Archive for December, 2008

December 23, 2008

Wednesday, December 24th, 2008

CIT Group is getting a $2.33-billion TARP infusion. A lot of people who bought protection at 2500+bp are not going to be very happy.

Holy smokes! On continued heavy volume – that I remain convinced is tax-loss selling, perhaps with a bit of year-end window-dressing thrown in, PerpetualDiscounts were up today! That breaks a seven day losing streak. Not only that, but the behaviour of BNA.PR.C … well, it’s in the tables twice. Be sure to be sitting down when examining!

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30.
The Fixed-Reset index was added effective 2008-9-5 at that day’s closing value of 1,119.4 for the Fixed-Floater index.
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet N/A N/A N/A N/A 0 N/A N/A
Fixed-Floater 8.51% 8.65% 143,353 11.99 7 +1.0254% 621.4
Floater 9.53% 9.62% 97,072 9.90 2 -1.2773% 341.0
Op. Retract 5.57% 6.15% 171,350 3.92 14 +0.4712% 979.1
Split-Share 6.65% 12.23% 97,751 3.93 15 +0.2852% 928.4
Interest Bearing 10.11% 20.95% 59,643 2.62 3 -0.0146% 734.7
Perpetual-Premium N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A
Perpetual-Discount 8.25% 8.38% 251,885 11.06 71 +0.3453% 675.5
Fixed-Reset 6.09% 5.21% 1,122,538 14.61 18 -0.4274% 993.6
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
CM.PR.K Ratchet -5.9524%  
NA.PR.M PerpetualDiscount -4.8808% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.14% based on a bid of 16.76 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 16.76-18, 6×3. Day’s range of 16.56-18.39.
BSD.PR.A InterestBearing (for now!) -3.9894% Asset coverage of 0.7+:1 as of December 19, according to Brookfield Funds. Now with a (dubious) pre-tax bid-YTW of 28.90% based on a bid of 3.61 and a (dubious) hardMaturity 2015-3-31 at 10.00. Closing quote of 3.61-76, 5×4. Day’s range of 3.62-20.
NA.PR.L PerpetualDiscount -3.6958% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.14% based on a bid of 13.55 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 13.55-00, 2×7. Day’s range of 13.55-00.
CU.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -3.3503% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.73% based on a bid of 19.04 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 19.04-74, 8×3. Day’s range of 19.01-80.
ALB.PR.A SplitShare -3.1314% Asset coverage of 1.1+:1 as of December 18, according to Scotia Managed Companies. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 18.68% based on a bid of 18.87 and a hardMaturity 2011-2-28 at 25.00. Closing quote of 18.87-22, 40×1. Day’s range of 18.57-50.
BCE.PR.S FixFloat -3.0116%  
BCE.PR.Z FixFloat +3.0756%  
LBS.PR.A SplitShare +3.2637% Asset coverage of 1.3-:1 as of December 18 according to Brompton Group. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 11.22% based on a bid of 7.91 and a hardMaturity 2013-11-29 at 10.00. Closing quote of 7.91-29, 70×8. Day’s range of 7.81-50.
BNS.PR.N PerpetualDiscount +3.2914% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.77% based on a bid of 17.26 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote OF 17.26-27, 45×6 . Day’s range of 16.61-17.74.
CM.PR.J PerpetualDiscount +3.3003% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.33% based on a bid of 13.53 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 13.53-57, 1×1. Day’s range of 12.66-13.75.
GWO.PR.G PerpetualDiscount +3.4667% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.45% based on a bid of 15.52 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 15.52-68, 1×1. Day’s range of 14.85-53.
POW.PR.A PerpetualDiscount +3.9591% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.64% based on a bid of 16.28 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 16.28-79, 5×6. Day’s range of 14.87-16.96 (!).
BCE.PR.C FixFloat +4.8606%  
MFC.PR.C PerpetualDiscount +5.1491% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.32% based on a bid of 15.52 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 15.52-84, 2×3. Day’s range of 14.54-15.84.
POW.PR.B PerpetualDiscount +5.3163% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.59% based on a bid of 15.65 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 15.65-84, 10×1. Day’s range of 14.99-98.
PWF.PR.G PerpetualDiscount +5.8824% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.39% based on a bid of 18.00 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 18.00-19.65 (!) 3×1. Day’s range of 17.00-18.25.
PWF.PR.F PerpetualDiscount +7.1672% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.56% based on a bid of 15.70 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 15.70-90, 12×5. Day’s range of 14.60-16.00.
BCE.PR.Y Ratchet +8.0196%  
BNA.PR.C SplitShare +11.6247% Asset coverage of 1.7+:1 based on BAM.A at 18.05 and 2.4 BAM.A per preferred. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 21.09% based on a bid of 7.97 and a hardMaturity 2019-1-10 at 25.00. Closing quote of 7.97-22, 9×9. Day’s range of 7.12-97.
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
BNA.PR.C SplitShare 176,607 Scotia crossed 150,000 at 7.75. See above.
BAM.PR.H OpRet 126,054 TD crossed 100,000 at 19.50. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 14.04% based on a bid of 19.75 and a softMaturity 2012-3-30 at 25.00.
BMO.PR.J PerpetualDiscount 121,417 Anonymous bought 11,600 from Odlum Brown at 13.75. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.47% based on a bid of 13.51 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.K PerpetualDiscount 115,930 Scotia crossed 64,900 at 16.05. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.81% based on a bid of 15.70 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.I FixedReset 115,647 Scotia crossed 42,200 at 21.10.

