Archive for August, 2010

BIS Assesses Effects of Increasing Bank Capitalization

Monday, August 23rd, 2010

This paper was referenced in the recent BoC analysis of capital ratio cost/benefits as the “LEI Report”.

The Bank for International Settlements has released a report titled An assessment of the long-term economic
impact of stronger capital and liquidity requirements
:

This simple mapping yields two key results, with the central tendency across countries measured by the median estimate. First, each 1 percentage point increase in the capital ratio raises loan spreads by 13 basis points. Second, the additional cost of meeting the liquidity standard amounts to around 25 basis points in lending spreads when risk-weighted assets (RWA) are left unchanged; however, it drops to 14 basis points or less after taking account of the fall in RWA and the corresponding lower regulatory capital needs associated with the higher holdings of low-risk assets.

Their approach relies heavily on the theory that output losses due to bank crises may be ascribed entirely to the crisis (although they do acknowledge that “that factors unrelated to banking crises, and not well controlled for in these studies, may also influence the output losses observed in the data.”):

Why should the effects of banking crises be so long-lasting, and possibly even permanent? One reason is that banking crises intensify the depth of recessions, leaving deeper scars than typical recessions. Possible reasons for why banking related crises are deeper include: a collapse in confidence; an increase in risk aversion; disruptions in financial intermediation (credit crunch, misallocation of credit); indirect effects associated with the impact on fiscal policy (increase in public sector debt and taxation); or a permanent loss of human capital during the slump (traditional hysteresis effects).

One of the papers they quote in support of their approach is Carlos D. Ramirez, Bank Fragility, ‘Money Under the Mattress,’ and Long-Run Growth: U.S. Evidence from the ‘Perfect’ Panic of 1893:

This paper examines how the U.S. financial crisis of 1893 affected state output growth between 1900 and 1930. The results indicate that a 1% increase in bank instability reduces output growth by about 5%. A comparison of the cases of Nebraska, with one of the highest bank failure rates, and West Virginia, which did not experience a single bank failure reveals that disintermediation affected growth through a portfolio change among savers – people simply stop trusting banks. Time series evidence from newspapers indicate that articles with the words “money hidden” significantly increase after banking crises, and die off slowly over time.

Ramirez continues:

The intuition behind the explanation of why financial disintermediation affects
growth is straightforward. In the absence of deposit insurance or any other institutional arrangement that restores confidence on the banking system, depositors who experience losses or whose money becomes illiquid, even temporarily, may become reluctant to keep their money in the banking system. They simply stop “trusting” banks. This lack of trust may affect all depositors, including those that did not experience losses. With a high enough degree of risk aversion and a high enough probability of a bank run or failure depositors may be induced to reshuffle their liquid asset portfolio away from the banking system. To the extent that the panic induces a portfolio change in asset holdings away from the banking system and into more rudimentary forms of savings, such as keeping the money “under the mattress,” financial intermediation, and thus, growth are adversely affected.

According to me, this raises a red flag about the use of these data to determine the the severity of bank crises in the current environment, even without considering the difficulty of disentangling the degree of recession actually caused by the Panic versus the degree of economic stupidity that was merely brought to light. The Nebraskans kept their money “under the mattress” due to a lack of deposit insurance – just how relevant are the mechanics to what is going on now?

Additionally, the underlying rationale behind the desire to avoid banking crises points to an alternative solution to the problem: rather than reducing the chance of a systemic banking crisis, why not increase the range of alternative intermediation pathways?

Currently, regulators are doing everything they can – by way of Sarbox, completely random regulatory punishment for having been involved in the underwriting and distribution of investments that went bad, TRACE, costs of prospectus preparation, etc. – to deprecate the direct capital markets. A concious effort should be made in the other direction; the option of issuing public debt should be made more attractive to companies, not less.

Additionally, I have previously proposed that Investment Banks be treated differently from Vanilla Banks, not by a strick separation such as Glass-Steagall, but by imposing differing schedules for different types of banks, so that the latter would be penalized for holding assets while the former would be penalized for trading them (where “penalized” refers to higher capital requirements). The idea can be extended: bring back the Trust Company, which would get a preferential capital rate for first mortgages with loan-to-value of less than 75% and a penalty rate of everything else.

In the financial system as in the financial investments, bad investments (bad banks) can hurt you: it is concentration that kills you. And the point is related to my other big complaint about the regulatory response to the crisis: right in the age of networking, regulators are emphasizing systems which are vulnerable to single point failure.

Just as an example, the BIS paper notes:

The final approach used in this exercise relies on the Bank of Canada’s stress testing framework. This methodology is based on the idea that the failure of a bank arises from either a macroeconomic shock or spillover effects from other distressed banks. Spillover effects arise either because of counterparty exposures in the interbank market or because of asset fire sales that affect the mark to market value of banks’ portfolios. In this context, a greater buffer of liquid assets can only be beneficial insofar as it helps the bank to avoid asset fire sales, which would otherwise lead to losses.

