Archive for December, 2009

DBRS Redefines "Default"

Monday, December 21st, 2009

DBRS has issued a press release, DBRS Clarifies its Approach to Rating Bank Subordinated Debt and Hybrid Instruments.

I love the word “clarifies”. It should mean “make clearer” or “resolve ambiguity”, but is nowadays used by smiley-boys to mean “changing our position while hoping you don’t notice”.

The interesting bits are as follows:

DBRS does not view the ability to defer payments as a credit risk, but rather, a risk that holders of the deferrable instruments have agreed to as per the contractual terms of the instrument and DBRS does not consider “deferral” as being equal to “default”.

Notching for Deferral or Skipping of Payments

DBRS will add an additional notch when instruments with discretionary payments defer or skip. This notch will be applied as long as discretionary payments are not being made. This additional notch serves to differentiate between instruments that are still making payments from those that are not paying, but otherwise meeting the instrument’s terms and covenants. As noted already, DBRS does not view the exercising of the right to defer or skip payments as equivalent to default. Typically, a bank that defers or skips discretionary payments is usually in significant difficulty, so that its senior debt rating is already under pressure and its rating has likely been lowered. That results in lower ratings for subordinated debt. Recent examples, however, have illustrated occasions when a bank may defer or skip due to regulatory events, but retain significant strength and remain investment grade. In these circumstances, the senior debt rating remains the principal driver of the likelihood that payments will be resumed and insolvency avoided.

This represents something of a change from their treatment of Quebecor World:

While the cumulative nature of the Series 3 and Series 5 preferred shares affords Quebecor World the flexibility to suspend dividends, provided dividends are paid in arrears, DBRS notes preferred shareholders maintain a level of expectation that these dividends will be paid in a timely manner, and this expectation is reflected in the preferred share ratings. Having not met the expectation of preferred shareholders, DBRS notes the preferred shares are more reflective of a “D” rating.

What’s right or wrong? There is, of course, no right or wrong.

DBRS is definitely in the wrong, though, for changing their policy under the banner of “clarification” and for not specifying just what does constitute a default under their terminology. When does a Straight Perpetual default? Not when it skips a payment, under the new policy. So when? When it enters CCCA protection? When it’s written down or otherwise has its claim on assets extinguished? When?

Securitization: BIS Examines New Century Capital

Monday, December 21st, 2009

The Bank for International Settlements has released a working paper by Allen B Frankel titled The risk of relying on reputational capital: a case study of the 2007 failure of New Century Financial:

The quality of newly originated subprime mortgages had been visibly deteriorating for some time before the window for such loans was shut in 2007. Nevertheless, a bankruptcy court’s directed ex post examination of New Century Financial, one of the largest originators of subprime mortgages, discovered no change, over time, in how that firm went about its business. This paper employs the court examiner’s findings in a critical review of the procedures used by various agents involved in the origination and securitisation of subprime mortgages. A contribution of this paper is its elaboration of the choices and incentives faced by the various types of institutions involved in those linked processes of origination and securitisation. It highlights the limited roles played by the originators of subprime loans in screening borrowers and in bearing losses on defective loans that had been sold to securitisers of pooled loan packages (ie, mortgage-backed securities). It also illustrates the willingness of the management of those institutions that became key players in that market to put their reputations with fixed-income investor clients in jeopardy. What is perplexing is that such risk exposures were accepted by investing firms that had the wherewithal and knowledge to appreciate the overall paucity of due diligence in the loan origination processes. This observation, in turn, points to the conclusion that the subprime episode is a case in which reputational capital, a presumptively effective motivator of market discipline, was not an effective incentive device.

The end of the road for New Century came when:

Purchasers of New Century’s loan production normally conducted a due diligence examination after a sales agreement had been reached. The investor, or a due diligence firm hired by the investor, would review loan files to determine whether the loan was underwritten according to the pool’s guidelines. Loans not meeting guidelines could be excluded from the loan bundle (kicked out) and returned to the originator.

Once kicked out, the mortgages were known as a “scratch and dent” (S&D) loans, which were purchased by specialised investors at a large discount to their principal balance. Consequently, one measure of the deterioration of the quality of New Century’s loan production is the percentage of S&D loan sales. In 2004 and 2005, such sales amounted to less than 0.5% of New Century’s secondary market transactions. By contrast, in the first three quarters of 2006, S&D loan sales accounted for 2.1% of such transactions (Missal (2008, p. 68)).

The upsurge in loan repurchase requests to New Century coincided with a change in the methodology employed to estimate its allowance for loan repurchase losses. New Century’s board learned of the change after a considerable delay. This discovery was followed, after a few days, by a public announcement on 7 February 2007 that New Century’s results for the three quarters of 2006 needed to be restated. It also noted an expectation that losses would continue due to heightened early payment default (EPD) rates.