There were ninety-six other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

NBF.PR.A Downgraded to Pfd-4(low) by DBRS

Tuesday, December 23rd, 2008

DBRS has announced that it:

has today downgraded the Preferred Shares issued by NB Split Corp. (the Company) to Pfd-4 (low) from Pfd-2 (low), with a Stable trend. The rating has been removed from Under Review with Negative Implications, where it was placed on October 24, 2008.

In February and March of 2007, the Company raised gross proceeds of approximately $106 million by issuing 1.521 million Preferred Shares (at $32.72 each) and 3.043 million Capital Shares (at $18.45 each). The initial split share structure provided downside protection of 50% to the Preferred Shares (after expenses).

The net proceeds from the initial offering were invested in a portfolio of common shares (the NB Shares) of National Bank of Canada (National Bank). Dividends received from the NB Shares are used to pay a fixed, cumulative quarterly dividend to the holders of the Preferred Shares yielding 4.75% annually. Excess dividends net of all expenses of the Company may be paid as dividends on the Capital Shares. The current dividend income on the NB Shares less administration fees and other Company expenses is sufficient to fully cover the cost of the Preferred Shares distributions.

The value of the NB Shares has declined significantly since inception. From February 22, 2007, to December 22, 2008, the net asset value (NAV) of the Company dropped from $67.20 to $31.06, a decline of about 54%. As a result, all of the downside protection available to the Preferred Shares at inception has been eroded. Based on the most recent NAV, holders of the Preferred Shares would experience a loss of approximately 5% of their initial issuance price if the NB Shares were liquidated and proceeds distributed. However, the credit quality of National Bank remains strong as DBRS confirmed its senior debt rating at AA (low) with a Stable trend on November 26, 2008.

As a result of the large decline in asset coverage, DBRS has downgraded the rating of the Preferred Shares to Pfd-4 (low) with a Stable trend. A main constraint to the rating is that volatility of the common share price and changes in dividend policies of National Bank may result in reductions in asset coverage or dividend coverage from time to time.

The redemption date for both classes of shares issued is February 15, 2012.

The NAV for NBF.PR.A is posted on its website, as $31.06 on December 22; the issue price of the preferreds was $32.72. The preferreds closed today at 25.50-27.99 (!) 43×1. Based on the NAV and the ask price of the capital shares of $2.19, the monthly retraction (with formula R=95%NAV – 2C – 0.40) was $24.73 and hence not supportive.

NBF.PR.A was mentioned on PrefBlog in conncection with the DBRS March Review (not resolved) and the DBRS October Review. NBF.PR.A is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

December 22, 2008

Tuesday, December 23rd, 2008

Dealbreaker has a highly entertaining commentary on quants, inspired by a somewhat more serious Reuters piece:

Because some of their mathematical models failed to take into account factors that later turned out to be crucial, quants have been blamed for compounding risk and exacerbating the crash in financial markets.

The profession’s reputation took a beating in August 2007, when some quant funds — which try to beat the market by crunching vast amounts of data at lightning speed — lost a third of their value in a matter of days.

As the mortgage crisis gathered steam last year and financial markets became volatile, quant funds, which make up about 7 percent of the hedge fund universe, were caught flat-footed.

To raise cash, they started selling stocks, which created unusual moves in stock prices, throwing other quant models off. Finally, the selling snowballed into a full market panic.

“Before you know it, you have a chain reaction and the whole market dives on the basis of what amounts to a mathematical prediction,” said Peter Morici an economics professor at the University of Maryland.

“You create a mathematical herd. That’s why so often these schemes based on math models end in tears.”

Nassem Taleb, a former trader who wrote the best seller “Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable,” is even more outspoken. “Quants and quant programs are dangerous to society,” he said.

The failure last year to foresee that subprime borrowers might default on their mortgages is only the latest example of mathematical models that rule out possible sets of circumstances because they were highly unusual.

In 1998, Connecticut hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management collapsed because its mathematical model failed to foresee the Russian debt crisis.

I have found that generalizing about “quants” is not a wise thing to do. There are quants and then there are pseudo-quants; the difference between the two can usually be found only by detailed analysis of the model, preferrably at the code level. I also find the idea of “quant schools” to be somewhat odd. It’s putting the cart before the horse! A more rational way of getting into the area is to do many, many calculations on the back of an envelope, executing your trades according to your model, and making money for your clients. You then realize that if you could do your calculations more rapidly, you could take advantage of shorter-lived anomalies; you also realize that increasing the size of your universe will give you more opportunities to exploit your model. So you end up “crunching vast amounts of data at lightning speed”, but the model is the main thing, not the amount of data or the speed.

I should also point out that the rescuers of LTCM made out like bandits; the relationships were basically valid, it was margin calls caused by transient anomalies that killed them. The danger is not quantitative analysis; the danger is over-leverage. But just try telling a salesman that the idea that “one” is good does not necessarily imply that “two” is better – especially when they can charge a full point to make it “three”!