You could get the same benefit by reducing the degree of interbank holdings, but such a solution is not even considered. BIS, it appears, will continue to risk-weight bank paper according to the credit rating of the sovereign – if you want an example of moral hazard, that’s a good one right there.

Anyway, BIS comes up with a figure of 13bp per point of capital ratio:

Column A of Table 6 reports the results of this exercise. In order to keep ROE from changing, each percentage point increase in the ratio of TCE to RWA results in a median increase in lending spreads across countries of 13 basis points.

… but this is subject to four major problems acknowledged by BIS:

  • The existing literature, which is the basis for this report’s estimates of the costs of banking crises, may overestimate the costs of banking crises. Possible reasons include: overestimation of the underlying growth path prior to the crises; failure to account for the temporarily higher growth during that phase; and failure to fully control for factors other than a banking crises per se that may contribute to output declines during the crisis and beyond, including a failure to accurately reflect causal relationships.
  • Capital and liquidity requirements may be less effective in reducing the probability of banking crises than suggested by the approaches used in the study. This would reduce the overall net benefits for a given level of the requirements. However, to the extent that net benefits remain positive, it would also imply that the requirements would need to be raised by more in order to achieve a given net benefit.
  • Shifting of risk into the non-regulated sector could reduce the financial stability benefits.
  • The results of the impact of regulatory requirements on lending spreads are based on aggregate balance sheets within individual countries, so that they do not consider the incidence of the requirements across institutions. They implicitly assume that theinstitutions that fall short of the requirements (ie, that are constrained) do not react more than those with excess capital or liquidity (ie, that are unconstrained). These effects may not be purely distributional.

I consider the third point most important. To the extent that higher capital ratios imply higher spreads implies a greater role for the shadow banking industry, then the real effect of higher capital levels will be to shift important economic activity from the somewhat flawed regulated sector to a sector with no regulation at all.

I certainly support the idea that we should have layers of regulation – a strong banking system surrounded by a less regulated / less systemically important investment banking sector, surrounded in turn by a wild-n-wooly hedge fund/shadow bank sector … but regulators are, as usual fixing yesterday’s problem with little thought for the implications.

New Issue: INE FixedReset 5.00%+279

Monday, August 23rd, 2010

Innergex Renewable Energy Inc. has announced:

that it will be issuing 3,400,000 Cumulative Rate Reset Preferred Shares, Series A (the “Series A Preferred Shares”) for aggregate gross proceeds of $85 million on a bought deal basis to a syndicate of underwriters led by BMO Capital Markets and TD Securities Inc.

The Series A Preferred Shares will pay cumulative dividends of $1.25 per share per annum, yielding 5.00% per annum, payable quarterly, for the initial five year period ending January 15, 2016. The dividend rate will be reset on January 15, 2016 and every five years thereafter at a rate equal to the 5-year Government of Canada bond yield plus 2.79%. The Series A Preferred Shares will be redeemable by Innergex on or after January 15, 2016, in accordance with their terms.

Holders of the Series A Preferred Shares will have the right, at their option, to convert their shares into Cumulative Floating Rate Preferred Shares, Series B, (the “Series B Preferred Shares”) subject to certain conditions, on January 15, 2016 and on January 15 every five years thereafter. Holders of the Series B Preferred Shares will be entitled to receive cumulative quarterly floating dividends at a rate equal to the three-month Government of Canada Treasury Bill yield plus 2.79%.

As stated by Michel Letellier, President and Chief Executive Officer of Innergex: “With this transaction, Innergex’s capital structure is more diversified and will appeal to a broader investor base”. Net proceeds resulting from the sale of the Series A Preferred Shares will be used by Innergex to enhance its financial flexibility, to reduce indebtedness and for general corporate purposes.

The Series A Preferred Shares will be offered for sale to the public in each of the provinces of Canada pursuant to a short form prospectus of Innergex to be filed with Canadian securities regulatory authorities in all Canadian provinces. The offering is scheduled to close on or about September 14, 2010, subject to certain conditions, including obtaining all necessary regulatory approvals.

Furthermore, Innergex will be filing a revised Annual Information Form which takes into account the previously completed combination of the Corporation with Innergex Power Income Fund.

Innergex Renewable Energy Inc. is a leading developer, owner and operator of run-of-river hydroelectric facilities and wind energy projects in North America. Innergex’s management team has been involved in the renewable power industry since 1990. Innergex owns a portfolio of projects which consists of: i) interests in 17 operating facilities with an aggregate net installed capacity of 326 MW; ii) interests in 7 projects under development with an aggregate net installed capacity of 203 MW for which power purchase agreements have been secured; and iii) prospective projects of more than 2,000 MW (net).

The issue is rated P-3 by S&P and Pfd-3(low) by DBRS. The first dividend, if declared, shall be payable on January 17, 2011, the first business day after January 15, 2011 for $0.42123 per Series A Preferred Share, based on closing September 14, 2010.

More junk!

