Archive for January, 2009

New Issue: CIBC Fixed-Reset 6.50%+447

Monday, January 26th, 2009

CIBC has announced:

that it had entered into an agreement with a group of underwriters led by CIBC World Markets Inc. for an issue of 8 million non-cumulative Rate Reset Class A Preferred Shares, Series 35 (the “Series 35 Shares”) priced at $25.00 per Series 35 Share to raise gross proceeds of $200 million.

CIBC has granted the underwriters an option, exercisable in whole or in part prior to closing, to purchase an additional 3 million Series 35 Shares at the same offering price. Should the underwriters’ option be fully exercised, the total gross proceeds of the financing will be $275 million.

The Series 35 Shares will yield 6.5% per annum, payable quarterly, as and when declared by the Board of Directors of CIBC, for an initial period ending April 30, 2014. On April 30, 2014 and on April 30 every five years thereafter, the dividend rate will reset to be equal to the then current five-year Government of Canada bond yield plus 4.47%.

Holders of the Series 35 Shares will have the right to convert their shares into non-cumulative Floating Rate Class A Preferred Shares, Series 36 (the “Series 36 Shares”), subject to certain conditions, on April 30, 2014 and on April 30 every five years thereafter. Holders of the Series 36 Shares will be entitled to receive a quarterly floating rate dividend, as and when declared by the Board of Directors of CIBC, equal to the three-month Government of Canada Treasury Bill yield plus 4.47%.

Holders of the Series 36 Shares may convert their Series 36 Shares into Series 35 Shares, subject to certain conditions, on April 30, 2019 and on April 30 every five years thereafter.

The expected closing date is February 4, 2009. The net proceeds of this offering will be used for general purposes of CIBC.

Update, 2009-2-3: CIBC announced on January 27:

that as a result of strong investor demand for its domestic public offering of non-cumulative Rate Reset Class A Preferred Shares, Series 35 (the “Series 35 Shares”), the size of the offering has been increased to 10 million shares. The gross proceeds of the offering will now be $250 million.

In addition, CIBC has granted the underwriters an option, exercisable in whole or in part prior to closing, to purchase up to an additional 3 million Series 35 Shares at a price of $25.00 per share. Should the underwriters’ option be fully exercised, the total gross proceeds of the financing will be $325 million.

The issue is set to close tomorrow and trade with the symbol CM.PR.L
The first dividend will be payable April 28 for $0.37842 based on closing Feb. 4

January 23, 2009

Friday, January 23rd, 2009

Inflation is down, according to Statistics Canada:

The Bank of Canada’s core index advanced 2.4% over the 12 months to December, identical to the rise in November. The main contributors to the increase in the core index were higher prices for bread, cereal products and meat products. Price declines for purchasing and leasing passenger vehicles remained the primary downward contributor.

The seasonally adjusted monthly core index posted no change from November to December, after rising 0.6% from October to November.