The August 2007 quant debacle has been previously discussed on PrefBlog. Pseudo-quants got hammered; everybody else made out just fine.

There are fears of a wave of defaults on commercial property:

U.S. commercial properties at risk of default could triple if rental income from office, retail and apartment buildings drops by even 5 percent, a likely possibility given the recession, according to research by New York-based real estate analysts at Reis Inc.

Lenders that used optimistic rent estimates to grant mortgages beginning in 2005 stand to lose as much as $23.1 billion, or 7.02 percent, of total unpaid balances if landlords lose 5 percent of net operating income, according to Reis. Analysts examined data on 22,890 properties that together may account for unpaid loans of about $329 billion in 2009, said Victor Calanog, director of research.

Reis estimates at least 353 properties, or 1.5 percent of the total number analyzed, could fall into default as net operating income, mainly from rent, barely clears loan payments.

Properties at risk include those with net operating income less than 1.1 times their loan payment, Calanog said. That “base case” translates to $9.08 billion of unpaid balances, or 2.76 percent of the total dollar value outstanding on the mortgages.

Brookfield is always – well, recently – a hot topic of discussion on PrefBlog, so here are some numbers from the Brookfield Properties 3Q08 Report:

Nine months to 2008-9-30
  US
Commercial
Property
Canadian
Commercial
Property
Net Operating Income $831-million $215-million
Interest on Debt $445-million $35-million

Income coverage is not the same thing as profitability, of course (there’s depreciation to be covered, among other things), but there is no indication here of impending cash flow difficulties with Brookfield’s consolidated property arm.

Strange and violent action in the CMBS and derivative markets on November 20. I was hoping for some good CMBS colour on Across the Curve, but he’s taking the week off. Huh! I wanted to spend Christmas with my loved ones, too … but the banks are closed.

I’ve argued here interminably that what we want right now by way of fiscal policy is infrastructure spending. Daniel Gros argues on VoxEU that it’s too hard to get shovels in the ground quickly enough and advocates tax cuts and deferrals:

Even in the US, this instrument will only have limited importance, as public infrastructure spending is projected to increase from around 2.6% (in 2007) to 3.6% of GDP (in 2009), thus constituting only a small fraction of the overall deficit, which is now projected to climb to around 8%–9% of GDP.

Households that depend on credit to finance their consumption will be most affected by the credit crunch and are thus most likely to react to a tax cut by maintaining their consumption. For this type of household, a tax cut (or an increase in expenditure) will be an effective tool to prevent an even sharper drop in consumption.

The fact that the marginal propensity to save is likely to be much higher in countries with solvent households (Germany and most of rest of continental Europe) also implies that the multiplier effect of spending on public infrastructure will also be lower than in the Anglo-Saxon countries where households are close to bankruptcy. This is another reason why the German government should be more hesitant than others to engage in a big fiscal stimulus.

A similar reasoning applies to the corporate sector – in a credit crunch investment will be strongly affected by the liquidity situation of enterprises. This implies that in countries where the corporate sector is a heavy borrower (Spain, France and Italy) it would be important to improve the liquidity situation of enterprises. One simple way to do this would be to allow all corporations to postpone payment of corporate income taxes for 1-2 years. This would not result in higher deficits as usually measured, but the cash deficit would increase as governments would effectively extend a credit to the corporate sector. Such a measure would thus be very different from a tax cut because it would not lead to larger debt levels and thus should not lead to sustainability problems later on. Postponing the payment of corporate income tax would of course help only enterprises that make a profit, but this should be considered an advantage because it would mitigate the impact of the credit crunch for sound enterprises, i.e. those that deserve to be saved. Companies that did not pay corporate income tax because they were not able to turn a profit even during the boom would not benefit, but they are also the most likely ones to be insolvent anyway.

I cannot think that the tax deferral option is realistic. If I managed a large profitable corporation and was told my tax was deferred and would be due in 1-2 years, I wouldn’t rush out and spend the money. Nope. I’d buy some high quality short term bonds, book a little free profit and not increase my business risk.

The direct household stimulus argument is a little harder to deal with; my main point was actually brought up by the author:

Even in the US, where the private savings rate has been close to zero, households still chose to save more than half of the tax rebate decided earlier in 2008.

while my other point is also referred to:

Households that depend on credit to finance their consumption will be most affected by the credit crunch and are thus most likely to react to a tax cut by maintaining their consumption. For this type of household, a tax cut (or an increase in expenditure) will be an effective tool to prevent an even sharper drop in consumption.

See? They’ll just blow it on beer and prostitutes.

A recession is nature’s way of telling us we’ve been doing it wrong … one reason why I think we should be very cautious about bailing out the big automakers. Infrastructure spending – as long as it is genuinely useful infrastructure spending – is the way to go.

The Fed has approved CIT Group’s application to become a bank holding company.

Yet another horrible day for the market, with PerpetualDiscounts losing 1.0128% on heavy volume. That’s its seventh straight losing day … but look at the bright side! There are only two more days of tax-loss selling to go … and one of them a short day … and then I’ll have to think up another rationale!

