Market Action

June 29, 2009

Bernanke roughly handled by the House Oversight Committee:

Republican lawmakers who have consistently opposed government rescues of financial companies have accused the central bank of overstepping its authority in pressuring Bank of America to absorb Merrill Lynch.

Republican congressional staff wrote in a memo on documents received by the House panel from the Fed through a subpoena that a “gun placed to the head of Bank of America” forced the Charlotte, North Carolina-based bank to go through with the merger, which was announced in mid-September.

but has found defenders in Econbrowser‘s James Hamilton’s post On Grilling the Fed Chair:

It is one thing to have different views from those of the Fed Chair on particular decisions that have been made– I certainly have plenty of areas of disagreement of my own. But it is another matter to question Bernanke’s intellect or personal integrity. As someone who’s known him for 25 years, I would place him above 99.9% of those recently in power in Washington on the integrity dimension, not to mention IQ. His actions over the past two years have been guided by one and only one motive, that being to minimize the harm caused to ordinary people by the financial turmoil. Whether you agree or disagree with all the steps he’s taken, let’s start with an understanding that that’s been his overriding goal.

and in a somewhat more lukewarm manner by Accrued Interest’s Ben Bernanke: Smooth Criminal:

Now the morons in congress are coming for Ben Bernanke for how he handled the Bank of America/Merrill Lynch merger. Seriously? Now, let there be no doubt. Ken Lewis was pressured by the Fed in a way that should leave a bad taste in the mouth of any free citizen. But we were in the middle of an economic war. Sometimes some bad shit happens on the battlefield and sometimes its OK if we look the other way.

Willem Buiter remarks that Too Big to Fail is Too Big (emphasis added):

In banking and most highly leveraged finance, size is a social bad. Fortunately, there is quite a list of effective instruments for cutting leveraged finance down to size.

  • Legally and institutionally, unbundle narrow banking and investment banking (Glass Steagall-on-steroids).
  • Legally and institutionally prevent all banks (narrow banks and investment banks) from engaging in activities that present manifest potential conflicts of interest. This means no more universal banks and similar financial supermarkets.
  • Limit the size of all banks by making regulatory capital ratios an increasing function of bank size.
  • Enforce competition policy aggressively in the banking sector, by breaking up banks if necessary.
  • Require any remaining systemically important banks to produce a detailed annual bankruptcy contingency plan.
  • Only permit limited liability for narrow banks/public utility banks.
  • Create a highly efficient special resolution regime for all systemically important financial institutions. This SRR will permit an omnipotent Conservator/Administrator to financially restructure the failing institutions (by writing down the claims of the unsecured creditors or mandatorily converting them into equity), without interfering materially with new lending, investment and funding operations.

The Geithner plan for restructuring US regulation is silent on the too big to fail problem. That alone is sufficient to ensure that it will fail to result in a more stable and safer US banking and financial system.

Of the laundry list, Assiduous Readers will know that I am most in favour of making regulartory capital requirements an increasing function of bank size: it requires the least judgement by regulators and politicians, is the most transparent and allows the highest degree of forward planning by the banks and by the investors in those banks.

I also want to see an unbundling of narrow banking and investment banking, but preferably not by legislative fiat. I want to see the regulations altered to recognize that there is a difference in institutional culture between these two activities and offer institutions a choice between capital requirement regimes. Those opting for Narrow Banking will find they can lever up their buy-and-hold holdings of consumer loans a little more, but find their trading activities require more capital to cover; those opting for Investment Banking will find it relatively easier to lever up a trading operation, but when paper stays on the books for more than a few months it requires progressively more capital.

I recently read a fascinating paper on the origins of corporate boards; Franklin A. Gevurtz’s The Historical and Political Origins of the Corporate Board of Directors:

Prompted by the litany of complaints about corporate boards – as once again highlighted by recent corporate scandals – this paper seeks to add to the literature on why corporation laws in the United States (and, indeed, around the world) generally call for corporate governance by or under a board of directors. Moreover, this paper takes a very different approach in searching for an answer. Instead of theorizing, this paper examines historical sources in order to look at how and why an elected board of directors came to be the accepted mode of corporate governance. This will entail a reverse chronological tour all the way back to the antecedents of today’s corporate board in fourteenth through sixteenth century companies of English merchants engaged in foreign trade. The central insight of this chronology is that the corporate board of directors did not develop as an institution to manage the business corporation. Rather, it is an institution the business corporation inherited when the business corporation evolved out of societies of independent merchants. This paper also shows how these merchant societies based their adoption of the antecedents of today’s corporate board on widespread political theories and practices in medieval Europe that, although hardly democratic, often called for the use of collective governance by a body of representatives. The discovery of the historical and political origins of the corporate board, besides being interesting in its own right, suggests that the current frustration with corporate boards may arise from confusing an institution designed to achieve political legitimacy through consent of the governed, with the goal of assuring efficient management of a business on behalf of passive investors.

A good solidly strong day for preferreds as FixedResets continued to rock ‘n’ roll on continued heavy volume. I will be most interested to see what tomorrow brings, given the DBRS Mass Downgrade of Bank Prefs & IT1C … probably not much effect, but the banks that got downgraded two notches (HSB, NA, LB) rather than just one (BMO, BNS, CM, RY, TD) might see some effects.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -1.4702 % 1,188.7
FixedFloater 7.09 % 5.51 % 35,562 16.31 1 0.0000 % 2,126.6
Floater 3.20 % 3.59 % 76,896 18.30 3 -1.4702 % 1,485.0
OpRet 4.94 % 3.47 % 121,412 0.89 14 0.2391 % 2,210.2
SplitShare 5.74 % 6.31 % 69,731 4.20 3 0.2717 % 1,900.6
Interest-Bearing 5.99 % 0.35 % 22,795 0.08 1 0.2000 % 2,021.1
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.2709 % 1,744.9
Perpetual-Discount 6.32 % 6.37 % 161,445 13.41 71 0.2709 % 1,607.0
FixedReset 5.63 % 4.64 % 486,697 4.35 40 0.3178 % 2,029.1
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
BAM.PR.K Floater -2.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 10.86
Evaluated at bid price : 10.86
Bid-YTW : 3.62 %
MFC.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -2.01 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 17.54
Evaluated at bid price : 17.54
Bid-YTW : 6.48 %
TRI.PR.B Floater -1.63 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 15.05
Evaluated at bid price : 15.05
Bid-YTW : 2.61 %
BAM.PR.O OpRet -1.26 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Option Certainty
Maturity Date : 2013-06-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 23.51
Bid-YTW : 6.76 %
CM.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -1.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 21.95
Evaluated at bid price : 22.26
Bid-YTW : 6.45 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.04 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 19.52
Evaluated at bid price : 19.52
Bid-YTW : 6.45 %
SLF.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.04 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 18.50
Evaluated at bid price : 18.50
Bid-YTW : 6.54 %
CU.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.11 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 23.42
Evaluated at bid price : 23.71
Bid-YTW : 6.18 %
PWF.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 1.12 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 21.60
Evaluated at bid price : 21.60
Bid-YTW : 6.50 %
GWO.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 1.35 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 22.38
Evaluated at bid price : 22.56
Bid-YTW : 6.58 %
GWO.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.38 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 20.51
Evaluated at bid price : 20.51
Bid-YTW : 6.39 %
BAM.PR.H OpRet 1.39 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.25
Evaluated at bid price : 25.50
Bid-YTW : 4.94 %
GWO.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 1.41 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 18.66
Evaluated at bid price : 18.66
Bid-YTW : 6.55 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet 1.59 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 22.40
Bid-YTW : 7.06 %
CU.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 2.17 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 24.71
Evaluated at bid price : 25.00
Bid-YTW : 6.06 %
HSB.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 3.54 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 20.45
Evaluated at bid price : 20.45
Bid-YTW : 6.28 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
GWO.PR.X OpRet 208,558 Nesbitt crossed blocks of 150,000 and 25,000 shares, both at 26.00; RBC crossed 30,000 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.67
Evaluated at bid price : 26.00
Bid-YTW : 3.69 %
GWO.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 203,313 Nesbitt crossed 160,000 at 22.20 and another 40,000 at 22.40.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 22.38
Evaluated at bid price : 22.56
Bid-YTW : 6.58 %
TD.PR.M OpRet 125,600 RBC crossed three blocks, 49,000 and 30,000 and 19,000 shares, all at 26.16; Desjardins crossed 25,000 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-05-30
Maturity Price : 25.75
Evaluated at bid price : 26.20
Bid-YTW : 3.47 %
BMO.PR.P FixedReset 114,910 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 23.22
Evaluated at bid price : 25.32
Bid-YTW : 4.90 %
GWO.PR.J FixedReset 81,700 Nesbitt sold 33,900 to RBC at 26.25, then crossed 43,500 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.25
Bid-YTW : 4.80 %
TD.PR.S FixedReset 72,875 RBC bought 18,800 from Anonymous at 24.95, then crossed 26,000 at 24.94.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-29
Maturity Price : 24.86
Evaluated at bid price : 24.91
Bid-YTW : 4.37 %
There were 44 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
Issue Comments