Update: DBRS comments:

While the Company’s existing assets would be expected to produce reasonable financial results and credit metrics under a steady-state scenario, the capital program will require significant financing beyond internally generated cash flow, expected to consist largely of debt. Furthermore, DBRS expects that Innergex will maintain a high common dividend payout ratio (in excess of 100% of net income) throughout the medium term. As such, consolidated credit metrics are expected to remain tight for the rating category through the medium term, with EBITDA-to-interest in the area of 2.5 times (x) and cash flow-to-debt in the 8% to 10% range. DBRS would expect future modest improvement in coverage metrics when assets under development are completed and enter service. Debt-to-capital, currently 62%, would be expected to migrate upward over time, given the significant common dividends.

The proceeds from the intended $85 million preferred share offering will be used to refinance existing debt and to fund future capital expenditures. While the amount of preferred shares will comprise a material portion of the capital structure, particularly in relation to the book value of shareholders’ equity, DBRS is comfortable with the provisional Pfd-3 (low) rating given the stability of the underlying business (largely attributable to the young generating fleet and strong PPAs), as well as the significant financial cushion that the common dividends provide.

Eight of the Company’s 14 operating assets have non-recourse debt totalling approximately $320 million; while selective use of project financing can serve to isolate business risk at the individual asset level, the asset-level debt obligations rank ahead of Innergex’s obligations.

Update, 2010-9-8: DBRS has finalized the rating at Pfd-3(low) with a stable trend.

PIC.PR.A Proposes Term Extension

Friday, August 20th, 2010

Premium Income Corporation has announced:

that its Board of Directors has approved a proposal to extend the term of the Fund for an additional seven years.

The final redemption date for the Class A Shares and Preferred Shares of the Fund is currently November 1, 2010 and the Fund proposes to implement a reorganization (“Reorganization”) that will allow shareholders to retain their investment in the Fund until at least November 1, 2017.

In connection with the Reorganization, holders of Class A Shares will continue to receive ongoing leveraged exposure to a high-quality portfolio consisting principally of common shares of Bank of Montreal, The Bank of Nova Scotia, Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce, Royal Bank of Canada and The Toronto-Dominion Bank, as well as attractive quarterly cash distributions. Currently, the Fund is paying quarterly distributions at a rate of $0.60 per year. The Fund intends to continue to pay distributions at this rate until the net asset value (“NAV”) per Unit (a “Unit” being considered to consist of one Class A Share and one Preferred Share) reaches $22.50. At such time, quarterly distributions paid by the Fund will vary and will be calculated as approximately 8.0% per annum of the NAV of a Class A Share. If the Reorganization is approved and implemented, holders of Preferred Shares are expected to continue to benefit from fixed cumulative preferential quarterly cash dividends in the amount of $0.215625 per Preferred Share ($0.8625 per year) representing a yield of 5.75% per annum on the original issue price of $15.00.

As part of the Reorganization, the Fund is also proposing other changes including changing its authorized share capital by adding new classes of shares issuable in series, changing the monthly retraction prices for the Class A Shares and the Preferred Shares so that they are calculated by reference to market price in addition to NAV and changing the dates by which notice of monthly retractions needs to be provided and by which the retraction amount will be paid. The Fund will also allow for the calculation of a diluted NAV in the event the Fund should ever issue warrants or rights to acquire additional Class A Shares or Preferred Shares.

The Fund believes that the Reorganization will allow shareholders to maintain their investment in the Fund on a basis that will better enable it to meet its investment objectives for both classes of shares.

If the Reorganization is approved and implemented, shareholders will be given a special retraction right to retract their Class A Shares or Preferred Shares at NAV on November 1, 2010. The redemption date of the shares will automatically be extended for successive seven-year terms after November 1, 2017, the Board of Directors will be authorized to set the dividend rate on the Preferred Shares for any such extension of term and shareholders will be able to retract their Class A Shares or Preferred Shares at NAV prior to any such extension.

A special meeting of holders of Class A Shares and Preferred Shares has been called and will be held on September 29, 2010 to consider and vote upon the proposal. Further details of the proposal will be outlined in an information circular to be prepared and delivered to holders of Class A Shares and Preferred Shares in connection with the special meeting. The Reorganization is also subject to all required regulatory approvals.

A fascinating part of this press release is the section As part of the Reorganization, the Fund is also proposing other changes including changing its authorized share capital by adding new classes of shares issuable in series, changing the monthly retraction prices for the Class A Shares and the Preferred Shares so that they are calculated by reference to market price in addition to NAV and changing the dates by which notice of monthly retractions needs to be provided and by which the retraction amount will be paid.

So it sounds like they want to go the route taken by CGI and BNA (there may be others) and have what is essentially permanent capital units leveraged by a variety of preferreds. Changing the monthly retraction price sounds like it could be scary, but we will just have to wait for details.

Another item of interest is their intention to provide a partial NAV test on capital unit distributions, so that these distributions will be relatively low until Asset Coverage exceeds 1.5x.

However, the problem with this proposal is that preferred shareholders are being asked to provide a term extension for junk. The NAV on August 12 is only $19.94 implying Asset Coverage of only 1.3+:1. That’s pretty skimpy. On the other hand, the promoters are proposing to continue the dividend rate of 5.75%, which is relatively good.