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30.
The Fixed-Reset index was added effective 2008-9-5 at that day’s closing value of 1,119.4 for the Fixed-Floater index.
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet N/A N/A N/A N/A 0 N/A N/A
Fixed-Floater 8.59% 8.74% 140,047 11.90 7 -0.1272% 615.1
Floater 9.41% 9.49% 93,396 10.02 2 +0.8637% 345.4
Op. Retract 5.58% 7.04% 165,970 4.10 14 -0.2140% 974.5
Split-Share 6.67% 12.19% 96,777 3.92 15 +0.1808% 925.7
Interest Bearing 10.10% 21.39% 59,444 2.64 3 -2.0792% 734.8
Perpetual-Premium N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A
Perpetual-Discount 8.26% 8.40% 245,245 11.02 71 -1.0128% 673.1
Fixed-Reset 6.06% 5.19% 1,142,358 14.66 18 -0.4395% 997.9
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
BCE.PR.Y Ratchet -7.7736%  
BCE.PR.C FixFloat -7.0370%  
POW.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -6.7857% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.99% based on a bid of 15.66 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 15.66-84, 9×7. Day’s range of 15.58-16.75.
BSD.PR.A InterestBearing (for now!) -6.2344% Asset coverage of 0.7+:1 as of December 19, according to Brookfield Funds. Now with a (dubious) pre-tax bid-YTW of 27.82% based on a bid of 3.76 and a (dubious) hardMaturity 2015-3-31 at 10.00. Closing quote of 3.76-99, 29×5. Day’s range of 3.75-85.
BNA.PR.C SplitShare -6.0526% Asset coverage of 1.7+:1 based on BAM.A at 18.05 and 2.4 BAM.A per preferred. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 23.07% based on a bid of 7.14 and a hardMaturity 2019-1-10 at 25.00. Closing quote of 7.14-00, 3×46. Day’s range of 7.60-10.
PWF.PR.G PerpetualDiscount -5.6604% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.89% based on a bid of 17.00 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 17.00-50, 1×14. Day’s range of 17.35-75.
RY.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -4.9967% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.93% based on a bid of 14.26 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 14.26-77, 4×3. Day’s range of 14.26-01.
POW.PR.B PerpetualDiscount -4.4987% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.05% based on a bid of 14.86 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 14.86-29, 5×6. Day’s range of 14.85-51.
HSB.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -4.1060% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.88% based on a bid of 14.48 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 14.48-99, 5×6. Day’s range of 14.00-15.20.
BNS.PR.J PerpetualDiscount -3.9542% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.01% based on a bid of 16.76 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 16.76-99, 2×8. Day’s range of 16.41-35.
NA.PR.N FixedReset -3.9409%  
NA.PR.K PerpetualDiscount -3.6551% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.85% based on a bid of 16.87 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 16.87-24, 7×3. Day’s range of 16.87-75.
NA.PR.M PerpetualDiscount -3.5577% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.68% based on a bid of 17.62 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 17.62-95, 2×1. Day’s range of 17.61-47.
RY.PR.I FixedReset -3.4706%  
TD.PR.A FixedReset -3.3708%  
RY.PR.E PerpetualDiscount -3.2542% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.02% based on a bid of 14.27 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 14.27-55, 15×10. Day’s range of 14.20-96.
TD.PR.P PerpetualDiscount -3.0795% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.75% based on a bid of 17.31 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 17.31-50, 2×20. Day’s range of 17.07-85.
BMO.PR.H PerpetualDiscount +3.5958% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.06% based on a bid of 16.71 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 16.71-89, 1×3. Day’s range of 16.05-91.
FTN.PR.A SplitShare +4.2199% Asset coverage of 1.4-:1 as of December 15 according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.03% based on a bid of 8.15 and a hardMaturity 2015-12-1 at 10.00. Closing quote of 8.15-23, 29×5. Day’s range of 7.92-15.
BCE.PR.G FixFloat +4.6512%  
IAG.PR.A PerpetualDiscount +4.7581% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.78% based on a bid of 13.21 and a limitMaturity. Closing quote 13.21-44, 4×11. Day’s range of 13.16-14.43.
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
RY.PR.F PerpetualDiscount 183,745 Scotia crossed 130,000 at 14.58. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.80% based on a bid of 14.50 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.C PerpetualDiscount 93,975 Scotia crossed 69,500 at 15.30. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.77% based on a bid of 15.05 and a limitMaturity.
SLF.PR.E PerpetualDiscount 78,540 Desjardins bought two blocks from Nesbitt, of 10,000 and 12,200 shares, both at 12.50. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 9.16% based on a bid of 12.40 and a limitMaturity.
GWO.PR.H PerpetualDiscount 73,750 Scotia crossed 49,000 at 14.31. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.67% based on a bid of 14.10 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.O PerpetualDiscount 70,640 National crossed 20,000 at 18.91. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.56% based on a bid of 18.91 and a limitMaturity.

There were ninety-one other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

What is the YTW of RY.PR.N? Win a PrefLetter!