PerpetualDiscounts were off again today, reducing their month-to-date return to +5.65%, having peaked on January 13 at +7.51%. The median pre-tax bid-YTW is now 6.95%, equivalent to 9.73% interest at the standard conversion factor of 1.4x, compared to long corporates, still steady at 7.5%. The pre-tax interest-equivalent spread is thus 223bp.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 6.91 % 7.62 % 37,348 13.47 2 -1.5620 % 854.7
FixedFloater 7.39 % 7.02 % 150,619 13.69 8 -0.9992 % 1,386.9
Floater 5.43 % 4.61 % 35,389 16.22 4 -1.3023 % 967.5
OpRet 5.31 % 4.76 % 142,780 4.05 15 0.2877 % 2,023.8
SplitShare 6.28 % 9.84 % 79,275 4.14 15 -0.2689 % 1,772.5
Interest-Bearing 7.18 % 8.50 % 36,685 0.90 2 -0.1172 % 1,968.9
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.2455 % 1,550.5
Perpetual-Discount 6.92 % 6.95 % 231,379 12.62 71 -0.2455 % 1,427.9
FixedReset 6.01 % 4.98 % 817,266 14.88 22 -0.1483 % 1,805.4
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
PWF.PR.A Floater -7.54 % Bids disappeared, with four trades totalling 4,200 in a range of 12.50-00; closing at 12.02-50, 2×8.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 12.02
Evaluated at bid price : 12.02
Bid-YTW : 4.36 %
ELF.PR.G Perpetual-Discount -4.61 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 14.50
Evaluated at bid price : 14.50
Bid-YTW : 8.29 %
BAM.PR.G FixedFloater -4.45 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 10.51
Bid-YTW : 10.46 %
ELF.PR.F Perpetual-Discount -4.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 15.26
Evaluated at bid price : 15.26
Bid-YTW : 8.79 %
PPL.PR.A SplitShare -3.62 % Asset coverage of 1.4+:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2012-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.53
Bid-YTW : 9.76 %
SBC.PR.A SplitShare -3.45 % Asset coverage of 1.3-:1 as of January 22, according to Brompton Group.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2012-11-30
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 7.83
Bid-YTW : 12.67 %
BCE.PR.R FixedFloater -3.02 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 15.76
Bid-YTW : 7.08 %
BCE.PR.Y Ratchet -2.97 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 14.36
Bid-YTW : 7.62 %
RY.PR.E Perpetual-Discount -2.36 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 17.40
Evaluated at bid price : 17.40
Bid-YTW : 6.48 %
RY.PR.A Perpetual-Discount -2.34 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 17.09
Evaluated at bid price : 17.09
Bid-YTW : 6.52 %
BNS.PR.O Perpetual-Discount -2.29 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 20.90
Evaluated at bid price : 20.90
Bid-YTW : 6.75 %
TD.PR.Y FixedReset -2.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 21.96
Evaluated at bid price : 22.00
Bid-YTW : 4.22 %
CU.PR.A Perpetual-Discount -2.14 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 21.53
Evaluated at bid price : 21.53
Bid-YTW : 6.87 %
BAM.PR.K Floater -1.87 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 7.36
Evaluated at bid price : 7.36
Bid-YTW : 7.23 %
FFN.PR.A SplitShare -1.81 % Asset coverage of 1.1+:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2014-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 7.61
Bid-YTW : 11.07 %
TD.PR.C FixedReset -1.78 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 23.68
Evaluated at bid price : 23.72
Bid-YTW : 4.93 %
BNS.PR.Q FixedReset -1.77 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 21.12
Evaluated at bid price : 21.12
Bid-YTW : 4.40 %
SBN.PR.A SplitShare -1.75 % Asset coverage of 1.7-:1 as of January 15 according to Mulvihill.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2014-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.96
Bid-YTW : 7.53 %
RY.PR.L FixedReset -1.74 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 23.66
Evaluated at bid price : 23.70
Bid-YTW : 4.98 %
GWO.PR.I Perpetual-Discount -1.71 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 15.51
Evaluated at bid price : 15.51
Bid-YTW : 7.36 %
FTN.PR.A SplitShare -1.65 % Asset coverage of 1.3-:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2015-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 7.76
Bid-YTW : 9.99 %
CM.PR.E Perpetual-Discount -1.58 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 19.29
Evaluated at bid price : 19.29
Bid-YTW : 7.32 %
RY.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -1.58 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 17.47
Evaluated at bid price : 17.47
Bid-YTW : 6.60 %
BCE.PR.I FixedFloater -1.44 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 15.78
Bid-YTW : 7.06 %
GWO.PR.H Perpetual-Discount -1.43 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 16.57
Evaluated at bid price : 16.57
Bid-YTW : 7.42 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -1.40 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 17.58
Evaluated at bid price : 17.58
Bid-YTW : 6.72 %
IAG.PR.A Perpetual-Discount -1.13 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 16.61
Evaluated at bid price : 16.61
Bid-YTW : 7.02 %
SLF.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.11 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 15.55
Evaluated at bid price : 15.55
Bid-YTW : 7.26 %
PWF.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 1.16 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 21.75
Evaluated at bid price : 21.75
Bid-YTW : 6.95 %
PWF.PR.M FixedReset 1.34 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 24.95
Evaluated at bid price : 25.00
Bid-YTW : 5.22 %
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.79 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 18.23
Evaluated at bid price : 18.23
Bid-YTW : 6.93 %
BAM.PR.B Floater 2.10 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 7.77
Evaluated at bid price : 7.77
Bid-YTW : 6.84 %
NA.PR.N FixedReset 2.23 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 22.44
Evaluated at bid price : 22.50
Bid-YTW : 4.49 %
SLF.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 2.27 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 16.65
Evaluated at bid price : 16.65
Bid-YTW : 7.23 %
BNA.PR.B SplitShare 2.38 % Asset coverage of 1.8+:1 as of December 31 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2016-03-25
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 21.50
Bid-YTW : 7.69 %
BNA.PR.C SplitShare 2.42 % Asset coverage of 1.8+:1 as of December 31 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2019-01-10
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 11.01
Bid-YTW : 15.94 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet 3.34 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 17.62
Bid-YTW : 10.65 %
TRI.PR.B Floater 4.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 11.50
Evaluated at bid price : 11.50
Bid-YTW : 4.61 %
DFN.PR.A SplitShare 4.44 % Asset coverage of 1.7-:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2014-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.70
Bid-YTW : 8.22 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BNS.PR.T FixedReset 103,166 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.05
Bid-YTW : 5.91 %
RY.PR.P FixedReset 85,318 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 24.97
Evaluated at bid price : 25.02
Bid-YTW : 5.96 %
BNS.PR.P FixedReset 83,680 Nesbitt crossed 60,000 at 23.00.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 22.87
Evaluated at bid price : 22.95
Bid-YTW : 4.29 %
ELF.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 71,647 RBC bought 21,000 from National at 16.00; Scotia bought two blocks of 10,000 each at 10.90; one from anonymous, the other from National.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 15.26
Evaluated at bid price : 15.26
Bid-YTW : 8.79 %
TD.PR.E FixedReset 60,545 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 25.09
Evaluated at bid price : 25.14
Bid-YTW : 6.06 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 43,800 Nesbitt crossed 30,000 at 17.63, then another 10,000 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-23
Maturity Price : 17.58
Evaluated at bid price : 17.58
Bid-YTW : 6.72 %
There were 29 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

Ricardo Cabellero on the Credit Crunch

Friday, January 23rd, 2009

Ricardo Cabellero is the Ford International Professor of Economics at MIT, Co-Director of the World Economic Laboratory, and Head of the Economics Department. He has just written a pair of columns for VoxEU, liberally sprinkled with accessible references addressing first the causes of the credit crunch and secondly his prescriptions for future policy.