Comparators are:

PIC.PR.A Comparators
Ticker Asset Coverage Yield Notes
FFN.PR.A 1.4-:1 5.42% Full NAV Test
LFE.PR.A 1.3+:1 5.45% Full NAV Test
WFS.PR.A 1.1+:1 16.27%
to June 30, 2011
Full NAV Test
LCS.PR.A 1.2+:1 5.25% Full NAV Test
BSD.PR.A 1.2+:1 9.51%
Interest
Abusive management

Well, you can make what you like of it, but I say that a measly 5.75% isn’t enough to compensate seven-year money for low Asset Coverage and the lack of a full NAV test (in which Capital Unitholders get NOTHING, zip, zero, zilch, for as long as Asset Coverage is below 1.5:1).

This is particularly true since Income Coverage in 1H10 was only 0.8-:1 … coverage of the distributions to both preferred share and capital unitholders was 0.5-:1.

We want more! At least one of:

  • Full NAV Test
  • Higher Coupon
  • Higher Asset Coverage (by consolidation of Capital units / partial redemption of preferreds)

Otherwise – and subject to the potential for very pleasant, but unlikely, surprises in the final documents … VOTE NO!

PIC.PR.A was last mentioned on PrefBlog when it was Upgraded to Pfd-4(high) by DBRS. PIC.PR.A is tracked by HIMIPref™, but is relegated to the Scraps index on credit concerns.

August 20, 2010

Friday, August 20th, 2010

Was the Panic of 2007 bogus? I have previously highlighted doubts about the ABX index validity (as has, famously, Fabulous Fab) … Richard Stanton and Nancy Wallace supply another interesting paper, The Bear’s Lair: Indexed Credit Default Swaps and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis:

ABX.HE indexed credit default swaps on baskets of mortgage-backed securities are now the main benchmark used by financial institutions to mark their subprime mortgage portfolios to market. However, we find that current prices for the ABX.HE indices are inconsistent with any finite assumption for mortgage default rates, and that ABX.HE price changes are uncorrelated with changes in the credit performance of the underlying loans. These results cast serious doubt on the suitability of the ABX.HE indices as valuation benchmarks. We also find that ABX.HE price changes are significantly related to short-sale activity in the option and equity markets of the publicly traded builders, the commercial banks, the investment banks and the government sponsored enterprises (GSEs). This suggests that capital constraints, limiting the supply of ABS insurance, may be playing a role here similar to that identified by Froot (2001) in the market for catastrophe insurance.

We collect detailed credit and prepayment histories from 2006{2008 for all of the roughly 360,000 individual loans underlying the ABX.HE indices, and use these data, plus current prices, to infer the market’s expectations for future defaults. Using both a simple, “back-of-the-envelope” model (in which all defaults and insurance payments occur instantaneously) and a full CDS valuation model calibrated to the historical loan-level performance data, we find that recent price levels for ABX.HE index CDS are inconsistent with any reasonable forecast for the future default performance of the underlying loans. For example, assuming a recovery rate of 21%, the AAA ABX.HE prices on June 30, 2009 imply default rates of 100% on the underlying loans. In other words, if recovery rates exceed 21% (a value well below anything ever observed in U.S. mortgage markets), there is no default rate high enough to support observed prices. We also find that changes in the credit performance of the underlying loans explain almost none of the observed price changes in the ABX.HE indices. These results cast serious doubt on the use of the ABX.HE indices for marking mortgage portfolios to market.

The Canadian preferred share market advanced modestly on good volume today, with PerpetualDiscounts gaining 2bp and FixedResets up 7bp.

MFC issues maintained their presence in the volume highlights; probably continuing portfolio rebalancing after the DBRS downgrade.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.4480 % 2,053.3
FixedFloater 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.4480 % 3,110.6
Floater 2.55 % 2.17 % 36,998 21.93 4 -0.4480 % 2,217.1
OpRet 4.90 % -2.64 % 102,983 0.19 9 0.1249 % 2,350.8
SplitShare 6.03 % -25.10 % 67,997 0.09 2 0.1459 % 2,333.1
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1249 % 2,149.6
Perpetual-Premium 5.77 % 5.49 % 101,002 5.58 7 -0.1405 % 1,959.4
Perpetual-Discount 5.74 % 5.78 % 183,793 14.07 71 0.0161 % 1,891.3
FixedReset 5.28 % 3.28 % 287,612 3.38 47 0.0676 % 2,244.9
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
TRI.PR.B Floater -1.06 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-20
Maturity Price : 23.09
Evaluated at bid price : 23.35
Bid-YTW : 2.05 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
RY.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 210,890 TD crossed 187,800 at 20.60.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-20
Maturity Price : 20.63
Evaluated at bid price : 20.63
Bid-YTW : 5.49 %
TRP.PR.B FixedReset 77,674 Scotia crossed 11,000 at 24.97; Nesbitt crossed 50,000 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-20
Maturity Price : 24.92
Evaluated at bid price : 24.97
Bid-YTW : 3.63 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 49,579 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-20
Maturity Price : 18.90
Evaluated at bid price : 18.90
Bid-YTW : 6.16 %
TD.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 43,971 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-20
Maturity Price : 22.25
Evaluated at bid price : 22.40
Bid-YTW : 5.46 %
SLF.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 42,436 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-20
Maturity Price : 20.03
Evaluated at bid price : 20.03
Bid-YTW : 6.03 %
MFC.PR.E FixedReset 37,773 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.00
Bid-YTW : 4.44 %
There were 36 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

FixedReset Index Sets All-Time Low Median-YTW Record

Friday, August 20th, 2010

The HIMIPref™ FixedReset Index set a new record low median-YTW record today, as this value dropped to a niggardly 3.26%, a new low.