Monday, December 22nd, 2008

I will admit that sometimes I look at the analysis generated by HIMIPref™ and blink. The assumptions and procedures and approximations used in the course of the analysis can sometimes work together in unexpected ways … so the results need to be reviewed in order to determine whether

  • the programme is really doing what I wanted it to do, and
  • whether I still want the programme to do what I previously wanted it to do

Such are the joys of quantitative analysis, when you can spend a month trying to figure out the analysis of one instrument on a date from ten years back!

This time, however, it’s today’s analysis of RY.PR.N: it closed today at 26.00-10, 28×1, after trading 29,390 shares in a range of 26.00-10.

And yet despite the $26.00 price, HIMIPref™ shows the pre-tax bid-YTW scenario as being the limitMaturity – that is, the dummy maturity thirty-years hence which is used as a substite for “forever”.

First, some facts: the issue closed on December 9 and is a fixed reset with the terms 6.25%+350. The analysis assumes that 5-year Canadas will now and forever yield 1.83%, so the rate is presumed to be reset to 5.33% at the first (and all subsequent) reset dates.

HIMIPref™ calculates the yield to first call of 5.4130% and yield-to-limit of 5.2913%. I have uploaded the cash-flow reports for the five year and 30-year maturities. The YTW is the worst yield, 5.2913%, and the YTW scenario is the 30-year maturity.

There cannot be much argument about the yield calculation for the five year maturity; everything is known, so it’s all perfectly standard. However, the thirty year maturity is simply an analytical placeholder for “forever” and the maturity value is not known. As you can see from the reports, HIMIPref™ estimates a price of $23.44 for the 30-year case.

Why $23.44? For that we have to look at the HIMIPref™ calculation of costYield … I have uploaded the relevant cash flow analysis. Readers will note the cash flow entry dated 2014-3-26, for -1.73 (future value) discounted to -1.34 (present value). This is the estimate of what the issuer’s call option is costing the holder; the implication is that if this option didn’t exist, we’d be willing to pay $1.34 (present value) more for the security.

The value of the option is calculated using a time-influenced distribution of possible prices centred on the current price. As shown by the Option Cash Flow Effect Analysis, it is currently assumed that there is a 53% chance of the option being exercised. Slicing the price distribution into two parts on that date, it is calculated that the average unconstrained price in exercise scenarios is 28.24; the average unconstrained price in non-exercise scenarios is 23.44. Voila! An estimated maturity price of $23.44.

I’ve also uploaded an Excel spreadsheet where I did a little fooling around with the reports. Raw data is in cells a1:e128. I’ve converted the semi-annual yield back into annual in cells c129:c130. The cash-flows with some decimals put back in are in cells g1:g122. My check on the arithmetic is in cells i1:j122 and sum to a present value of $26.03805; I’m assuming that the extra 3.805 cents is due to rounding differences of dates and days-in-year approximations. I used cells l1:n124 to play around with the yield-effect of different maturity values, and summarized my playing in cells l127:n130, which I will reproduce here:

RY.PR.N
Effect of Maturity Value
on Calculated Yield
Maturity Value Semi-Annual Yield
25.00 5.38%
26.00 5.44%
23.44 5.290%

It’s not all that sensitive, but the rate with a 26.00 end-value is slightly in excess of the 5-year rate, implying that if we rely on a 26.00 end-value then the 5-year yield is the YTW … as would be expected.

But I claim that you cannot count on a 26.00 end-value. I claim that if the unconstrained market price is 26.00 on a call date, then the issuer will call the issue at 25.00 instead. All you can count on at the end of eternity (which is 30-years off) is that fraction of the price distribution that escaped the calls … and that has an average value of 23.44.

And hence, the YTW scenario for a 26.00 issue callable at 25.00 in five years is … the limit maturity. This doesn’t happen for normal “straight” perpetuals: if the issue had an expected cash flow stream of 6.25% for the entire 30-year period, rather than 6.25% for five years and 5.33% thereafter, the five-year call would have a lower yield and hence be the YTW scenario.

And, just for fun, let’s have a contest! Presuming an end-value of 23.44, what post-reset 5-Year Canada yield (and hence, what dividend rate on RY.PR.N) do we need to bump the yield up to the point where the 5-year call becomes the Yield-To-Worst scenario? First correct answer wins a copy of the January edition of PrefLetter.

RPA.PR.A Downgraded to P-3 / Watch Negative by S&P

Monday, December 22nd, 2008

ROC Pref II Corp has announced:

that Standard & Poor’s (“S&P”) lowered its ratings on ROC II’s Preferred Shares from P-2 to P-3 and the Preferred Shares remain on CreditWatch with negative implications. S&P expects to resolve the CreditWatch placement within a period of 90 days and update its opinion. As announced in a press release dated December 8, the move comes as a result of the Tribune Company credit event as well as several downgrades of companies held in the Reference Portfolio.

ROC Pref II Corp.’s Preferred Shares pay a fixed quarterly coupon of 4.65% on their $25.00 principal value and will mature on or about December 31, 2009. The Standard & Poor’s rating addresses the likelihood of full payment of distributions and payment of $25.00 principal value per Preferred Share on the maturity date. The Preferred Shares are listed for trading on the Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbol RPA.PR.A.

The effect of the Tribune credit event was reported on PrefBlog.