New Century’s announcement prompted margin calls by many of its warehouse lenders and requests for accelerated loan repurchases. Soon, all of New Century’s warehouse lenders ceased providing new funding. Because simultaneous margin calls by its warehouse lenders could not be met, New Century filed for bankruptcy on April 2, 2007. It ceased to originate mortgages and entered into an agreement to sell off its loan servicing businesses.

Amusingly, in the light of the current bonus hysteria:

The examiner’s access to internal New Century documents provided valuable insights into how the appearance of the warning flags influenced, or did not influence, management. For example, the examiner could find no reference to loan quality in the internal documents that described New Century’s bonus compensation system for regional managers for 2005 and 2006 (Missal (2008, p. 147)). The examiner says that the compensation of New Century’s loan production executives was directly and solely related to the amount of mortgage loans originated, loans that, in turn, were subsequently sold or securitised.32 Likewise, the examiner found no mention of penalties (reduced commission payments to loan production staff) that would be assessed against defective loans that required price discounts for secondary market sale.

Heightened investor concerns about the performance of subprime loans were reflected in changes in their due diligence processes (Missal (2008, p. 165)). Historically, investors would ask due diligence firms to examine, on their behalf, only a small sample of loans in a particular pool. The character of the process first changed in 2006 when most investors began to look at the appraisal documents in all loan files in a loan pool. Investors then increased the share of loan files examined. This intensification of due diligence efforts was responsible for a sharp increase in New Century’s kickout rate from 6.9% in January 2006 to 14.95% in December 2006 (Missal (2008, p. 161)).

The author concludes:

The examiner’s report suggests that some of the actions undertaken to improve loan quality in late 2006 and early 2007 were designed to anticipate new credit risk concerns among New Century’s counterparties. Nonetheless, when New Century announced a need to recast its financial reports, there had not yet been a defection by any of its largest counterparties. Not surprisingly, defections ensued immediately after the announcement. In those circumstances, the bunching of defections probably signalled an absence of attention on the part of counterparties to the mounting risks of ongoing transactions with New Century. In turn, the evidence of ineffective counterparty risk management has led to concerns about the effectiveness of existing governance structures (corporate and regulatory) and, in particular, reputational capital as an incentive device. Can those structures now be relied on to discipline the risk-taking incentives of those involved in underwriting securities backed by subprime (and other risky) assets?

Econbrowser's Plan to Fix the Financial System

Sunday, December 20th, 2009

James Hamilton of Econbrowser has republished a paper he wrote for the UCSD Economics Department’s Economics in Action, with the title What Went Wrong and How Can We Fix It?.

He makes a few assertions which I dispute:

The institutions that originally made the loans sold them off to private banks or to the government-sponsored enterprises Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. This system created moral hazard incentives for the originators, encouraging them to fund unsound loans. When private banks bought the loans, they packaged them into complex securities that were in turn sold off to private investors, an additional step that permitted the securitizers to profit, even if the loans were poor quality.

Increased regulation of securitization is certainly a very sexy issue nowadays, and it appears that tranche retention of some kind will be mandated in the future. Why not? It’s a nice simple story, easily understood by the man in the street and makes it look as if regulators are Taking Action. But does it mean anything?

The UK’s Financial System Authority says, in its Financial Risk Outlook 2009 (previously reported on PrefBlog:

Hence, the new model of securitised credit intermediation was not solely or indeed primarily one of originate and distribute. Rather, credit intermediation passed through multiple trading books in banks, leading to a proliferation of relationships within the financial sector. This ‘acquire and arbitrage’ model resulted in the majority of incurred losses falling on banks and investment banks involved in risky maturity transformation activities, rather than investors outside the banking system. This explosion of claims within the financial system resulted in financial sector balance sheets becoming of greater consequence to the economy. Financial sector assets and liabilities in the US and the UK grew far more rapidly as a proportion of GDP than those of corporates and households (see Chart A7 and A8).

There’s a good chart … somewhere, produced by somebody … that conveys this information in visual form, but I can’t remember where I saw it!

Anyway … since that’s what happened, what good is mandated tranche retention going to do? The banks collectively believed in their collective product and held it. If it had, in fact, been forced down the throat of poor innocent pension funds because the banks considered it a hot potato, we’d have a global pension fund solvency crisis right now and we don’t – at least, not much worse than usual.

Additionally, tranche retention is simply another excuse for the lazy not to do any work. Seems to me that if you’re buying a billion dollars worth of mortgages, maybe you should have a look at what you’re buying, regardless of whether the seller holds a 5% tranche or not. But perhaps I’m just old-fashioned that way.

