of 1000.0 as of December 31, 1993.

HIMI Index Values 2003-7-31
Index Closing Value (Total Return) Issues Mean Credit Quality Median YTW Median DTW Median Daily Trading Mean Current Yield
Ratchet 1,390.4 1 2.00 -0.09% 0.08 141M 3.31%
FixedFloater 2,080.0 8 2.00 3.38% 17.7 86M 5.31%
Floater 1,741.8 7 2.00 3.66% 17.7 76M 3.97%
OpRet 1,660.8 29 1.41 4.10% 3.9 142M 5.11%
SplitShare 1,623.4 8 1.75 3.89% 3.5 44M 5.43%
Interest-Bearing 2,010.5 9 2.00 4.88% 1.2 155M 7.72%
Perpetual-Premium 1,284.0 27 1.62 5.30% 6.6 203M 5.59%
Perpetual-Discount 1,472.6 3 2.00 5.67% 14.4 119M 5.55%

Index Constitution, 2003-07-31, Pre-rebalancing

Index Constitution, 2003-07-31, Post-rebalancing