I was immediately impressed by his rejection of currently fashionable scapegoating:

There is an emerging consensus on the causes of the crisis which essentially rehashes an old list of complaints about potential excesses committed in the phase prior to the crisis. The sins include uncontrolled global imbalances, unscrupulous lenders, and an insatiable Wall Street, all of them lubricated by an ever expansionary Federal Reserve.

It follows from this perspective that the appropriate policy response is to focus on reducing global imbalances, boosting financial regulation, bringing down leverage ratios, and adding bubble-control to the Fed’s mandate.

I do not share this consensus view and its policy prescriptions

I have often complained – e.g., yesterday – that the targetting of “perverse incentives” as the root of all evil misses the point. You have to sell what you manufacture. If you can’t sell it, no profit for the company, no bonus. Targetting Wall Street and its 30-year-old traders implicitly absolves the grey-haired financial managers and regulators who created the demand, bought the product, and demanded more.

I will point out that it is very difficult to talk an investor out of making money. You can convince them that a future investment making $1 a month has $10 worth of risk and should be avoided. You can commiserate with them after they’ve lost their $10. But in between, don’t try telling somebody who has just made $1 that he was lucky, not smart.

For quite some time, but in particular since the late 1990s, the world has experienced a chronic shortage of financial assets to store value. The reasons behind this shortage are varied. They include the rise in savings needs by aging populations in Japan and Europe, the fast growth and global integration of high saving economies, the precautionary response of emerging markets to earlier financial crises, and the intertemporal smoothing of commodity producing economies.

Moreover, because of the US’s role as the centre of world capital markets, much of the large global demand for financial assets has been channelled toward US assets. This has been the main reason for the large global “imbalances” observed in recent years. The large current account deficits experienced by the US are simply the counterpart of the large demand for its assets.

I once asked an economist I respect about the US current account deficit and financing by US debt. Could the root cause, I asked, be a demand for US debt by the rest of the world, rather than US demand for foreign goods? I didn’t get much of an answer … I should have asked Cabellero!

However, there was one important caveat that would prove crucial later on. The global demand for assets was particularly for very safe assets – assets with AAA credit ratings. This is not surprising in light of the importance of central banks and sovereign wealth funds in creating this high demand for assets. Moreover, this trend toward safety became even more pronounced after the NASDAQ crash.

Soon enough, US banks found a “solution” to this mismatch between the demand for safe assets and the expansion of supply through the creation of risky subprime assets; the market moved to create synthetic AAA instruments.

Wall Street met the demand of blind investors. What’s unusual about that? I have also noted some academic experimental work indicating that the price of an asset tends to increase to the money available to buy it, regardless of intrinsic quality.

The AAA tranches so created were held by the non-levered sector of the world economy, including central banks, sovereign wealth funds, pension funds, etc. They were also held by a segment of the highly-levered sector, especially foreign banks and domestic banks that kept them on their books, directly and indirectly, as they provided attractive “safe” yields. The small toxic component was mostly held by agents that could handle the risk, although highly levered investment banks also were exposed.

Much of the focus on the regulatory and credit agency mistakes highlights the fact that the AAA tranch seems to have been too large relative to the “true” capacity of the underlying risky instruments to create such a tranch. While I agree with this assessment, I believe it is incomplete and, because of this, it does not point to the optimal policy response.

Instead, I believe the key issue is that even if we give the benefit of the doubt to the credit agencies and accept that these instruments were indeed AAA from an unconditional probability of default perspective (the only one that counts for credit agencies), they were not so with respect to severe macroeconomic risk.

This created a highly volatile concoction where highly levered institutions of systemic importance were holding assets that were very vulnerable to aggregate shocks. This was an accident waiting to happen.

It’s very hard to forecast a paradigm shift. If the people being advised are making good money, they won’t listen to such a forecast anyway. Even if they do acknowledge the possibility of such an event, they will be serenely confident of their ability to recognize the turning point when it happens and cash out at the top.

To paraphrase a recent secretary of defence, risk refers to situations where the unknowns are known, while uncertainty refers to situations where the unknowns are unknown. This distinction is not only linguistically interesting, but also has significant implications for economic behaviour and policy prescriptions.

There is extensive experimental evidence that economic agents faced with (Knightian) uncertainty become overly concerned with extreme, even if highly unlikely, negative events. Unfortunately, the very fact that investors behave in this manner make the dreaded scenarios all the more likely.

Worsening the situation, until very recently, the policy response from the US Treasury exacerbated rather than dampened the uncertainty problem.

Early on in the crisis, there was a nagging feeling that policy was behind the curve; then came the “exemplary punishment” (of shareholders) policy of Secretary Paulson during the Bear Stearns intervention, which significantly dented the chance of a private capital solution to the problem; and finally, the most devastating blow came during the failure to support Lehman. The latter unleashed a very different kind of recession, where uncertainty ravaged all forms of explicit and implicit financial insurance markets.

In the second column, Dr. Cabellero developes the “financial insurance” theme:

An economy with no financial insurance operates very differently from the standard modern economies we are accustomed to in the developed world.

  • There is limited uncollateralized or long-term credit (since such loans always have an insurance built in through the possibility of default),
  • the risk premium sky-rockets,
  • economic agents hoard massive amount of resources for self-insurance and real investment purposes.

During the last quarter of 2008 we witnessed the beginning of a transition from an economy with insurance to one without it.

Fair enough! That’s as good a summary as any I’ve seen. But what are the implications?