Click for Big

To celebrate, I am publishing the constituents of this index, with three sorts:

August 19, 2010

Friday, August 20th, 2010

Econbrowser‘s James Hamilton sounds a gloomy note in his post Will the Fed Do More?:

Certainly Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis President James Bullard is trying to communicate that the Fed needs to respond more if disinflation continues:

There has been disinflation. It has been at the low end of where I’d like to see it. For that reason I think we should supplement our quantitative easing program if we get further developments on that front. We should have a plan in place to take action if it moves lower.

My expectation is that Hoenig’s forecast will prove optimistic, and that last week’s modest easing is not the last we’re going to hear from the Fed.

Not to be out-done, Econbrowser‘s Menzie Chinn writes a post Financing US Debt which presents highlights of a recent paper:

We use the CBO assessment of the President’s budget, and a key estimated relationship between the ten year – three month spread and the unemployment gap, inflation, structural budget deficits, and foreign official purchase of Treasury securities. Note that we presume that, contrary to some people’s assertions, deficits matter. Actually, we estimate the relationship, and find that each percentage point of the structural, or cyclically adjusted, budget deficit raises the spread by 27 basis points. The fit is displayed in Chart 5.

The Canadian preferred share market rocketted ahead on good volume today, with PerpetualDiscounts up 26bp and FixedResets up 16bp. FixedResets set a new all-time low median average yield-to-worst at 3.26%. Interestingly, the Bozo Spread (Current Yield PerpetualDiscounts less Current Yield FixedResets) has narrowed very slightly to 45bp.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.2112 % 2,062.6
FixedFloater 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.2112 % 3,124.5
Floater 2.54 % 2.16 % 37,323 21.95 4 0.2112 % 2,227.0
OpRet 4.90 % 0.55 % 103,677 0.20 9 0.0862 % 2,347.9
SplitShare 6.04 % -24.10 % 70,236 0.09 2 0.2297 % 2,329.7
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0862 % 2,146.9
Perpetual-Premium 5.77 % 5.32 % 98,815 1.76 7 0.0562 % 1,962.2
Perpetual-Discount 5.74 % 5.77 % 183,740 14.12 71 0.2558 % 1,891.0
FixedReset 5.29 % 3.26 % 291,604 3.38 47 0.1550 % 2,243.4
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
TRI.PR.B Floater 1.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-19
Maturity Price : 23.32
Evaluated at bid price : 23.60
Bid-YTW : 2.02 %
CM.PR.M FixedReset 1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 28.17
Bid-YTW : 3.23 %
W.PR.J Perpetual-Discount 1.64 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-19
Maturity Price : 23.88
Evaluated at bid price : 24.13
Bid-YTW : 5.87 %
SLF.PR.F FixedReset 4.00 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.85
Bid-YTW : 3.15 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
TD.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 57,244 Desjardins crossed two blocks of 20,000 each, both at 22.35.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-19
Maturity Price : 22.16
Evaluated at bid price : 22.31
Bid-YTW : 5.48 %
RY.PR.L FixedReset 38,400 Anonymous crossed 37,800 at 27.25.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.30
Bid-YTW : 2.83 %
BNS.PR.N Perpetual-Discount 37,490 Nesbitt crossed 30,000 at 23.97.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-19
Maturity Price : 23.65
Evaluated at bid price : 23.85
Bid-YTW : 5.55 %
BMO.PR.L Perpetual-Premium 33,514 Desjardins crossed 30,000 at 26.00.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2017-06-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.76
Bid-YTW : 5.29 %
TRP.PR.C FixedReset 32,155 Nesbitt crossed 18,000 at 25.50.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-19
Maturity Price : 23.27
Evaluated at bid price : 25.45
Bid-YTW : 3.71 %
PWF.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 31,803 Desjardins crossed 30,000 at 21.75.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-19
Maturity Price : 21.46
Evaluated at bid price : 21.77
Bid-YTW : 5.90 %
There were 36 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

ALA.PR.A Rockets to Premium on Massive Volume

Friday, August 20th, 2010

AltaGas Ltd. has announced:

it has closed its previously announced public offering of 8,000,000 Cumulative Redeemable Five-Year Rate Reset Preferred Shares, Series A (the “Series A Preferred Shares”) at a price of $25 per Series A Preferred Share (the “Offering”). The Offering resulted in AltaGas receiving gross proceeds of $200 million.