DBRS: Mass Downgrade of Bank Preferreds & IT1C

DBRS has announced that it:

has today downgraded the preferred shares and innovative Tier 1 instrument ratings of the Canadian banks it rates, following the application of changes in DBRS’s global banking methodology. The ratings have been removed from Under Review with Negative Implications, where they were placed on April 20, 2009. All other ratings for the Canadian banks are unaffected; related rating trends remain unchanged. The downgrades reflect the revision of DBRS’s views on external support as it relates to preferred shares and the elevated risk of non-payment of preferred dividends relative to the risk of default indicated by senior debt ratings. The downgrades do not reflect any specific credit event at any of the listed institutions or related entities.

The change in methodology affects preferred shares ratings in three ways:

(1) The change in the global banking methodology dictates that the starting point for notching preferred shares will be based on the intrinsic assessment rating, rather than the senior debt rating (which may incorporate the benefit of external support). The primary factor that has led to this change in the methodology is recent actions taken in other jurisdictions that demonstrate no systemic external support for preferred shares. As such, the preferred shares and Tier 1 innovative instruments ratings of the listed institutions and their related entities that benefited from a one-notch uplift in October 2006 (due to the support assessment designation of SA2) will now be removed.

The preferred shares and Tier 1 innovative instruments of the affected institutions are: Bank of Montreal, Bank of Nova Scotia, Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce, National Bank of Canada, Royal Bank of Canada, and Toronto-Dominion Bank.

(2) The other change in the global banking methodology incorporates the elevated risk of non-payment of preferred dividends relative to the risk of default for more senior debt instruments. As such, the changes in the methodology have increased the base notching, even within the strongest rating categories, and the base notching now expands as the credit quality of the bank migrates downward. Within this approach, there exists some flexibility to adjust the notching for factors that reflect the position of individual banks. Historically, DBRS’s methodology resulted in a fixed relationship across all rating categories.

The preferred shares and Tier 1 innovative instruments of the affected institutions are: National Bank of Canada and Laurentian Bank of Canada.

(3) The final change in the global banking methodology affects SA1 category banks. The preferred shares rating for the subsidiary will be notched relative to the preferred share of the parent in the same way that all debt ratings are notched between the two entities.

The preferred shares and Tier 1 innovative instruments of the affected institution is: HSBC Bank Canada.

DBRS will host a teleconference tomorrow morning, Tuesday June 30, at 11:00 am ET, to discuss today’s rating action.

Interested callers should dial the appropriate number listed below at least five minutes before the 11:00 am ET call time.

Local Callers: 416-695-5800, quoting passcode: 5742370

Toll Free Callers: 800-408-3053, quoting passcode: 5742370

This follows the original announcement that they were on Review-Negative.

Affected issues are:

DBRS Mass Bank Downgrade
2009-6-29
Issue Old Rating New Rating
BMO.PR.H Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.J Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.K Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.L Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.M Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.N Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.O Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BMO.PR.P Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.J Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.K Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.L Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.M Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.N Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.O Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.P Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.Q Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.R Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.T Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
BNS.PR.X Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
CM.PR.A Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.D Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.E Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.G Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.H Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.I Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.J Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.K Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.L Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.M Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.P Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
CM.PR.R Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-1(low)
[Trend Negative]
HSB.PR.C Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-2(high)
[Trend Negative]
HSB.PR.D Pfd-1
[Trend Negative]
Pfd-2(high)
[Trend Negative]
LB.PR.D Pfd-3(high) Pfd-3(low)
LB.PR.E Pfd-3(high) Pfd-3(low)
NA.PR.K Pfd-1(low) Pfd-2
NA.PR.L Pfd-1(low) Pfd-2
NA.PR.M Pfd-1(low) Pfd-2
NA.PR.N Pfd-1(low) Pfd-2
NA.PR.O Pfd-1(low) Pfd-2
NA.PR.P Pfd-1(low) Pfd-2
RY.PR.A Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.B Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.C Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.D Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.E Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.F Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.G Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.H Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.I Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.L Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.N Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.P Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.R Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.T Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.W Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.X Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
RY.PR.Y Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.A Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.C Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.E Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.G Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.I Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.K Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.M Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.N Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.O Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.P Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.Q Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.R Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.S Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)
TD.PR.Y Pfd-1 Pfd-1(low)