I also feel Dr. Hamilton’s statement regarding AIG is imprecise, while not being incorrect:

Entities like the insurance giant AIG were allowed to write huge volumes of credit default swaps that purportedly would insure the holders of these mortgages against losses, even though AIG did not remotely have the financial ability to fulfill all the commitments it made

The issue is not that AIG wrote so much protection, but that regulators allowed banks that held it to offset risky positions without collateralization (in fact, the only financial institution with enough brains to demand collateralization, Goldman Sachs, is regularly vilified for doing so in the gutter blogs).

Regardless of one’s views on whether a central clearing house for derivatives is a good idea (I don’t think it is), it should be apparent that the driving force behind the idea is a regulatory smokescreen. Fully collateralized, so what? The regulators could have demanded full collateralization a long, long time ago – and should have: any uncollateralized exposure should have soaked up the exposed bank’s capital – but they didn’t.

I think he misses a point about Fannie and Freddie:

In the cases of Fannie and Freddie, the government created an asymmetric payoff structure in which the profits went to private investors while the losses were picked up by the taxpayers.

True enough, but that’s not the whole problem; perhaps not even the real problem. Fannie & Freddie depressed mortgage rates due to their implicit government guarantee. When Agency paper trades right on top of Treasury’s, what profit is left for private enterprise? It’s fairly well accepted at this point that one reason why Canadian banks have been so resilient is because they can earn economically satisfactory returns by holding residential mortgages (see IMF Commentary and OSFI commentary, as well as commentary on Australian banks) – they didn’t need to reach for yield.

BoE Releases December 2009 Financial Stability Report

Saturday, December 19th, 2009

The Bank of Engand has released the December 2009 Financial Stability Report, with the usual tip-top analysis.

The first chart puts things into perspective: the UK is a smaller economy than the US or the Continent:

Who but the Old Lady of Threadneedle Street would dare produce an equity returns graph dating back to 1693?

UK banks are strongly encouraged to sell equity:

Despite inevitable short-term costs, there is a strong case for banks acting now to improve balance sheet positions while conditions are favourable. Retaining a higher share of current buoyant earnings could significantly increase banks’ resilience and ability to lend. If discretionary distributions had been 20% lower per year between 2000 and 2008, banks would have generated around £75 billion of additional capital — more than provided by the public sector during the crisis. It is also an opportune time for banks to raise capital externally, extend the maturity of their funding, and develop and implement plans for refinancing substantial sums as official sector support is withdrawn.

The bank is also throwing its weight behind Contingent Capital and leverage caps:

Capital buffers will need to rise, possibly substantially, over the coming years. The quality of banks’ capital also needs to improve. To absorb losses, capital should comprise equity or instruments that convert to equity automatically under pre-defined conditions. To avoid excessive reliance on refined regulatory risk weights, risk-based capital requirements should be accompanied by a mandatory maximum leverage ratio (Box 6).

They’ve done some work to see how much capital should be required going forward:

On average, a pre-crisis Tier 1 capital ratio of around 8.5% would have been needed by banks in the sample to avoid going below a Tier 1 capital ratio of 4% during the crisis (Chart A). Minimum capital requirements are likely to be higher in the future.

A feature of this analysis is the wide variation in results across banks, shown by the distributions in Chart A. Banks with similar pre-crisis Tier 1 capital ratios faced different outcomes in some cases. Even if all banks in the sample had a pre-crisis capital ratio of 8.5%, 40% of the banks would still have breached the 4% Tier 1 capital ratio in-crisis. The highest pre-crisis Tier 1 capital ratio that would have been needed across the sample of banks to maintain a 4% Tier 1 capital ratio in-crisis is around 18%. This variation across banks suggests the need for flexibility in their future capital structure and potentially a higher average buffer. In principle, this could be achieved through greater use of contingent capital (see Section 3).

Oddly, they have a chart decomposing credit spreads according to the BoC methodology, which I dislike, as opposed to the Webber & Churm methodology used in the past:

There is no explanation in the report regarding the change.

There are big problems with loan-to-value ratios on commercial property … or there would be if they were recognized!

The sharp declines in capital values have triggered breaches of loan to value (LTV) covenants, with some loans in negative equity. Estimates from the Property Industry Alliance (PIA) suggest that average LTVs could reach 114% by end-2010.

As well as causing covenant breaches, declines in values (and rises in LTVs) will also have reduced firms’ access to credit by reducing the value of the commercial property that they might use as collateral for secured borrowing. Market contacts suggest that banks have been willing, to date, to show forbearance in respect of breaches of LTV covenants. In addition, research by De Montfort University suggests that, while loans are still performing, some lenders have not sought to revalue underlying properties. As a result, the sharp declines in capital values alone had a fairly limited impact on banks.

Footnote: The PIA is an alliance of five property bodies — the British Council for Offices, British Council of Shopping Centres, British Property Federation, Investment Property Forum and Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors.