The Offering was first announced on August 10, 2010 when AltaGas entered into an agreement with a syndicate of underwriters, led by TD Securities Inc., RBC Capital Markets and CIBC World Markets Inc.
Net proceeds from the Offering will be used to reduce outstanding indebtedness under AltaGas’ credit facilities, thereby strengthening AltaGas’ balance sheet and giving it the financial flexibility to support, among other things, construction activities related to the Forrest Kerr project.

The Series A Preferred Shares will commence trading today on the Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbol ALA.PR.A.

The offering was super-sized from $150-million to $200-million, announced, August 10.

ALA.PR.A was announced as a FixedReset 5.00%+266 on August 10.

It traded 989,638 shares today in a range of 25.19-42 before closing at 25.38-44, 17×50.

Vital statistics are:

ALA.PR.A FixedReset YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2015-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.38
Bid-YTW : 4.69 %

BoC Releases Summer 2010 Review

Thursday, August 19th, 2010

The Bank of Canada has released the Bank of Canada Review: Summer 2010 with articles:

  • Lessons Learned from Research on Infl ation Targeting
  • Monetary Policy and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates
  • Price-Level Targeting and Relative-Price Shocks
  • Should Monetary Policy Be Used to Counteract Financial Imbalances?
  • Conference Summary: New Frontiers in Monetary Policy Design

The Financial Imbalances article points out:

Another potentially important cost of leaning against
fi nancial imbalances stems from the difficulty of identifying them and of calibrating an appropriate response. If fi nancial imbalances are falsely identified, responding to them through monetary policy could induce undesirable economic fluctuations (Greenspan 2002; Bernanke and Gertler 1999).

The question, according to the authors, is:

Granted that appropriate supervision and regulation
are the fi rst line of defence against financial imbalances, the key question is whether they should be the only one. In this context, developing a view on whether monetary policy should lean against financial imbalances requires that we first examine the interaction between the effects of prudential tools and those of monetary policy on fi nancial imbalances that stem from various sources.

A credit-fuelled housing bubble is a particularly relevant example of a fi nancial imbalance. This section considers the case of over-exuberance in the housing sector, represented as a temporary increase in the perceived value of housing that results in a short-term surge in mortgage credit. This example is calibrated to produce housing-market dynamics that are roughly similar to those of the housing market in the United States in the run-up to the recent crisis. Specifically, the size of the shock is set at 5 per cent of the value of housing collateral; this leads to an average increase in mortgage debt in the first year of about 16 per cent, comparable with the average annual growth rate of mortgage debt over the 2003–06 period.

We evaluate the relative merits of using monetary policy to contain this imbalance and compare it with a well-targeted prudential instrument—namely, an adjustment in the mortgage loan-to-value (LTV) ratio.

The authors have the fortitude to emphasize:

As mentioned in the introduction, one important argument against using monetary policy as a tool in these situations is that fi nancial imbalances cannot be detected with certainty. This uncertainty applies not only to monetary policy, but also to prudential policy, and should play a role in determining how forcefully to react to the prospect of building financial imbalances.

By me, this is such an important consideration that it virtually negates the concept of leaning against the flow. I am in favour of a progressive surcharge on banks’ Risk Weighted Assets based on how much these have changed over the past few years, but that’s based more on management factors than economic ones.

By definition, a bubble will have lots of defenders ready to explain why it is not a bubble, as discussed recently in FRBB: Bubbles Happen. Trying to nip bubbles in bud on the basis of a bureaucrat deciding that eggs should cost $2.99 a dozen and $3.25 is too much is fraught with dangers.

BIS Proposes CoCos: Regulatory Trigger, Infinite Dilution

Thursday, August 19th, 2010

The Bank for International Settlement has released a Proposal to ensure the loss absorbency of regulatory capital at the point of non-viability – consultative document:

the proposal is specifically structured to allow each jurisdiction (and banks) the freedom to implement it in a way that will not conflict with national law or any other constraints. For example, a conversion rate is not specified, nor is the choice between implementation through a write-off or conversion. Any attempt to define the specific implementation of the proposal more rigidly at an international level, than the current minimum set out in this document, risks creating conflicts with national law and may be unnecessarily prescriptive.

The Basel Committee welcomes comments on all aspects of the proposal set out in this consultative document. Comments should be submitted by 1 October 2010 by email to: baselcommittee@bis.org.

However, if we define gone-concern also to include situations in which the public sector provides support to distressed banks that would otherwise have failed, the financial crisis has revealed that many regulatory capital instruments do not always absorb losses in gone-concern situations.

That’s a nice little definition of “gone concern”, giving bureaucrats the authority to ursurp the prerogatives of the legal system. One thousand years of bankruptcy law … pffffft!

The proposal will be examined clause by clause:

All non-common Tier 1 instruments and Tier 2 instruments at internationally active banks must have a clause in their terms and conditions that requires them to be written-off on the occurrence of the trigger event.

Reasonable enough.

Any compensation paid to the instrument holders as a result of the write-off must be paid immediately in the form of common stock (or its equivalent in the case of non-joint stock companies).