At this juncture of the crisis there are mountains of investment-ready cash waiting for some indication that the time to enter the market has arrived. But investors are frozen staring at each other, and by so doing, they are further dragging the economy downward. The normal speculative forces that trigger a recovery are for everybody to want to arrive first, to “make a killing.” But with so much fear around us, investors have changed the paradigm and they are now content with letting somebody else try his or her luck first, so we are stuck.

We need to reverse this mechanism by restoring the appetite for arriving first.

My sense is that, to a first order of approximation, the correct policy response should build on the following three observations:

  • Many of the ex-ante “imbalances” are more structural in nature than is implied in the consensus view, and hence will remain with us long after the crisis is over.
  • They stem from a global excess demand for financial assets and, especially, for AAA financial assets.
  • The main policy mistakes took place during rather than prior to the crisis.


Contrary to what investors thought at the peak of the boom, the (private) financial sector in the US is not able to satisfy the global demand for AAA assets when large negative aggregate events take place. However, the US government does have the capacity to fill this gap, especially because it is the recipient of flight-to-quality capital.

As long as the government becomes the explicit insurer for generalised panic-risk, we can in the medium run go back to a world not too different from the one we had before the crisis (aside from real estate prices and the construction sector).

This must be acknowledged in advance, and paid for by the insured institutions. Reasonable concerns about transparency, complexity, and incentives can be built into the insurance premia. Collective deleveraging, as currently being done, should not constitute the core response; macroeconomic insurance should.

The recent government intervention with respect to Citi – with its mixture of (paid) insurance and capital – is a promising precedent. So too was the second government package for AIG.

These interventions need to be scaled up to the whole financial system (banks and beyond), and it is better to do it all at once, for in this case the likelihood of the government ever having to disburse funds for its insurance provision becomes remote.

In all these contexts, trimming the (lower) tail-risk offers the biggest bang-for-the-buck. In this sense, capital injections are not a particularly efficient way of dealing with the problem unless the government is willing to invest massive amounts of capital, certainly much more than the current TARP. The reason is that Knightian uncertainty generates a sort of double-(or more)-counting problem, where scarce capital is wasted insuring against impossible events (Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2008b).

Does this mean that there is no role for capital injections? Certainly not. Knightian uncertainty is not the only problem in financial markets, and capital injections are needed for conventional reasons as well. The point is simply that these injections need to be supplemented by insurance contracts, unless the government is willing to increase the TARP by an order of magnitude (i.e. measure it in trillions).

Very well argued!

It is amusing to note – given the tendency to blame complexity nowadays – that the “insurance contract” represents a Credit Default Swap on the equity tranche of a tiered product made up of other tiered products, ie. CDO-squared. Ha-ha!

And, as it happens, there is a manner in which private companies can apply this prescription – more or less – on the public markets.

Assiduous Readers will remember that Manulife got into difficulty with its seg-fund guarantees. The problem is that they are – as managers – ascribing a very low probability to those guarantees being required, while at the same time they are – as regulated bodies – ascribing a higher probability to the melt-down scenario. Sound familiar?

So here’s a modest proposal … and I’ll use Manulife as an example, but any institution with any clearly definable tail-risk will do:

  • MFC sets up a wholly owned subsidiary that provides disaster insurance to the parent.
  • The sub is capitalized with $1-billion
  • The sub buys government bonds (preferrably strips, but any immunized portfolio will do) worth, say $1.2-billion in ten years.
  • The sub sells ten-year disaster insurance to the parent on commercial terms; e.g. “If the TSX is below X in 10 years, sub pays parent $1.2-billion.”
  • Parent distributes all the common of the sub to the parent’s shareholders.

MFC has the money to do this. According to their Annual Report, they spent $2.245-billion on share buybacks in 2007 and $1.631-billion in 2006. Just divert some money from that.

With this plan, MFC reduces its vulnerability to tail risk, while at the same time giving the shareholders the benefit of the positive (as perceived by management) net present value of the insurance. As a bonus, the risk has been unbundled for investors to retain or dump, as they see fit.

Update, 2009-1-26: Aleablog supports the Caballero plan. Dealbreaker is somewhat suspicious.

OSFI Examining Liquidity Risk

Friday, January 23rd, 2009

OSFI has advised that it:

is in the process of revising Guideline B-6 on Liquidity to take account of the Principles recommended by the Basel Committee and to incorporate any additional guidance that is appropriate for domestic application. Similar deliberations are taking place across jurisdictions through the BCBS and other regulatory fora. A consultation draft of the revised Guideline is targeted for release in the summer of 2009.

There is, surprisingly, a request for submissions:

As part of our development of new guidance on liquidity, OSFI welcomes submissions as to how to best give effect to the BCBS Principles on a consistent and measurable basis.

… but no indication that these submissions will be publicly disclosed and discussed.

The Basel Committee on Banking Supervisions’s September ’08 Principles for Sound Liquidity Risk Management and Supervision include:

Principle 13: A bank should publicly disclose information on a regular basis that enables market participants to make an informed judgement about the soundness of its liquidity risk management framework and liquidity position.

… with the exhortation:

As part of its periodic financial reporting, a bank should provide quantitative information about its liquidity position that enables market participants to form a view of its liquidity risk. Examples of quantitative disclosures currently disclosed by some banks include information regarding the size and composition of the bank’s liquidity cushion, additional collateral requirements as the result of a credit rating downgrade, the values of internal ratios and other key metrics that management monitors (including regulatory metrics that may exist in the bank’s jurisdiction), the limits placed on the values of those metrics, and balance sheet and off-balance sheet items broken down into a number of short-term maturity bands and the resultant cumulative liquidity gaps. A bank should provide sufficient qualitative discussion around its metrics to enable market participants to understand them, eg the time span covered, whether computed under normal or stressed conditions, the organisational level to which the metric applies (group, bank or non-bank subsidiary), and other assumptions utilised in measuring the bank’s liquidity position, liquidity risk and liquidity cushion.