Many will find the commentary on the composition of Tier 1 Capital interesting, particularly given the Canadian limits following OSFI’s debasement of bank capital:

Ahead of the crisis, the composition of banks’ capital shifted away from common equity and reserves (core Tier 1 capital) towards lower-quality instruments (Chart 3.4). Experience during the crisis in the United Kingdom and elsewhere has revealed that these instruments were not always able to absorb losses for going-concern banks.

There is now broad agreement internationally that equity and reserves should form a much larger part of banks’ capital in the future. The Bank believes that no instrument should be classified as going-concern capital if it does not have the same loss-absorbing characteristics as common equity. In practice, this means either that the principal of the instrument can be written down at the same time and to the same extent as common equity, or that the instrument is convertible into equity — so-called ‘contingent capital’.

And now we’re getting into the meaty bit! Contingent Capital is a vital concept for preferred shareholders: I am convinced that the preferred share as we know it is dead; it will all be contingent at some point in the future. Bet a nickel.

On what terms private non-bank investors would be willing to provide such insurance remains unclear. For example, investor appetite may initially be restricted if these instruments are excluded from benchmark indices or are not permitted under certain investment mandates. If, over time, an investor base for such instruments did not develop, this would provide a useful signal that debt investors were unwilling to accept losses on their investments in banks. For contingent capital instruments to be loss-absorbing, their design needs careful consideration. In this respect, the definition of the conversion trigger is crucial. Contingent capital would need to convert automatically, or at the discretion of the regulator, rather than on the initiative of the issuer. Setting the trigger involves balancing the risk of conversion too soon (before capital is needed) and too late (when funding problems may already have emerged). The acceptable level of contingent capital within banks’ capital structure also needs to be considered carefully. Too much convertible debt could increase the risk of a bank equity price ‘death spiral’ — whereby investors may short-sell the stock in anticipation of dilution as the trigger for conversion comes closer.

This constant harping on regulatory discretion really gets on my wick. In a crisis, the pronouncement by a regulator that Bank X is sufficiently endangered that it needs to trigger conversion will be a death sentence. Conversion needs to be automatic, predictable and hedgeable: as I have argued countless times, these conditions are met by setting a trigger-and-conversion price at the time of issue of the non-equity capital (maybe 50% of issue-time common price for Tier 1; 25% for Tier 2). If the common price falls below the trigger price (on a well-defined exchange in a well defined way for a well defined period) then the contingent capital converts at that particular trigger price. Holders who wish to hedge will be able to buy options with their income payments … alternatively, options players may wish to buy the CoCo from the existent holders in order to get the embedded option; this will depend on the market price of the CoCo.

Death Spirals are not an issue if the conversion price is fixed; and become less important as a minimum coversion price increases (e.g., in Canadian Operating Retractible issues, the minimum conversion price is $2, which prevented the IQW.PR.C conversion from becoming a death spiral … although it ultimately made no difference).

The BoE states flatly:

The Bank would support the introduction of a leverage ratio
and this being hard-wired into regulatory rules through Pillar 1, provided that it can be well defined. It will be difficult to set a single standard applicable across different business models and accounting regimes, but it is important to achieve consistent implementation across jurisdictions.

… which, I think, can be taken at face value. Given the tenor of the rest of their discussion, I don’t think they intend to invent problems regarding implementation specifics to mask a distaste for the idea.

I’m not so enthralled with the following:

In a recent Discussion Paper (DP), the Bank contributed to emerging ideas on how such a macroprudential regime could be made operational.(2)
The DP examined the possibility of applying time-varying capital surcharges on banks to dampen cyclical exuberance (the orange bars in the stylised example in Chart 3.13). Raising capital requirements in a credit boom would offer greater self-insurance for the financial system against a subsequent bust. It could also provide incentives for banks to restrain exuberant lending by raising its marginal cost. In addition, the DP suggested that capital surcharges could be imposed on firms to better reflect their individual contribution to systemic risk (the magenta bars in Chart 3.13). These would be based on factors such as firms’ size, complexity, interconnectedness and propensity to cause losses to others through asset fire sales. The key objective would be to lower the probability of default of banks whose failure would impose a large spillover cost on the financial system. Systemic surcharges could also provide incentives for banks to alter their balance sheets or business models, supporting structural initiatives in this area (see Section 3.2).

I don’t support the nod-and-wink model of regulation by any means, and the proposals to give regulators discretion in such matters will only enhance the attractiveness of regulatory capture. Counter-cyclical requirements, yes: have a surcharge on asset growth over the past 5-10 years. Systemic surcharges, yes: have a surcharge on a progressive schedule based on risk-weighte assets. Regulatory discretion? No. Not only can’t the regulators be trusted with that degree of power (NOBODY can be trusted with that degree of power), but it raises the spectre of single-point failure even higher and will make the regulators the mutual plaything of the banks and politicians.