The main effect of this, I feel, is the decreased notching between the top banks and the top insurers. Previously, MFC, SLF, PWF & GWO had been ranked a notch below the Big 5 … and I thought that was a little on the skimpy side. Now there’s no notching. Interesting…

Update: It is interesting to note that this is largely a reversal of the the October 2006 Mass Upgrade of Banks.

Interesting External Papers

Why are Most Funds Open-Ended?

This paper was highlighted in the BIS Annual Report, so I had a look.

The full title of the paper is Why are Most Funds Open-Ended? Competition and the Limits of Arbitrage:

The majority of asset-management intermediaries (e.g., mutual funds, hedge funds) are structured on an open-end basis, even though it appears that the open end form can be a serious impediment to arbitrage. I argue that the equilibrium degree of open-ending in an economy can be excessive from the point of view of investors. When funds compete for investors’ dollars, they may engage in a counterproductive race towards the open-end form, even though this form leaves them ill-suited to undertaking certain types of arbitrage trades. One implication of the analysis is that, even absent short-sales constraints or other frictions, economically large mispricings can coexist with rational, competitive arbitrageurs who earn small excess returns.

One implication of this is that the connection between arbitrageurs’ profits and overall market efficiency is very tenuous. In Example 1, the ex ante gross return to investors of 1.10 translates into a 2 percent annual alpha for professionally-managed money, assuming a five-year horizon. This looks relatively small, in keeping with the empirical evidence on the performance of fund managers. Yet this small alpha coexists with an infinitely elastic supply of the UC [Uncertain Convergence] asset, which can be thought of as having a price that deviates from fundamental value by a factor of three. Indeed, fund managers barely touch the UC asset, even though eventual convergence to fundamentals is assured, and there are no other frictions, such as trading costs or short-sales constraints. As noted in the introduction, this kind of story would seem to fit well with the unwillingness of hedge funds to bet heavily against the internet bubble of the late 1990s, by, e.g., taking an outright short position on the NASDAQ index—something which would certainly have been feasible to do at low cost from an execution/trading-frictions standpoint.

Footnote: Brunnermeier and Nagel (2003) give a nice illustration of the risks that hedge funds faced in betting against the internet bubble. They analyze the history of Julian Robertson’s Tiger Fund, which in early1999 eliminated all its investments in technology stocks (though it did not take an outright short position). By October 1999, the fund was forced to increase its redemption period from three to six months in an effort to stem outflows. By March 2000, outflows were so severe that the fund was liquidated—ironically, just as the bubble was about to burst.

The central point of this paper is easily stated. Asset-management intermediaries such as mutual funds and hedge funds compete for investors’ dollars, and one key dimension on which they compete is the choice of organizational form. In general, there is no reason to believe that this competition results in a form that is especially well-suited to the task of arbitrage. Rather, there is a tendency towards too much open-ending, which leaves funds unable to aggressively attack certain types of mispricing—i.e., those which do not promise to correct themselves quickly and smoothly. This idea may help to shed light on the arbitrage activities of another class of players: non-financial firms. Baker and Wurgler (2000) document that aggregate equity issuance by non-financial firms has predictive power for the stock market as a whole. And Baker, Greenwood and Wurgler (2003) show that such firms are also able to time the maturity of their debt issues so as to take advantage of changes in the shape of the yield curve. At first such findings appear puzzling. After all, even if one grants that managers have some insight into the future of their own companies, and hence can time the market for their own stock, it seems harder to believe that they would have an advantage over professional arbitrageurs in timing the aggregate stock and bond markets. However, there is another possible explanation for these phenomena. Even if managers of non-financial firms are less adept at recognizing aggregate-market mispricings than are professional money managers, they have an important institutional advantage—they conduct their arbitrage inside closed-end entities, with a very different incentive structure. For example, it was much less risky for the manager of an overpriced dot-com firm to place a bet against the internet bubble in 1999 (by undertaking an equity offering) than it was for a hedge-fund manager to make the same sort of bet. In the former case, if the market continued to rise, no visible harm would be done: the dot-com firm could just sit on the cash raised by the equity issue, and there would only be the subtle opportunity cost of not having timed the market even better. There would certainly be no worry about investors liquidating the firm as a result of the temporary failure of prices to converge to fundamentals.