This means that write-down structure’s like Rabobank’s would not, of themselves, qualify for inclusion. There would need to be another clause in the terms reflecting the possibility of the BIS proposal being triggered while the other trigger is waiting.

The issuing bank must maintain at all times all prior authorisation necessary to immediately issue the relevant number of shares specified in the instrument’s terms and conditions should the trigger event occur.

Well, sure.

The trigger event is the earlier of: (1) the decision to make a public sector injection of capital, or equivalent support, without which the firm would have become non-viable, as determined by the relevant authority; and (2) a decision that a write-off, without which the firm would become non-viable, is necessary, as determined by the relevant authority.

This is the dangerous part, as it gives unlimited authority to the regulators to wipe out a bank’s capital investors, with no accountability or recourse whatsoever.

The issuance of any new shares as a result of the trigger event must occur prior to any public sector injection of capital so that the capital provided by the public sector is not diluted.

This means that infinite dilution of the common received on conversion is possible.

The relevant jurisdiction in determining the trigger event is the jurisdiction in which the capital is being given recognition for regulatory purposes. Therefore, where an issuing bank is part of a wider banking group and if the issuing bank wishes the instrument to be included in the consolidated group’s capital in addition to its solo capital, the terms and conditions must specify an additional trigger event. This trigger event is the earlier of: (1) the decision to make a public sector injection of capital, or equivalent support, in the jurisdiction of the consolidated supervisor, without which the firm receiving the support would have become non-viable, as determined by the relevant authority in that jurisdiction; and (2) a decision that a write-off, without which the firm would become non-viable, is necessary, as determined by the relevant authority in the home jurisdiction.

Reasonable enough, but this could cause a lot of fun with rogue regulators and cross-default provisions.

Any common stock paid as compensation to the holders of the instrument can either be common stock of the issuing bank or the parent company of the consolidated group.

The major problem – besides the evasion of bankruptcy law – with this document is that there is no distinction drawn between Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital for conversion purposes. Tier 1 capital is supposed to provide going-concern loss absorption, but the only thing triggering conversion is the Armageddon scenario. I don’t think that sub-debt holders will be particularly pleased about that.

However, the terms of this proposal are so abusive, so antithetical to the interests of investors, that I suspect most instruments will be issued with a pre-emptive trigger, so that conversion will be triggered prior to the regulators (well … reasonable regulators, anyway) exercising their unlimited and unaccountable power.

Bloomberg notes:

The Association for Financial Markets in Europe, an industry group representing banks, said last week that failing financial companies should reduce the risk to taxpayers by using contingent capital and by converting debt into equity to fund their own rescue.

In what it termed a “bail-in,” AFME said bank bond holders should see their securities convert into common shares in the event an institution’s capital ratios fall below a pre-set level, the group said in a discussion paper on Aug. 12.

Update: The AFME discussion paper, The Systemic Safety Net: Pulling failing firms back from the edge is very vague and relies on assertions, rather then evidence and argument, to make its point. It might also be dismissed as intellectually dishonest, in that it takes no account of any other proposals or academic work.

Of some interest is their view on the market-based triggers I endorse:

A trigger based on market metrics or a determination of impending systemic risk (made by a regulator) would not be effective. In addition to creating marketability issues, a trigger based on share price or market capitalisation is subject to manipulation and will almost certainly foreclose a proactive capital raise because it may fail to move the firm a safe enough distance from the trigger, which in turn will generate further negative price spirals. A trigger based on a determination of systemic risk is also unattractive, partly because it could not be used in cases of idiosyncratic risk. Waiting until firm‐specific risk has spiralled into systemic risk is destabilising.

Their preference is for a trigger based on capital ratios:

A trigger based on a core capital ratio set above the minimum core tier 1 capital requirements under the re‐invigorated Basel III capital standards would meet these criteria. Firms should have the discretion to set the trigger in accordance with their own objectives to achieve the optimal balance between prudential and economic considerations. Factors the issuer might consider in setting the trigger are:

a. To receive treatment as going concern capital the trigger should activate before any breach of the firm’s minimum regulatory capital requirements, or any other circumstances giving rise to regulatory intervention.

b. The probability of breach needs to be low enough to attract a credit rating as debt and, as such, near to subordinated debt for purposes of pricing.

I have grave difficulties with their view that market prices will be manipulated, but capital levels won’t. Additionally, as an investor, I have grave reservations about tying my investment to a capital ratio definition that will almost certainly be changed in the life of the instrument.

August 18, 2010

Wednesday, August 18th, 2010

The Barclays settlement of allegations they did business with bad people and covered it up was criticized here yesterday. I am pleased to see it has hit a roadblock:

A federal judge refused to endorse a settlement between the U.S. and a bank for a third time in a year, calling a proposed $298 million fine of Barclays Plc for trading with Iran, Cuba and Sudan “a sweetheart deal.”

U.S. District Judge Emmet Sullivan in Washington scheduled a hearing for today to address the question he asked prosecutors yesterday: “Why isn’t the government getting tough with the banks?” U.S. District Judge Ellen Huvelle in Washington on Aug. 16 likewise held up a $75 million settlement between the Securities and Exchange Commission and Citigroup Inc., lawyers in the case said.