The next part is good. In Canada, we denigrate the shadow-banking sector:

With these objectives in mind, HM Treasury has announced that it intends to publish a discussion paper on developing non-bank lending channels in the United Kingdom, drawing on advice from the FSA and the Bank.(1) Key issues to be considered include identifying necessary improvements to market infrastructure that will help corporate borrowers to access non-bank investors.

One thing I haven’t seen before is the proposal to treat all retail deposits as covered bonds:

One way of ensuring continuity of payment services could be to require banks to invest retail deposits solely in risk-free assets such as government bonds — an approach commonly referred to as ‘narrow banking’. A number of commentators have put forward proposals along these lines in response to the crisis.(1) This could be seen as an extension of arrangements already in place for private banknotes issued by some Scottish and Northern Irish banks. These banks are required to hold cash or credit balances with the Bank of England fully backing their note issuance. These assets cannot be used for any other purpose and would be excluded — or ‘ring-fenced’ — from any insolvency proceeding and reserved for satisfying the claims of note holders.

An arrangement where retail deposits are backed by risk-free assets need not require the creation of dedicated narrow banks, although this could conceivably occur naturally over time. Existing banks could instead be required to segregate their retail deposit books and the assets backing them within their internal structures. The segregated part of a bank would effectively be subject to a 100% liquidity requirement, and would need to be easily extractable from the wider group using available resolution tools. In this way, the integrity of the payment system would be assured, while still allowing banks to exploit economies of scope between payment services and other types of banking activity.

Regulation FD Under Attack

Saturday, December 19th, 2009

In my essay Credit Ratings: Investors in a Bind I argued that the NRSRO exemption to Regulation FD be repealed.

This exemption may be summarized as

Regulation FD requires that an issuer, or any person acting on its behalf, publicly disclose material nonpublic information if the information is disclosed to certain specified persons. Currently, one exception to this requirement is disclosure of information to an entity whose primary business is the issuance of credit ratings, so long as the information is disclosed solely for the purpose of developing a rating and the entity’s ratings are publicly available.

The fact that credit rating agencies have access to material non-public information that you or I would go to jail for possessing can lead to considerable second-guessing when evaluating the credit quality of any given issue or issuer; encouraging an over-reliance by investors on credit rating agencies and increasing the degree of financial instability inherent in the system (by encouraging cliff-risk through market reaction to downgrades and other difficulties caused by exposure to single-point failure).

The author of the above summary, Charles A. Sweet of Bingham McCutchen LLP goes on to advise, in his post In an Effort to Encourage Unsolicited Ratings, SEC Requires Disclosure of All Information Provided to NRSROs Hired to Provide Credit Ratings; Also Adopts and Proposes Various New Disclosure Requirements for NRSROs:

The SEC has adopted, substantially as proposed, an expansion of this provision to permit the disclosure of material nonpublic information to NRSROs even if their ratings are not public. According to the SEC, this change will accommodate both subscriber-based NRSROs that do not make their ratings publicly available for free, as well as NRSROs that access information under the new disclosure rules but which do not ultimately issue a rating.

… which is great news, but not as good as the information passed on by Jim Hamilton of Jim Hamilton’s World of Securities Regulation in his post House Passes Historic Financial Overhaul Legislation:

The House of Representatives passed historic legislation today overhauling the US financial regulatory system.

The SEC is directed to revise Regulation FD to remove from FD the exemption for entities whose primary business is the issuance of credit ratings (Section 6007).

Let’s just hope that this part of the legislation, anyway, becomes law … next stop, National Policy 51-201!

Larry MacDonald Looks at DFN / DFN.PR.A

Saturday, December 19th, 2009

In a two part post, Canadian Business Online columnist Larry MacDonald took a look at the DFN Capital Shares and the DFN.PR.A Preferred Shares; he was kind enough to quote me in the latter post.

DFN.PR.A was last mentioned on PrefBlog when the company announced that its rights offering was 47% subscribed. DFN.PR.A is tracked by HIMIPref™ but is relegated to the Scraps subindex on credit concerns.

Update, 2009-12-29: Mr. MacDonald recycled my comments for a non-public piece published by TD Webbroker titled Looking for Income Yield?

December 18, 2009

Friday, December 18th, 2009

Deutsche Bank is marching to a different drummer – worrying about competition, of all things!:

Deutsche Bank AG, Germany’s biggest bank, plans to spread the costs of the U.K. bonus tax to all employees worldwide, risking a backlash from bankers outside of London.

Chief Executive Officer Josef Ackermann, in an interview with the Financial Times, said the bank wouldn’t restrict the cost of the tax to the U.K. bonus pool.

“We will clearly globalize it,” Ackermann said. “If parts are paid out of the bonus pool, we would seek to globalize it. It would be unfair to treat the U.K. bankers differently.”