There are some interesting corrollaries to the BIS desire for increased arbitrage:

  • Hedge Funds are Good
  • Shorting is Good
  • Credit Default Swaps are Good

One wonders how much consistency we may see in their views going forward!

Interesting External Papers

BIS Releases Annual Report

The Bank for International Settlements has released its Annual Report 2008-09; some of the policy recommendations are contentious!

One interesting reference is:

Moreover, managers of assets in a given asset class were rewarded for performance exceeding benchmarks representing average performance in that investment category. As a result, even if managers recognised a bubble in the price of some asset, they could not take advantage of that knowledge by selling short for fear that investors would withdraw funds. The result was herding that caused arbitrage to fail.

Footnote: For a discussion of how arbitrage fails when individual investors cannot distinguish good asset managers from bad ones, see J Stein, “Why are most funds open-end? Competition and the limits of arbitrage”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 120, no 1, February 2005, pp 247–72.

I’ll have to read that reference sometime!

The regulators continue to deflect blame for the crisis onto the Credit Rating Agencies:

In the end, the rating agencies– assigned the task of assessing the risk of fixed income securities and thus of guarding collective safety – became overwhelmed and, by issuing unrealistically high ratings, inadvertently contributed to the build-up of systemic risk.

Footnote: Differences in the methodologies used by the rating agencies also provided incentives for the originators to structure their asset-backed securities in ways that would allow them to “shop” for the best available combination of ratings (across both rating agencies and the liabilities structure of those instruments). See I Fender and J Kiff, “CDO rating methodology: some thoughts on model risk and its implications”, BIS Working Papers, no 163, November 2004.

Which is, of course, self-serving nonsense. It is the regulators who have been assigned the task of guarding collective safety. CRAs merely publish their opinions, the same way I do and the same way any idiot with access to the internet can do. As discussed by researchers at the Boston Fed in Making Sense of the Sub-Prime Crisis (which has been discussed on PrefBlog), the tail risk of sub-prime securities was well-known, well-publicized and ignored.

And as for their observation that:

And because of the complexity of the instruments, reliance on ratings increased even among the most sophisticated institutional investors.

… well, if I don’t understand something and can’t understand how to model it, I don’t buy it. I guess that makes me the most sophisticated investor in the world.

They do make one sensible observation:

Finally, there were governance problems in risk management practices. For both structural and behavioural reasons, senior managers and board members were neither asking the right questions nor listening to the right people. The structural problem was that risk officers did not have sufficient day-to-day contact with top decision-makers, often because they did not have sufficiently senior positions in their organisations. Without support from top management, it didn’t matter much what the chief risk officer said or to whom he or she said it. The structural problem was compounded by the behavioural response to a risk officer whose job it is to tell people to limit or stop what they are doing. If what they are doing is profitable, it is going to be difficult to get managers and directors to listen.

However, I don’t see anything addressing the obvious corrollory that bank size must be controlled, preferrably through the imposition of progressively increasing capital requirements based on size. After all, if all the big international banks disappeared, where would an intelligent and knowledgable BIS employee look to for future employment? To achieve the desired end, it’s probably better to insist on a greater and better paid head-count in the Risk Management division.