RPA.PR.A is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

PRF.PR.A Downgraded to P-2(high) / Watch Negative by S&P

Monday, December 22nd, 2008

ROC Pref Corp has announced:

that Standard & Poor’s (“S&P”) lowered its ratings on the Company’s Preferred Shares from P-1 to P-2 (high) and the Preferred Shares remain on CreditWatch with negative implications. S&P expects to resolve the CreditWatch placement within a period of 90 days and update its opinion. As announced in a press release dated December 8, the move comes as a result of the Tribune Company credit event as well as several downgrades of companies held in the Reference Portfolio.

ROC Pref Corp.’s Preferred Shares pay a fixed quarterly coupon of 4.30% on their $25.00 principal value and will mature on or about September 30, 2009. The Standard & Poor’s rating addresses the likelihood of full payment of distributions and payment of $25.00 principal value per Preferred Share on the maturity date. The Preferred Shares are listed for trading on the Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbol PRF.PR.A.

The effect of the Tribune credit event was reported on PrefBlog.

PRF.PR.A is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

OSFI Clarifies Position on Bank Capital

Monday, December 22nd, 2008

In a speech given on November 18, OSFI Superintendant Julia Dickson said:

With the new found appreciation for capital, everyone is asking what capital level is enough, particularly in the banking sector, which has been in the eye of the storm. While it is difficult to do a comparison of capital ratios across global life companies (due to differences in nomenclature and approach), it is easier to do in the banking sector, and that has been the focus of much attention.

What we see in a comparison of international banks against Canadian banks is that our big five banks went into the turmoil with high capital levels (and we would say the same about life companies). Bank Tier 1 ratios at Q3 2008 ranged from 9.47 per cent to 9.81 per cent. This compared to Tier 1 ratios at other global banks that often started with the digits 6, 7 and 8 (versus 9 in Canada).

If you look at what is contained in Tier 1 — as they say, never judge a book by its cover — you will find that Canadian banks have platinum quality Tier 1 when compared to banks in other countries. The percentage of common shares is skyhigh, something not replicated in other places around the world.

Capital injections from governments into other global banks have tended to be in preferred shares (and sometimes preferred shares with step-ups or incentives to redeem that detract from their permanence, and permanence is a critical element for OSFI to consider something as Tier 1 capital). Canadian bank Tier 1 common ratios at Q3 2008 tended to be in the high 7s or low 8s. Elsewhere in the world the ratios were typically 5, 6, and low 7s.

To summarize, quality, and level of capital, are equally important and the market needs to focus on that. Going forward, there is going to be an incredible amount of attention paid by regulators internationally on the level and quality of capital. I believe Canada is well placed to enter those discussions. I also think that decisions will likely only be taken once world economies strengthen, and financial institutions will be given plenty of advance notice regarding new requirements.

The increase in the Tier 1 preferred limit has been discussed on PrefBlog. It does seem rather odd to me that OSFI is exalting the high quality of bank capital while at the same time permitting its debasement. There’s not necessarily a contradiction here, but there is definitely a need for a wee bit of discussion on the point.

Now, in the face of media frenzy, OSFI has released a note of calm:

Recent media reports regarding the Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions’ (OSFI) position on capital ratio levels may have led to some confusion. On Friday, December 19, 2008, OSFI provided the following information to the media:
OSFI’s views on capital were outlined in a speech given by Superintendent Julie Dickson on November 13, 2008, and those views have not changed.

In that speech, the Superintendent made a number of points, among them, that Canadian banks remain well capitalized. It noted that common equity ratios of the large banks are particularly high, and that markets ought to consider this in their views about capital adequacy. This point was made because markets were demanding that Canadian banks increase capital, possibly based on a simple comparison of Tier 1 levels across global banks, even though many global banks have had capital injections from governments.

Further, it was noted that banks should not engage in share buy-backs without first clearing it with OSFI, as capital needed to be managed conservatively. Managing capital conservatively does not mean increasing capital.

OSFI has discussed global market developments both with banks and international regulators, as a similar phenomenon of markets taking a view on capital and driving up capital levels, is being observed globally. At the same time, to the extent banks have met market expectations regarding capital, this makes Canadian banks well-positioned to continue to lend.

As well, OSFI has increased flexibility within its rules by increasing the preferred share limit to 40 per cent from 30 per cent, which reduces the cost of capital for financial institutions, and may further support lending.

In short, OSFI has not pushed for higher capital ratios across the board, and OSFI agrees that capital is a cushion that should be available to be drawn down when faced with unexpected losses.