Ackermann told the Financial Times today that governments shouldn’t interfere in setting pay, saying bonuses should be the result of “supply and demand for skilled people.”

The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland has published the December edition of Economic Trends. The article on “Supply and Demand Shocks in Residential Mortgages” was interesting, although not noteworthy enough to merit a dedicated post.

A solid, though hardly spectacular, day for preferreds today, with PerpetualDiscounts up 9bp and FixedResets gaining 3bp. This is the eighth consecutive day of gains for FixedResets and they’re up about 78bp on the month-to-date. Volume was good; it should slow down next week, but the pending settlement of the YPG new FixedReset should give the traders something to do.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.4886 % 1,570.9
FixedFloater 5.66 % 3.81 % 42,379 19.03 1 0.0000 % 2,750.7
Floater 2.50 % 2.93 % 101,327 19.91 3 0.4886 % 1,962.5
OpRet 4.85 % -8.55 % 131,339 0.09 15 0.1173 % 2,320.8
SplitShare 6.44 % -4.88 % 240,424 0.08 2 0.0222 % 2,085.2
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1173 % 2,122.2
Perpetual-Premium 5.88 % 5.83 % 81,802 2.33 7 -0.0909 % 1,877.5
Perpetual-Discount 5.78 % 5.83 % 198,878 14.06 68 0.0905 % 1,799.5
FixedReset 5.40 % 3.68 % 350,809 3.87 41 0.0330 % 2,164.9
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
IAG.PR.C FixedReset -1.73 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.25
Bid-YTW : 3.77 %
BAM.PR.P FixedReset 1.03 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.35
Bid-YTW : 4.79 %
PWF.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 1.41 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-12-18
Maturity Price : 24.01
Evaluated at bid price : 24.38
Bid-YTW : 5.98 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
IGM.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 207,679 Inventory blow-out.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-12-18
Maturity Price : 24.10
Evaluated at bid price : 24.29
Bid-YTW : 6.12 %
MFC.PR.D FixedReset 193,911 Desjardins crossed two blocks, of 125,000 and 31,300 shares, both at 28.00.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.89
Bid-YTW : 3.87 %
IGM.PR.A OpRet 102,098 Called for redemption.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.67
Evaluated at bid price : 25.98
Bid-YTW : 3.31 %
GWO.PR.J FixedReset 53,612 Nesbitt crossed 50,000 at 27.15.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.15
Bid-YTW : 3.67 %
BNS.PR.T FixedReset 43,160 TD crossed 17,100 at 28.00.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-25
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.84
Bid-YTW : 3.71 %
RY.PR.T FixedReset 41,200 RBC crossed 20,000 at 27.80 and 10,000 at 27.90.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-09-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.80
Bid-YTW : 3.80 %
There were 38 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

TIPS Market Microstructure

Friday, December 18th, 2009

The Federal Reserve Bank of New York has published a staff report by Michael J. Fleming and Neel Krishnan title The Microstructure of the TIPS Market. The authors examined the electronic records of inter-dealer broker trading, which provided quotes and trade sizes, everything time-stamped to the second. Nothing particularly useful here, perhaps, but there are some items of interest.

Trading activity for on-the-run TIPS is substantially higher than it is for off-the-run TIPS (Table 3). Daily trading in the on-the-run 10-year note thus averages $137 million, more than six times higher than average trading volume ($22 million) of individual off-the-run 10-year notes. The comparable ratio for the 5-year note is just over three ($87 million versus $27 million) and it is somewhat less than five for the 20-year bond ($30 million versus $6 million). Such on-the-run/off-the-run differentials are just as striking in the nominal market (Fleming (2002), Fabozzi and Fleming (2005), Goldreich, Hanke, and Nath (2005), and Barclay, Hendershott, and Kotz (2006)), reflecting a concentration of liquidity in just a few securities, and in those securities that tend to have the largest floating supplies.

While there is a similar on-the-run/off-the-run divergence in daily trading frequency, such a pattern is not evident in trade size. In fact, average trade sizes are actually slightly higher for off-the-run TIPS.

While bid-ask spreads and quoted depth are similar for on-the-run and off-the-run securities, “quote incidence” is markedly higher for on-the-run securities. Quote incidence gauges the percent of time there are two-sided quotes in a security (that is, both a posted bid price and a posted offer price). This proportion averages close to 60% for the on-the-run 10-year note (during New York trading hours, defined as 7:30 a.m. to 5 p.m.), but only about 15% for any given off-the-run 10-year note. That is, for off-the-run 10-year notes, there is a one-sided quote, or no quote, about 85% of the time.

There are pronounced day-of-week effects in trading activity in the TIPS market, as there are in the nominal market. In particular, trading volume is lowest on Monday, averaging $424 million, highest on Wednesday and Thursday, averaging $615 and $658 million, respectively, with Tuesday and Friday in between, at $552 and $546 million, respectively. These patterns remain when controlling for the announcements examined in this paper.