As an example of current reporting the RBC 2008 Annual Report contains a three page section (pp. 109-112 of the report, 111-114 of the PDF) on liquidity risk, comprised largely of ‘don’t worry, trust us’ blather and precious little quantitative data.

Ed Clark on TARP & Moral Hazard

Friday, January 23rd, 2009

Ed Clark, CEO of TD Bank, has gotten himself into a little trouble over some remarks made at the RBC Capital Markets Canadian Bank CEO Conference, Jan. 8, 2009, in Toronto.

He began by deprecating TARP:

I think we have the capital, but, as I said when I do the little arithmetic, that’s an issue. As you know – I mean, I have strong views on this. The United States comes along and it puts this TARP in and adds three points to the Tier 1 ratio. If we were in the United States today, our Tier 1 ratio would be about 12.5%, so you sit there and you say this is just a con game, a five-year retractable pref we’re going to call common equity, because the US government says, Basel was an interesting thought, but we overrule Basel. And so if we look at Wells Fargo, USB and PNC, our tangible common equity is 40% or 50% bigger than theirs. And that’s the way I run the bank, is everything starts with tangible common equity, and then you leverage that up in different structures and that’s – so you get that and then you try to maximize your return on risk-weighted assets, which means you maximize your operating ROE.

… which was interesting enough, but his comments on the safety of TD preferred shares – and by implication, other Canadian banks – have attracted attention:

I think Mr. Bernanke’s going to win. He’s going to say to the market, I’m going to make it so expensive for you to hold riskless assets that you will finally wake up and say you can take some risk.

And that’s really what happened in our preferred share issue, is that the average consumer sat there and said, well, this is 6.25%, but it’s actually 8% pretax, effectively government guaranteed, maybe not explicitly, but what are the chances that TD Bank is going to not be bailed out if it did something stupid? And so where else do I get 8% government investments right now? And I think suddenly the retail market came back in January and said, give me more of this, and so when we did our issue, they said, could you give us some more of this piece of paper?

And so I do think that we are going to be able to emerge out of this and say the Canadian bank will not only redefine Canadian banking, I think it will redefine Canada as to say, somehow you guys did it right. It’s not obvious, you don’t look that smart when we look at you, but somehow you stumbled your way through here and did this right.

And so, I think that’s worth fighting hard for, and if that means that when the shorts from the US arrive in Toronto and swagger down Bay Street and say, we’re going to short all the Canadian banks and teach you guys a lesson, we’re going to put you out of business, you have to take them seriously, fight back. But you don’t fight back by going on the market. And so if that means we have to raise non-common Tier 1 ratio to look pretty, I’ll do that. It’s stupid, but it’s good to the interests of my shareholders.

It’s an interesting passage. I certainly agree with the characterization of Bernanke’s strategy for fighting the credit crunch. I have recently highlighted the enormous build-up in excess reserves in the US, that are currently held at basically no interest at the Fed; a hopeful sign is a recent shrinking of the Fed’s balance sheet; and if the Fed keeps spreads where they are – or follows my recommendation to slowly increase them – then at some point greed will overcome fear.

The last part of the passage deals with the eternal financial markets question: lucky or smart? He obviously has a conflict of interest in being so firmly in the “smart” school and buttresses it with a little nationalist swagger; I’m going to retain my opinion of “lucky”. But you never really know.

It’s the middle piece of the passage, where he states in so many words that there’s an implicit government guarantee on TD’s (and presumably the rest of the Big 6) preferred shares.

It’s a shockingly irresponsible statement; one may hope that at the very least he has a highly uncomfortable meeting with the regulators (he won’t, of course, but it’s always pleasant to hope).

I will go so far as to agree that at this particular time, if any of the Big 6 disclosed that they were far too close to insolvency for comfort, there would almost certainly be a bail-out (although I’m less certain that preferred shareholders would get off scot-free). I think the global response to the Lehman insolvency has convinced policy makers that now is not the right time to apply doctrinaire free market principles.

But. But! These preferreds Mr. Clark is flogging are perpetual. Interest rate may be mitigated – with corresponding increase in reinvestment risk – but the credit risk is perpetual. Twenty years ago, Mr. Clark’s smart bank was on the verge of insolvency, having hired too many MBAs to accumulate More Bad Assets in Mexico, Brazil and Argentina.

Could it happen again? Why not? Even if we allow Mr. Clark’s assertion that TD is very smart, I’m reminded of an investment aphorism (source unknown, at least to me): Only buy businesses that an idiot could run, because eventually an idiot will.

If, ten years forward, TD Bank does something stupid at a time when the collapse of a rinky-dink little Canadian bank will not have global systemic implications … it could fail. And I will remind investors that Tier-1 eligible preferred shares are perpetual, and the word “perpetual” includes “ten years forward”.

So anyway, he’s been taken to the woodshed by a bravely anonymous “government official”, reports Bloomberg:

Toronto-Dominion Bank Chief Executive Officer Ed Clark was “absolutely wrong” to suggest the bank had the implicit promise of a bailout under any circumstances, a senior Canadian government official said.