Term Premia on Real-Return Bonds in the UK

Monday, December 22nd, 2008

The Bank of England has released Working Paper #358, “Understanding the real rate conundrum: an application of no-arbitrage finance models to the UK real yield curve”, by Michael Joyce, Iryna Kaminska and Peter Lildholdt, with the abstract:

Long-horizon interest rates in the major international bond markets fell sharply during 2004 and 2005, at the same time as US policy rates were rising; a phenomenon famously described as a ‘conundrum’ by Alan Greenspan the Federal Reserve Chairman. But it was arguably the decline in international long real rates over this period which was more unusual and, by the end of 2007, long real rates in the United Kingdom remained at recent historical lows. In this paper, we try to shed light on the recent behaviour of long real rates, by estimating several empirical models of the term structure of real interest rates, derived from UK index-linked bonds. We adopt a standard ‘finance’ approach to modelling the real term structure, using an essentially affine framework. While being empirically tractable, these models impose the important theoretical restriction of no arbitrage, which enables us to decompose forward real rates into expectations of future short (ie risk-free) real rates and forward real term premia. One general finding that emerges across all the models estimated is that time-varying term premia appear to be extremely important in explaining movements in long real forward rates. Although there is some evidence that long-horizon expected short real rates declined over the conundrum period, our results suggest lower term premia played the dominant role in accounting for the fall in long real rates. This evidence could be consistent with the so-called ‘search for yield’ and excess liquidity explanations for the conundrum, but it might also partly reflect strong demand for index-linked bonds by institutional investors and foreign central banks.

From the discussion:

One clear finding of our results across all the models we estimate is the importance of movements in estimated real term premia in explaining movements in real rates. This is contrary to what appears to be the conventional wisdom that real term premia are small and negligible. Indeed, many papers simply ignore the presence of real term premia altogether (for a recent example, see Ang, Bekaert and Wei (2007)).

Negative term premia are of course quite consistent with finance theory and may indicate that for some investors long-maturity index-linked bonds are seen as providing a form of ‘insurance’. However, the emergence of negative term premia in the late 1990s seems likely to have reflected the impact of various accounting and regulatory changes that have caused pension funds to match their assets more closely to their liabilities by switching into long-maturity conventional and index-linked bonds (see McGrath and Windle (2006)). Indeed, the timing of the move to negative term premia suggested by the model decompositions seems to broadly match the introduction of the MFR in 1997, which market commentary suggests had a significant impact on UK pension fund asset allocation.

Footnote: More recently, the Pensions Act 2004, which became effective in December 2005, introduced a new Pensions Regulator with powers to require pension fund trustees and sponsors to address issues of underfunding. Another factor that may also have influenced pension fund behaviour has been the ‘FRS 17’ accounting standard, which became effective from the start of 2005, and has meant that pension scheme deficits/surpluses need to be measured at market value and included on company balance sheets. Both these factors are thought to have increased pension fund demand for longer-duration nominal and real gilts, as assets which provide a better match for their liabilities. See discussion in the ‘Markets and Operations’ article of the Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Spring 2006.

With conclusions:

Another important finding, common to all the estimated model specifications, is that our term premia estimates appear to have been negative over much of the sample period since the late 1990s. We have argued that this is likely to reflect the impact of various accounting and regulatory changes in the United Kingdom that have encouraged pension funds to match their assets more closely to their liabilities, by switching into long-maturity conventional and index-linked bonds. The importance of this Category 3 explanation for the behaviour of term premia after the 1990s needs to be borne in mind when interpreting more recent downward moves in term premia.

In terms of understanding the fall in long rates over the conundrum period during 2004 and 2005, all the estimated models suggest that falls in UK long real rates have to a significant degree reflected reductions in real term premia, though the extent to which this is true varies with the precise model specification used. The importance of the reduction in term premia might indicate the influence of changing institutional investor behaviour, but the fact that the decline in long rates was a global phenomenon suggests to us that this is unlikely to have been the primary cause. This leads us to the conclusion that excess liquidity and search for yield were more important in explaining the compression of real term premia. But since our models also suggest that there is some evidence that perceptions of the neutral rate of interest may have fallen, we cannot rule out the possibility that changes in the balance of investment and saving may also have had an impact. In terms of the recent conjuncture, all our model specifications would suggest that there is a risk real rates may rise in the future, since in all of the models forward premia or expected future short rates are below their long-run expected levels.

Chart 6: Decomposition of the ten-year real forward rate from the survey model:

Financing the Fed's Balance Sheet

Monday, December 22nd, 2008

James Hamilton of Econbrowser writes another marvellous review of the Fed’s Balance sheet, updating his prior commentary which was also reviewed on PrefBlog.

One thing I had been unclear about was the precise nature of the “Supplementary Financing Program Account” of Treasury at the Fed, which is financing all the special programmes. While the assertion has been made that the Fed’s intervention is sterilized (meaning that it is causing no increase in monetary aggregates) … I wasn’t sure. However, the Monthly Treasury Statement referenced by Dr. Hamilton shows clearly (Table 6 on page 20) that Treasury has issued about $630-odd billion in Treasury Securities in fiscal 2009 to date, of which $588-billion has been from the public. This more than covers the $134-billion increase in the Supplementary Account, while still leaving $402-billion to finance the deficit … which is the total deficit for F2009 reported in Table 5 on page 18.

OK, so that’s cleared up!

Dr. Hamilton concludes:

For the record, let me reiterate my personal position on all this.

(1) I am doubtful of the Fed’s ability to alter interest rate spreads through the kinds of compositional changes in its balance sheet implemented over the last two years. Whatever your prior ideas were about this, surely it’s time to revise those in light of incoming data– if the first trillion dollars didn’t do the job, how much do you think it would take to accomplish the task?