Market Timing by Issuers

Friday, December 18th, 2009

The Bank of Canada has released Discussion Paper 2009-14 by Jonathan Witmer, Market Timing of Long-Term Debt Issuance:

The literature on market timing of long-term debt issuance yields mixed evidence that managers can successfully time their debt-maturity issuance. The early results that are indicative of debt-maturity timing are not robust to accounting for structural breaks or to other measures of debt maturity from firm-level data that account for call and put provisions in debt contracts. The author applies the analysis from some recent U.S. studies to aggregate Canadian data to determine whether the market-timing results are robust. Although the relation between debt maturity and future excess returns is in the same direction as in the United States, it is not statistically significant. This mixed evidence, combined with the difficulties in interpreting predictive regressions of this nature, provides little support for the notion that firms can effectively reduce their cost of capital by varying the maturity of their debt issuance to take advantage of market conditions. Managers do, however, try to time their debt-maturity issuance, given that long-term corporate debt issuance in both Canada and the United States is negatively related to the term spread.

One possible mechanism of interest is:

An argument against [firms that are successfully timing an inefficient market as an explanation for the relation between future excess long-term bond returns and the long-term share [return]] is that, as a whole, corporate managers should not have inside information on the evolution of future market interest rates, so the evidence that their issuance decisions predict interest rates raises the question as to how firms in the aggregate have some sort of advantage over other sophisticated market participants, such as banks and institutional investors, in recognizing market mispricings. To explain this, Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2009) propose a “gap-filling” theory, whereby corporate issuers act as macro liquidity providers (e.g., by issuing long-term debt) in a segmented bond market where certain groups of investors have fixed maturity preferences for long-term assets.19 Consistent with this theory, they show that corporations issue more long-term debt when the government issues relatively less long-term debt.20 Moreover, they use firm-level data to show that larger firms and firms in better financial position are more likely to engage in “gap filling.” If long-term Treasuries provide a lower expected return when their supply decreases relative to short-term Treasuries,21 this provides an explanation of the apparent ability of corporations’ aggregate issuing characteristics to predict future bond returns.

This would be the flip-side of “crowding out”.

However, the author concludes:

In Canada, the relation between debt maturity and future excess returns is in the same direction as in the United States, but it is not statistically significant. This mixed evidence, combined with the difficulties in interpreting predictive regressions of this nature, provides little support for the notion that firms can effectively reduce their cost of capital by varying the maturity of their debt issuance to take advantage of market conditions. Managers do, however, try to time their debt-maturity issuance, given that longer-term corporate debt issuance in both Canada and the United States is negatively related to the term spread. In the United States, corporations also may be providing liquidity at a macro level, since corporate debt issuance is negatively related to the proportion of government long-term debt outstanding. In Canada, there is less evidence for a relation between these two variables. Hence, while managers are not successful at forecasting future returns, they at least attempt to do so, and changing their maturity structure in such a way could increase the risk of liquidation if managers issue more short-term debt in an attempt to time interest rates. But the increased liquidation risk at the end of the sample period caused by debt-maturity timing is probably minimal, given that Canadian corporations had a long-term share of corporate debt outstanding comparable to historic norms.

One possible mechanism that I was sorry to see not tested or discussed is the idea that managers out-perform the market because they have inside information about their own firms and projects. Under this hypothesis, managers would issue 30-year paper to fund a long-term project simply because the numbers work for them – e.g., future operational profits will exceed the cost of funding (hopefully substantially). Their ability to fund long term profitable projects should, in aggregate, affect macroeconomic spreads and bond returns, since project will be funded when the required yield works, and not funded when it doesn’t.

BIS Reforms Grind One Step Closer

Friday, December 18th, 2009

The Bank for International Settlements has released a consultative document titled Strengthening the resilience of the banking sector, which fleshes out some of the proposals made when the granted most of Treasury’s wish list immediately prior to the last G-20 meeting.

Naturally, the regulators gloss over their own responsibility for the crisis:

One of the main reasons the economic and financial crisis became so severe was that the banking sectors of many countries had built up excessive on- and off-balance sheet leverage. This was accompanied by a gradual erosion of the level and quality of the capital base. At the same time, many banks were holding insufficient liquidity buffers. The banking system therefore was not able to absorb the resulting systemic trading and credit losses nor could it cope with the reintermediation of large off-balance sheet exposures that had built up in the shadow banking system. The crisis was further amplified by a procyclical deleveraging process and by the interconnectedness of systemic institutions through an array of complex transactions. During the most severe episode of the crisis, the market lost confidence in the solvency and liquidity of many banking institutions. The weaknesses in the banking sector were transmitted to the rest of the financial system and the real economy, resulting in a massive contraction of liquidity and credit availability. Ultimately the public sector had to step in with unprecedented injections of liquidity, capital support and guarantees, exposing the taxpayer to large losses.