There are “no guarantees” for companies that make “stupid decisions,” said the official yesterday in Ottawa, who spoke on condition he not be identified.

… or, at least, as close to the woodshed as we’re likely to get.

Why isn’t Spend-Every-Penny making this statement? Why aren’t the regulators demanding an instant and grovelling retraction?

January 22, 2009

Friday, January 23rd, 2009

I went to a seminar on Risk Management today, presented as part of the Finance Experts Discussion Series @ Rotman.

Rather disappointing, really. Panelists were:

  • Derrell Hendrix, CEO, RISConsulting and Founding Partner and CEO, Karson Management (Bermuda) Limited
  • John Hull, Maple Financial Group Chair in Derivatives and Risk Management, Professor of Finance and Co-Director, Master of Finance Program, Rotman School of Management, U of Toronto
  • Robert (Bob) Tapscott, interim CEO, RISConsulting

One of the RISConsulting guys – I forget which one – was of the view that transparency will save the world and drew comparisons to nuclear reactor design and operation. He did not address the problems inherent in forecasting financial markets – rather than designing and operating physical technology – nor did he explain whereby investors are presumed to be able to find the time to utilize such transparency. Hands up everybody who’s read through the entire annual report of every company in which they’ve invested!

Dr. Hull claimed that the world would be saved through reduction of perverse incentives, by which he means he wants deferred bonuses rather than immediate ones. He did not address the question of who in their right mind would willingly work for a deferred bonus, or what discounting rate a rational participant should apply to the deferred portion since eventual payment of the amount due is basically discretionary. I’d suggest 50%+. Counterparty risk is pretty extreme in such circumstances.

Limited / Deferred / Regulated compensation is getting a lot of ink nowadays. Econbrowser‘s James Hamilton is also beating that drum. Sigh. Time to move to Dubai, ’cause that’s where all the action’s going to be in ten years, at this rate.

Credit crunch commentary has now reached its most tiresome phase: it’s just being used as a vehicle to push along various long-standing agendas. The crisis itself is merely a tired rehash of the panic of 1825 and it’s BORING.