The recommendation that has attracted the most attention (e.g., a Reuters report) is:

Balancing innovation and safety in financial instruments requires providing scope for progress while limiting the capacity of any new instrument to weaken the system as a whole. Balance can be achieved by requiring some form of product registration that limits investor access to instruments according to their degree of safety. In a scheme analogous to the hierarchy controlling the availability of pharmaceuticals, the safest securities would, like non-prescription medicines, be available for purchase by everyone; next would be financial instruments available only to those with an authorisation, like prescription drugs; another level down would be securities available in only limited amounts to pre-screened individuals and institutions, like drugs in experimental trials; and, finally, at the lowest level would be securities that are deemed illegal. A new instrument would be rated or an existing one moved to a higher category of safety only after successful tests – the analogue of clinical trials. These would combine issuance in limited quantities in the real world with simulations of how the instrument would behave under severe stress.
Such a registration and certification system creates transparency and enhances safety. But, as in the case of pharmaceutical manufacturers, there must be a mechanism for holding securities issuers accountable for the quality of what they sell. This will mean that issuers bear increased responsibility for the risk assessment of their products.

In other words, if I want to sell you a product with a complex pay-out and you want to buy it … too bad; we’ll both go to jail on charges of not being smart enough. Similarly, if I sell you an investment product and you lose money, you can get your money back from me because it is quite obvious that I sold you something you’re not smart enough to buy.

I wonder what that little change will make to the deemed capitalization of securities firms!

Update, 2009-7-2: Regulation of product types endorsed by Willem Buiter:

What I have in mind is an FDA for new financial instruments and institutions. Like new medical treatments, drugs and pharmacological concoctions, new financial instruments, products and institutions are potentially socially useful. They can also be toxic and health-threatening.

Regulation

OSFI Seeks Comments on P&C Capitalization!

The Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions has announced:

The Office of the Superintendent of Financial Institutions and the Canadian P&C insurance industry are working together through the Minimum Capital Test (MCT) Advisory Committee to develop more advanced risk measurement techniques (internal models) for incorporation into the MCT / Branch Adequacy of Assets Test. These techniques will include the development of risk management and disclosure criteria for risk-sensitive methodologies for use by companies that have the commitment and resources to implement them.

The MCT Advisory Committee has developed and proposed a set of high level key principles to guide the development of a new capital framework. Please provide your comments by August 31, 2009.

This is significant. In the past I have harshly criticized OSFI’s lack of consultation. There’s no way of telling at this point whether this is genuine consultation or merely window-dressing, but it is undeniably a step forward.

The Key Principles are, unfortunately, so generic as to be useless. Like, f’rinstance:

Capital requirements should be risk-based.

It’s pretty hard to argue about that!

The section that might prove contentious is:

To allow market discipline, the meaning and methodology for, and the factual disclosure related to, regulatory capital and capital requirements should be transparent.

Assiduous Readers will know of my long-standing complaint about the lack of disclosure of the double-leverage inherent in the holdco/sub structure. The accompanying letter provides information regarding submission of comments:

For comments or questions, please contact Bernard Dupont at (613)990-7797 or bernard.dupont@osfi-bsif.gc.ca or Judith Roberge at (613) 990-4412 or judith.roberge@osfi-bsif.gc.ca.

I suggest that all those with an interest in the preferred shares issued by P&C holdcos (e.g., ELF.PR.F, ELF.PR.G) write in and suggest that ownership of a controlling interest in a P&C operating company be made conditional on the holdco publishing deconsolidated financial statements.

And, with respect to procedure, it will also be worthwhile to suggest that

  • All comments be made public
  • The response of the committee to the comments be published
Market Action

June 26, 2009

I weep for this world. In a move mocking the rule of law, British banks are being asked (told) to sign extra-legal agreements with the government:

Chancellor of the Exchequer Alistair Darling will put pressure on senior executives at Britain’s banks to sign agreements promising to end all tax avoidance, a person with knowledge of the plans said.

The Revenue and Customs wing of the Treasury on Monday will seek board level agreement from all U.K. banks and consult them on how to implement the plan, the person said. Banks refusing to sign the code will face more intrusive inspections from tax authorities.

The revenue office wants to change behavior to make sure banks comply with the the spirit as well as the letter of the law, the person said.

Fascism doesn’t usually come with fiery oration and jackboots. Fascism comes with earnest and well-meaning bureaucrats.

There might be some excitement in the CMBS business:

The ratings on $235.2 billion in debt backed by commercial mortgages may be cut by Standard & Poor’s as the ratings company seeks to reflect how the securities would fare in an “extreme economic downturn.”

The possible reductions, disclosed today in a report, follow S&P’s May 26 statement that the ratings of as much as 90 percent of top-ranked commercial mortgage-backed bonds sold in 2007 may be cut because of the changes in how they’re assessed.