They emphasize their disdain for Innovative Tier 1 Capital, which has been reflected in the ratings agencies evaluations:

The remainder of the Tier 1 capital base must be comprised of instruments that are subordinated, have fully discretionary noncumulative dividends or coupons and have neither a maturity date nor an incentive to redeem. Innovative hybrid capital instruments with an incentive to redeem through features like step-up clauses, currently limited to 15% of the Tier 1 capital base, will be phased out.

Due to conflicts with the legislation to outlaw income trusts, Canadian IT1C may be cumulative-in-preferred-shares and has a maturity date. It will be most interesting to see how that works out.

Of particular interest is:

The Committee intends to discuss specific proposals at its July 2010 meeting on the role of convertibility, including as a possible entry criterion for Tier 1 and/or Tier 2 to ensure loss absorbency, and on the role of contingent and convertible capital more generally both within the regulatory capital minimum and as buffers.

Contingent Capital is discussed regularly on PrefBlog – I don’t think it’s a matter of “if”, but “when”.

One part is simply crazy:

To address the systemic risk arising from the interconnectedness of banks and other financial institutions through the derivatives markets, the Committee is supporting the efforts of the Committee on Payments and Settlement Systems to establish strong standards for central counterparties and exchanges. Banks’ collateral and mark-to-market exposures to central counterparties meeting these strict criteria will qualify for a zero percent risk weight.

A centralized institution will never fail, eh? I guess that’s because it will never, ever, do any favours for politically well-connected firms, and Iceland was the last sovereign default EVER. I think I know where the next crisis is coming from.

There is also a section on liquidity management, but it does not address a key fault of the Basel II regime: that banks holdings of other banks’ paper is risk-weighted according to the credit of the sovereign supervisor. This ensures that problems accellerate once they start – it’s like holding your unemployment contingency fund in your employer’s stock.

Let us suppose that ABC Corp. issues $1-million in paper to Bank A. Bank A finances by selling some of its paper to Bank B. Bank B has an incentive – due to risk-weighting – to buy Bank A’s paper rather than ABC’s, which makes very little sense.

They’ve finally figured out that step-ups are pretend-maturities:

“Innovative” features such as step-ups, which over time have eroded the quality of Tier 1, will be phased out. The use of call options on Tier 1 capital will be subject to strict governance arrangements which ensure that the issuing bank is not expected to exercise a call on a capital instrument unless it is in its own economic interest to do so. Payments on Tier 1 instruments will also be considered a distribution of earnings under the capital conservation buffer proposal (see Section II.4.c.). This will improve their loss absorbency on a going concern basis by increasing the likelihood that dividends and coupons will be cancelled in times of stress.

Their emphasis on “strict governance” in the above is not credible. They had all the authority they wanted during the crisis to announce that no bank considered to be at risk – or no banks at all – would not be granted permission to redeem. Instead, they rubber-stamped all the pro-forma requests for permission, making it virtually impossible for banks to act in an economically sane fashion (as Deutsche Bank found out). It’s the supervisors who need to clean up their act on this one, not the banks.

I’m pleased by the following statement:

All elements above are net of regulatory adjustments and are subject to the following restrictions:
• Common Equity, Tier 1 Capital and Total Capital must always exceed explicit minima of x%, y% and z% of risk-weighted assets, respectively, to be calibrated following the impact assessment.
• The predominant form of Tier 1 Capital must be Common Equity

I am tempted to refer to the Common Equity ratio as “Tier Zero Capital”, but I have already used that moniker for pre-funded deposit insurance.

Their list of “Criteria for inclusion in Tier 1 Additional Going Concern Capital” is of immense interest, since this will include preferred shares:

8. Dividends/coupons must be paid out of distributable items

11. Instruments classified as liabilities must have principal loss absorption through either
(i) conversion to common shares at an objective pre-specified trigger point or (ii) a
write-down mechanism which allocates losses to the instrument at a pre-specified
trigger point. The write-down will have the following effects:
a. Reduce the claim of the instrument in liquidation;
b. Reduce the amount re-paid when a call is exercised; and
c. Partially or fully reduce coupon/dividend payments on the instrument.

Regretably, they do not provide a definition of “distributable items”. I suspect that this means that preferred dividends may not be considered return of capital and that they must come out of non-negative retained earnings, but it’s not clear.

One interesting thing is:

Minority interest will not be eligible for inclusion in the Common Equity component of Tier 1.

The next quotation has direct impact on Citigroup, particularly:

Deferred tax assets which rely on future profitability of the bank to be realised should be deducted from the Common Equity component of Tier 1. The amount of such assets net of deferred tax liabilities should be deducted.

All in all, the document has a certain amount of high-level interest, but the real meat is yet to come.