Good volume today, but the market was off a good bit, probably due – as much as anything in the markets is ever due – to a combination of rotten equities and heavy issuance.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 6.83 % 7.42 % 37,658 13.67 2 -0.0347 % 868.3
FixedFloater 7.32 % 6.90 % 153,304 13.82 8 -0.1379 % 1,400.9
Floater 5.36 % 4.79 % 35,027 15.87 4 -1.9529 % 980.2
OpRet 5.32 % 4.78 % 141,464 4.05 15 -0.1617 % 2,018.0
SplitShare 6.26 % 9.78 % 82,309 4.14 15 -0.9220 % 1,777.3
Interest-Bearing 7.18 % 8.24 % 36,981 0.90 2 -0.1170 % 1,971.2
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.5751 % 1,554.3
Perpetual-Discount 6.90 % 6.94 % 233,509 12.63 71 -0.5751 % 1,431.5
FixedReset 6.00 % 4.89 % 828,051 15.05 22 -0.7398 % 1,808.0
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
DFN.PR.A SplitShare -7.44 % Asset coverage of 1.7-:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2014-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.33
Bid-YTW : 9.13 %
BAM.PR.B Floater -7.20 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 7.61
Evaluated at bid price : 7.61
Bid-YTW : 6.99 %
PWF.PR.I Perpetual-Discount -5.49 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 21.50
Evaluated at bid price : 21.50
Bid-YTW : 7.03 %
NA.PR.M Perpetual-Discount -4.76 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 21.20
Evaluated at bid price : 21.20
Bid-YTW : 7.10 %
WFS.PR.A SplitShare -3.75 % Asset coverage of 1.2-:1 as of January 15, according to Mulvihill.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2011-06-30
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.48
Bid-YTW : 12.98 %
BNS.PR.R FixedReset -3.74 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 21.33
Evaluated at bid price : 21.61
Bid-YTW : 4.46 %
FBS.PR.B SplitShare -3.58 % Asset coverage of 1.1-:1 as of January 15 according to TD Securities.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2011-12-15
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 7.81
Bid-YTW : 14.60 %
GWO.PR.H Perpetual-Discount -3.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 16.81
Evaluated at bid price : 16.81
Bid-YTW : 7.32 %
SLF.PR.A Perpetual-Discount -2.86 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 16.28
Evaluated at bid price : 16.28
Bid-YTW : 7.40 %
SLF.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -2.66 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 15.38
Evaluated at bid price : 15.38
Bid-YTW : 7.34 %
PWF.PR.H Perpetual-Discount -2.43 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 20.49
Evaluated at bid price : 20.49
Bid-YTW : 7.07 %
RY.PR.L FixedReset -2.35 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 24.08
Evaluated at bid price : 24.12
Bid-YTW : 4.89 %
BNA.PR.C SplitShare -2.27 % Asset coverage of 1.8+:1 as of December 31 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2019-01-10
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 10.75
Bid-YTW : 16.32 %
GWO.PR.G Perpetual-Discount -2.16 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 18.11
Evaluated at bid price : 18.11
Bid-YTW : 7.28 %
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -2.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 17.91
Evaluated at bid price : 17.91
Bid-YTW : 7.05 %
CM.PR.K FixedReset -1.94 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 22.11
Evaluated at bid price : 22.75
Bid-YTW : 4.63 %
ELF.PR.G Perpetual-Discount -1.94 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 15.20
Evaluated at bid price : 15.20
Bid-YTW : 7.90 %
BCE.PR.I FixedFloater -1.84 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 16.01
Bid-YTW : 6.97 %
HSB.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -1.82 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 17.23
Evaluated at bid price : 17.23
Bid-YTW : 7.51 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount -1.81 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 16.28
Evaluated at bid price : 16.28
Bid-YTW : 7.27 %
ELF.PR.F Perpetual-Discount -1.79 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 15.91
Evaluated at bid price : 15.91
Bid-YTW : 8.43 %
FTN.PR.A SplitShare -1.74 % Asset coverage of 1.4-:1 as of January 15, according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2015-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 7.89
Bid-YTW : 9.67 %
TD.PR.A FixedReset -1.73 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 22.66
Evaluated at bid price : 22.70
Bid-YTW : 4.32 %
RY.PR.I FixedReset -1.71 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 22.96
Evaluated at bid price : 23.00
Bid-YTW : 4.37 %
TD.PR.C FixedReset -1.63 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 24.11
Evaluated at bid price : 24.15
Bid-YTW : 4.84 %
SLF.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -1.58 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 15.55
Evaluated at bid price : 15.55
Bid-YTW : 7.26 %
BNS.PR.P FixedReset -1.51 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 22.77
Evaluated at bid price : 22.85
Bid-YTW : 4.31 %
ALB.PR.A SplitShare -1.40 % Asset coverage of 1.2-:1 as of January 15 according to Scotia Managed Companies.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2011-02-28
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 19.75
Bid-YTW : 16.99 %
GWO.PR.F Perpetual-Discount -1.36 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 21.70
Evaluated at bid price : 21.70
Bid-YTW : 6.89 %
TD.PR.R Perpetual-Discount -1.33 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 20.80
Evaluated at bid price : 20.80
Bid-YTW : 6.78 %
CM.PR.J Perpetual-Discount -1.31 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 15.79
Evaluated at bid price : 15.79
Bid-YTW : 7.18 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -1.27 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 17.83
Evaluated at bid price : 17.83
Bid-YTW : 6.62 %
SLF.PR.E Perpetual-Discount -1.27 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 15.61
Evaluated at bid price : 15.61
Bid-YTW : 7.31 %
BMO.PR.H Perpetual-Discount -1.23 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 20.00
Evaluated at bid price : 20.00
Bid-YTW : 6.76 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet -1.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 17.05
Bid-YTW : 11.15 %
BNS.PR.M Perpetual-Discount -1.21 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 17.20
Evaluated at bid price : 17.20
Bid-YTW : 6.59 %
TRI.PR.B Floater -1.16 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 11.05
Evaluated at bid price : 11.05
Bid-YTW : 4.79 %
SBC.PR.A SplitShare -1.10 % Asset coverage of 1.4+:1 as of January 15 according to Brompton Group.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2012-11-30
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.11
Bid-YTW : 11.58 %
PWF.PR.L Perpetual-Discount -1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 18.25
Evaluated at bid price : 18.25
Bid-YTW : 7.04 %
PWF.PR.M FixedReset 1.02 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 24.62
Evaluated at bid price : 24.67
Bid-YTW : 5.29 %
TCA.PR.Y Perpetual-Discount 1.12 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 43.37
Evaluated at bid price : 44.15
Bid-YTW : 6.36 %
NA.PR.N FixedReset 1.20 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 21.96
Evaluated at bid price : 22.01
Bid-YTW : 4.59 %
LFE.PR.A SplitShare 1.50 % Asset coverage of 1.5-:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2012-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 9.47
Bid-YTW : 6.97 %
CU.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.64 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 22.66
Evaluated at bid price : 22.87
Bid-YTW : 6.68 %
FFN.PR.A SplitShare 3.06 % Asset coverage of 1.1+:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2014-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 7.75
Bid-YTW : 10.67 %
PPL.PR.A SplitShare 4.00 % Asset coverage of 1.4+:1 as of January 15 according to the company.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2012-12-01
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 8.85
Bid-YTW : 8.64 %
BAM.PR.N Perpetual-Discount 4.51 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 11.83
Evaluated at bid price : 11.83
Bid-YTW : 10.23 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
PWF.PR.J OpRet 201,898 Nesbitt crossed 200,000 at 25.05.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2013-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.00
Bid-YTW : 4.70 %
BNS.PR.T FixedReset 193,491 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 24.95
Evaluated at bid price : 25.00
Bid-YTW : 5.92 %
RY.PR.P FixedReset 108,295 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 24.96
Evaluated at bid price : 25.01
Bid-YTW : 5.96 %
TD.PR.M OpRet 71,341 Anonymous bought two blocks of 25,000 shares each from Desjardins at 26.00.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2013-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.90
Bid-YTW : 3.86 %
RY.PR.I FixedReset 61,273 Nesbitt crossed 25,000 shares at 23.10.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-01-22
Maturity Price : 22.96
Evaluated at bid price : 23.00
Bid-YTW : 4.37 %
IGM.PR.A OpRet 59,249 Nesbitt crossed 50,000 at 25.50.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2013-06-29
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.40
Bid-YTW : 5.47 %
There were 35 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

STW.PR.A: Capital Units' Distribution Cut

Thursday, January 22nd, 2009

STRATA Income Fund has announced:

Based upon a review of various factors, we have reduced the distribution for STRATA Income Fund (the “Fund”) to $0.05 per capital unit payable on February 13, 2009 to unitholders of record on January 31, 2009. Among the more important considerations were distribution cuts by a number of oil and gas royalty trusts in response to the recent correction in oil and gas prices, the global economic slowdown including its impact on corporate revenues and earnings, and corporate conversions accompanied by distribution cuts by a number of income trusts. These factors have caused COMPASS Income Fund (“COMPASS”), the sole underlying investment of the Fund, to reduce its distributions and STRATA to follow suit.