(2) I think the Fed’s goal should be a 3% inflation rate. Paying interest on reserves and encouraging banks to hoard them is inconsistent with that objective, as would be a new trillion dollars in money creation.

I would therefore urge the Fed to eliminate the payment of interest on reserves and begin the process of replacing the exotic colors in the first graph above with holdings such as inflation-indexed Treasury securities and the short-term government debt of our major trading partners.

I’m not sure that point 1 is phrased in a useful manner. As I see it, the objective is not so much to maintain spreads as it is to ensure that the market exists at all. It has been observed that securitization has declined, which has had essentially forced banks to intermediate between borrowers and lenders, as opposed to simply engaging in the disintermediation inherent in packaging their loans and taking the spreads and servicing fees.

John Kiff, Paul Mills & Carolyne Spackman wrote a piece for VoxEU, European securitisation and the possible revival of financial innovation:

Collapsing global securitisation volumes in the wake of the subprime crisis have raised fundamental questions over the viability of the originate-to-distribute business model.1 Issuance has dropped precipitously in both Europe and the US, with banks keeping more loans on their balance sheets and tightening lending standards as a result (Figure 1). The decline has been particularly sharp for mortgage-backed securities and mortgage-backed-securities-backed collateralised debt obligations. The originate-to-distribute model was thought to have made the financial system more resilient by dispersing credit risk to a broad range of investors. Ironically, however, it became the source of financial instability.

The risk transfer and capital saving benefits of securitisation, combined with underlying investor demand for securities, should eventually revive issuance. But the products are likely to be simpler, more transparent, and trade at significantly wider spreads.

All that lost securitization issuance is staying on banks’ balance sheets and there are only a few possibilities:

  • let the market collapse: in this case, banks will simply cease to make new loans; their balance sheets won’t take the strain and they can’t really issue new equity while the markets are so awfully depressed without really sticking it to their existing shareholders, or
  • let the markets adjust.

An adjustment in the market can take place in several different ways:

  • banks can re-intermediate: this will require balance sheet expansion, which can’t happen until they can sell equity at reasonable prices, or
  • securitization markets can get restarted

I suggest that it is a Public Good for securitization markets to restart and agree with Kiff et al. that this will likely be accompanied by greater transparency and wider spreads. Trouble is, nobody knows what those spreads will be like.

What should the spread of mortgages over governments be? Agency spreads in the US were minimal prior to the current crisis and it seems clear to me that they should be wider. I’ve tried to find an easy graph for mortgage spreads in Canada – where securitization is nowhere near as important – but the best I’ve been able to come up with is a chart from 1999:

Mortgages are not, perhaps, the best example to choose because as I have repeatedly noted, there is a lot more that’s wrong with the American mortgage market than mere sub-prime:

Americans should also be taking a hard look at the ultimate consumer friendliness of their financial expectations. They take as a matter of course mortgages that are:

  • 30 years in term
  • refinancable at little or no charge (usually; this may apply only to GSE mortgages; I don’t know all the rules)
  • non-recourse to borrower (there may be exceptions in some states)

  • guaranteed by institutions that simply could not operate as a private enterprise without considerably more financing
  • Added 2008-3-8: How could I forget? Tax Deductible

Clearly, in the particular case of US mortgages, the underlying pools must not just trade at wider spread, but they must be more investor friendly.

However, I do recognize Dr. Hamilton’s desire to put a limit on the amount of reintermediation that is being done by the Fed, but must disagree with the prescription of keeping the balance sheet grossed up with government bonds of any description.

I suggest that a schedule be put into place whereby, for instance, the Commercial Paper Funding Facility have its spreads gradually widened. Rates are now 2.19% for unsecured commercial paper and is scheduled to cease purchasing new paper on April 30, 2009. The current rate paid on excess & required reserve balances is now 0.25%. Thus, it is apparent that in the current environment, a spread of 194bp is not enough to get the banks to move into commercial paper in a big way. The same applies to the general public.

I suggest that this is a distress-level spread, being paid for CP of perfectly good quality; indicating a flight to safety. Eventually the climate of blind fear will dissapate, but until that happens the Fed should continue to apply the implicit Bagehot prescription of making credit freely available at punitive rates. And, perhaps, announce that the programme will be extended past April, but at spreads on CP of 110+110 (for the duration of the extension), rather than the current 100+100. Eventually, one of several things will happen:

  • Greed will overcome fear, and banks (et al.) will cease lending to the Fed at 0.25% and start lending to solid companies at 2.25%, or
  • Companies will refinance with longer term paper, or
  • Companies will go bust.

Bronte Capital Added to Blogroll

Saturday, December 20th, 2008

I haven’t read much of Bronte Capital, but I like what I see! The blog has been favourably reviewed by Felix Salmon.

The identification is not robust, but I believe that the author, John Hempton, was a Senior Analyst with Australia’s Platinum Asset Management. There is a Canadian connection with unsupported allegations that Mr. Hempton was involved – somehow – with the shorts’ attack on Fairfax. There is a John Hempton named in a class action lawsuit against SAC regarding Fairfax, but whether the lawsuit’s John Hempton is the same as the other John Hemptons named here is not clear. There is a similar reference in Fairfax’s lawsuit.