However, as mentioned on June 15, there are plenty of other CRAs available for discriminating ratings-shoppers. That post also mentioned how NAIC wanted to regulate AND provide credit ratings; apparently some have pointed out that this is Not A Good Idea:

Dierdre Manna, vice president of industry, regulatory and political affairs for the Property Casualty Insurers Association of America (PCI), questioned whether transferring rating responsibilities to regulators comports with the NAIC’s mission statement.

She also questioned whether it would be possible for the NAIC to fully separate regulatory and rating agency responsibilities.

A totally insane idea; much like grading schools and universities on their proportion of passing students … er, wait, we do that don’t we? Never mind.

US Banks made some pretty good money on derivative trading in the first quarter:

• The notional value of derivatives held by U.S. commercial banks increased $1.6 trillion in the first quarter, or 1%, to $202.0 trillion, due to the continued migration of investment bank derivatives business into the commercial banking system.
• U.S. commercial banks generated record revenues of $9.8 billion trading cash and derivative instruments in the first quarter of 2009, compared to a $9.2 billion loss in the fourth quarter of 2008.
• Net current credit exposure decreased 13% to $695 billion.
• Derivative contracts remain concentrated in interest rate products, which comprise 84% of total derivative notional values. The notional value of credit derivative contracts decreased by 8% during the quarter to $14.6 trillion.

There’s an essay on Credit Rating Agencies on VoxEU today, by Marc Flandreau & Norbert Gaillard, titled Icarus’ syndrome: Rating agencies and the logic of regulatory license:

But again, this per se does not explain why rating agencies were privileged by regulators over other instruments to promote forbearance. For instance, regulators could have used bond prices at the time of issue as a possible alternative. Our investigation revealed that what caused the emergence of rating agencies as a pillar of regulation was the perceived conflict of interest that investment banks and commercial banks involved in origination suffered at the time. It was perceived that bankers were “banksters” and had been unable to resist conflicts of interest between their role as originators and their role as gatekeepers of liquidity. As a result, the public suspected that the prices at which securities had been issued were likely to have been manipulated. Certification and regulatory intervention had to rest on some assessment of “value” that would be as far away from the origination process as conceivable. Rating agencies provided just this.

The rest of the story is well known. In doing this, regulators dragged the agencies closer to the core of the origination of new securities, which eventually proved damaging for their reputation. While some will emphasise the irony of now blaming the agencies for the very sins that caused their emergence in the first place, we suggest that there must be deep reasons for history to go in circles. And whatever they are, the lesson must be that there is no long-run, simple, and sustainable regulatory fix for our current troubles.

Deep reasons? I don’t think it’s all that deep:

  • Doing a good job is not as important as one might hope. It’s all about sales.
  • Forecasting the future is fraught with pitfalls. Only a pack of MBAs would bet their company’s future on a single forecast.
  • The rating agencies are not paid to do a good job. Hardly anybody cares if they do a good job and even fewer are capable of evaluating ex ante whether they do a good job. They’re paid to be the fall-guy; they are now earning their pay.