Notwithstanding the current challenging economic environment, we believe there are some very positive developments occurring which we shall consider in determining future distribution levels of COMPASS and of the Fund. More specifically, Middlefield’s oil and gas consultant, Groppe Long and Littell, is currently forecasting a significant recovery in energy prices with crude oil expected to average US$85 per barrel in 2009. In addition, we expect that the various economic stimulus packages and interest rate cuts will begin to take effect in the second half of 2009, thereby improving business prospects.

It should be noted that the Fund will be maturing on November 30, 2009, at which time the preferred securities, which are currently yielding 6.0% per annum, will be repaid in full at the original subscription price of $10.00 plus accrued interest. In addition, those holding STRATA capital units will have the option to receive the net asset value at maturity or exchange their capital units for units of COMPASS.

The capital units and the preferred securities trade on the Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbols STW.UN and STW.PR.A, respectively.

STW.PR.A was last mentioned on PrefBlog when its Stealth Redemption was confirmed. STW.PR.A is tracked by HIMIPref™ and is included in the HIMIPref™ InterestBearing subindex

SNH.PR.U to Mature on Schedule

Thursday, January 22nd, 2009

SNP Health Split Corp. has announced:

The Capital Shares and Preferred Shares will be redeemed by the Company on February 11, 2009 in accordance with the redemption provisions of the shares. Pursuant to these provisions, the Preferred Shares will be redeemed at a price per share equal to the lesser of $25.00 and the Net Asset Value per Unit. The Capital Shares will be redeemed at a price equal to the amount (for every two capital shares) by which the Net Asset Value per Unit exceeds $25.00.

The NAVPU is $28.70 as of January 15 according to Scotia Managed Companies. Not a very successful split corporation as far as the capital unitholders are concerned … capital units were issued at $11.15. On the bright side, though, I might use the handy graph of performance as an illustration of the difference between preferreds and capital!

SNH.PR.U was last mentioned on PrefBlog when it was downgraded to Pfd-5(high) by DBRS. SNH.PR.U is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

The Rising Cost of Make-Believe: BNS Sub-Debt Issue

Thursday, January 22nd, 2009

Scotia has announced:

that it has completed the domestic offering of $1 billion of 6.65% Subordinated Debentures due 2021 (the “Debentures”). The Debentures will qualify as Tier 2B capital of the Bank for regulatory purposes and are part of Scotiabank’s ongoing and proactive management of its capital structure.

The prospectus supplement is available on SEDAR, dated January 19:

The Debentures offered by this prospectus supplement will be dated January 22, 2009 and will mature on January 22, 2021. Interest on such Debentures at the rate of 6.65% per annum will be payable in equal semi-annual payments in arrears on January 22 and July 22 in each year, commencing July 22, 2009 and continuing until January 22, 2016.

The initial interest payment, payable on July 22, 2009, will be $33.25 per $1,000 principal amount of Debentures, based on an anticipated closing date of January 22, 2009. From January 22, 2016 until maturity on January 22, 2021, interest on such Debentures will be payable at an annual rate equal to the 90-day Bankers’ Acceptance Rate (as defined herein) plus 5.85% payable quarterly in arrears on the 22nd day of each of April, July, October and January in each year, commencing April 22, 2016.

A penalty rate of BAs+585! Note 12 of the Scotia 2008 Annual Report lists an issue with a pretend-maturity of 2009-5-12, real maturity in 2014, penalty rate of BAs+100bp.

Three month BAs are recorded by the Bank of Canada at 0.96% as of 1/21.

BoC Releases Monetary Policy Report Update

Thursday, January 22nd, 2009

The Bank of Canada has announced that it has released the January 2009 Update to the Monetary Policy Report:

The anticipated normalization of financial conditions, together with the stimulus coming from monetary and fiscal policies, should boost the growth of consumer spending in 2010. Exports are also expected to recover next year as the U.S. economy strengthens and the past depreciation of the Canadian dollar stimulates foreign demand. Excess supply will be gradually reduced, with the economy projected to return to balance by mid-2011. The projected return to balance of the Canadian economy is faster than either of the recoveries following the 1981–82 and 1990–92 recessions (Chart 7). In contrast to these earlier episodes, with an explicit 2 per cent inflation target since 1991 and expectations of inflation well anchored to this target, monetary policy has been able to react in a timely and significant way to help offset the economic downturn and promote conditions to support recovery. In addition, Canada enters this recession with greater fiscal flexibility and stronger corporate balance sheets than in the recession of the 1990s.

It would appear – so far! – that our current recession is unremarkable in terms of either severity or interval since the last one of note. Which, I trust, will explain my anger at the length of time it will take for Spend-Every-Penny’s good-times budgets to cover the projected cost of this rough period.

If we’re lucky, next week’s budget will include a credible projection of how much this recession will cost – including stimulus measures – together with a credible plan of tax increases – effective now – that will pay for it in the ten to fifteen years following recovery. My bet? We won’t be lucky.