“Courts are wrestling with what they see as a disparity between the way in which the conduct is being characterized as serious and the penalties that are being imposed,” said James Doty, former SEC general counsel who is now a partner at Baker Botts LLP in Washington.

U.S. agencies and prosecutors, taking note of the decisions, will begin trying harder to deliver the executives responsible for misconduct, Doty said.

I’ll believe it when I see it. Imposing fines on the shareholders is an accepted part of the game, but going after individuals will be a threat to the regulators’ club membership.

And at the same time, New Jersey is in the spotlight:

New Jersey settled claims that it misled investors in $26 billion of municipal bonds by masking underfunding of its two biggest pension plans, in the first Securities and Exchange Commission case to target a state.

New Jersey agreed to settle the SEC case without admitting or denying the agency’s findings. The state consented to a cease-and-desist order, and wasn’t required to pay any civil fines or penalties.

So what did happen? The SEC explains:

The SEC’s order requires the State of New Jersey to cease and desist from committing or causing any violations and any future violations of Sections 17(a)(2) and 17(a)(3) of the Securities Act of 1933. New Jersey consented to the issuance of the order without admitting or denying the findings. In determining to accept New Jersey’s offer to settle this matter, the Commission considered the cooperation afforded the SEC’s staff during the investigation and certain remedial acts taken by the state.

So basically it was a bureaucrats cuddle-fest. Fabulous Fabio … eat your heart out.

Inflationistas will be pleased to see that UK inflation exceeded 3.1% in July, which the BoE attributes to tax increases, oil prices and the decline of Sterling. HM Treasury has promised to tighten the fiscal screws further. The BoE’s views on inflation were last discussed August 11.

There was continued heavy volume in the Canadian preferred share market today, with PerpetualDiscounts gaining 34bp, while FixedResets lost 4bp.

PerpetualDiscounts now yield 5.79%, equivalent to 8.11% interest at the standard conversion factor of 1.4x. Long Corporates are now pretty close to 5.35%, so the pre-tax interest equivalent spread (also called the Seniority Spread) is about 270bp, down marginally – and perhaps spuriously – from the 275bp reported August 11.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1057 % 2,058.2
FixedFloater 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1057 % 3,118.0
Floater 2.54 % 2.16 % 36,886 21.96 4 0.1057 % 2,222.3
OpRet 4.91 % 0.54 % 107,960 0.20 9 -0.2365 % 2,345.8
SplitShare 6.06 % -21.87 % 69,600 0.09 2 0.9031 % 2,324.3
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.2365 % 2,145.1
Perpetual-Premium 5.77 % 5.23 % 92,482 5.58 7 0.3045 % 1,961.1
Perpetual-Discount 5.75 % 5.79 % 185,976 14.08 71 0.3352 % 1,886.2
FixedReset 5.30 % 3.32 % 295,966 3.38 47 -0.0362 % 2,239.9
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
SLF.PR.F FixedReset -3.70 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.78
Bid-YTW : 4.27 %
BAM.PR.O OpRet -2.13 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Option Certainty
Maturity Date : 2013-06-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.70
Bid-YTW : 4.23 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.06 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.57
Evaluated at bid price : 21.87
Bid-YTW : 5.79 %
BNS.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 20.65
Evaluated at bid price : 20.65
Bid-YTW : 5.51 %
RY.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.45
Evaluated at bid price : 21.45
Bid-YTW : 5.51 %
BNA.PR.D SplitShare 1.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-09-17
Maturity Price : 26.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.55
Bid-YTW : -21.87 %
BMO.PR.L Perpetual-Premium 1.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2017-06-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.90
Bid-YTW : 5.19 %
RY.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 1.43 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 20.50
Evaluated at bid price : 20.50
Bid-YTW : 5.46 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.62 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 18.80
Evaluated at bid price : 18.80
Bid-YTW : 6.19 %
NA.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.69 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.71
Evaluated at bid price : 21.71
Bid-YTW : 5.63 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
RY.PR.Y FixedReset 81,526 TD crossed blocks of 30,000 and 40,000, both at 27.95.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-12-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.93
Bid-YTW : 3.20 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet 70,300 Nesbitt crossed blocks of 40,000 and 27,300, both at 26.15.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.05
Bid-YTW : 4.88 %
BMO.PR.M FixedReset 56,245 Nesbitt crossed 19,800 at 26.60. TD crossed two blocks of 10,000 each at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-09-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.60
Bid-YTW : 2.73 %
HSB.PR.E FixedReset 54,579 TD crossed 40,000 at 27.98.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.94
Bid-YTW : 3.67 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 51,766 RBC crossed 24,000 at 21.13.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 21.17
Evaluated at bid price : 21.17
Bid-YTW : 5.73 %
MFC.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 45,093 TD crossed 15,300 at 18.15.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-08-18
Maturity Price : 18.15
Evaluated at bid price : 18.15
Bid-YTW : 6.21 %
There were 57 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.