PerpetualDiscounts took a break today, but FixedResets continued to rock ‘n’ roll. It’s astonishing! How low can yields on those suckers go? I’m amazed that a lot of new issuance isn’t being coaxed out of the woodwork … but if the price action is based on Current Yields rather than Yield-to-Worst (as I suspect is at least partially the case), perhaps it’s not as surprising as all that. Maybe it’s not even Current Yield – maybe it’s just the plain old coupon! It wouldn’t surprise me. mumble mumble … all these oh-so-clever quants running around, dividing one number by another number … I knew a quant once, he lost money.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.8481 % 1,206.4
FixedFloater 7.09 % 5.51 % 35,368 16.31 1 0.0000 % 2,126.6
Floater 3.16 % 3.54 % 75,606 18.42 3 -0.8481 % 1,507.1
OpRet 4.95 % 3.50 % 122,961 0.90 14 0.1832 % 2,205.0
SplitShare 5.75 % 6.36 % 68,280 4.21 3 0.2724 % 1,895.5
Interest-Bearing 6.00 % 2.21 % 22,898 0.08 1 1.3986 % 2,017.0
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.0043 % 1,740.2
Perpetual-Discount 6.34 % 6.37 % 161,335 13.42 71 -0.0043 % 1,602.7
FixedReset 5.65 % 4.73 % 491,750 4.35 40 0.3790 % 2,022.7
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -2.78 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 18.53
Evaluated at bid price : 18.53
Bid-YTW : 6.33 %
BAM.PR.B Floater -2.65 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 11.00
Evaluated at bid price : 11.00
Bid-YTW : 3.58 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -1.68 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 19.32
Evaluated at bid price : 19.32
Bid-YTW : 6.52 %
CM.PR.J Perpetual-Discount -1.51 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 17.63
Evaluated at bid price : 17.63
Bid-YTW : 6.39 %
IAG.PR.A Perpetual-Discount -1.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 17.26
Evaluated at bid price : 17.26
Bid-YTW : 6.71 %
BAM.PR.M Perpetual-Discount -1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 15.60
Evaluated at bid price : 15.60
Bid-YTW : 7.68 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount -1.03 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 18.22
Evaluated at bid price : 18.22
Bid-YTW : 6.45 %
RY.PR.L FixedReset 1.00 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.16
Bid-YTW : 4.65 %
NA.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 1.01 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 23.86
Evaluated at bid price : 24.06
Bid-YTW : 6.33 %
MFC.PR.D FixedReset 1.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.92
Bid-YTW : 4.96 %
RY.PR.R FixedReset 1.15 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.31
Bid-YTW : 4.25 %
RY.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.32 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 18.41
Evaluated at bid price : 18.41
Bid-YTW : 6.13 %
IAG.PR.C FixedReset 1.37 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.94
Bid-YTW : 5.29 %
STW.PR.A Interest-Bearing 1.40 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2009-07-26
Maturity Price : 10.00
Evaluated at bid price : 10.00
Bid-YTW : 2.21 %
SLF.PR.F FixedReset 1.50 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.40
Bid-YTW : 4.94 %
CM.PR.R OpRet 1.76 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2009-07-26
Maturity Price : 25.60
Evaluated at bid price : 26.00
Bid-YTW : -18.74 %
CIU.PR.B FixedReset 2.64 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-01
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.25
Bid-YTW : 4.84 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
GWO.PR.X OpRet 173,898 RBC crossed two blocks of 59,700 at 25.95 (in and out of inventory, maybe?); Scotia crossed 50,000 at the same price.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2010-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.67
Evaluated at bid price : 25.95
Bid-YTW : 3.81 %
BMO.PR.P FixedReset 142,900 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 23.18
Evaluated at bid price : 25.20
Bid-YTW : 5.05 %
BAM.PR.P FixedReset 32,815 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.51
Bid-YTW : 6.70 %
MFC.PR.D FixedReset 32,724 Nesbitt bought 14,800 from Scotia at 26.75.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.92
Bid-YTW : 4.96 %
TD.PR.S FixedReset 32,685 National bought 10,000 from anonymous at 24.95.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-26
Maturity Price : 24.83
Evaluated at bid price : 24.88
Bid-YTW : 4.52 %
NA.PR.O FixedReset 31,445 RBC bought 15,000 from TD at 27.05.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-17
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.06
Bid-YTW : 4.87 %
There were 41 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
Issue Comments

NEW.PR.C Closes

Newgrowth Corp. has announced:

that it has completed its public offering of Series 2 Class B Preferred Shares, (the “Preferred Shares”), raising approximately $ 30.7 million through the issuance of 2,238,510 Preferred Shares at a price of $ 13.70 per Preferred Share. The Preferred Shares were offered to the public by a syndicate of agents led by Scotia Capital Inc. The Preferred Shares were offered in order to maintain the leveraged “split share” structure of the Company following the successful reorganization of the Company approved by shareholders on May 11, 2009 which, among other things, extended the redemption date of the Capital Shares for an additional five year term. With the closing of the offering, there will be 2,238,510 Capital Shares and 2,238,510 Preferred Shares issued and outstanding on the close of business on June 26, 2009.

NewGrowth Corp. is a mutual fund corporation whose investment portfolio consists of publicly-listed securities of selected Canadian chartered banks and utility issuers. The Capital Shares and Preferred Shares of NewGrowth Corp. are both listed for trading on The Toronto Stock Exchange under the symbols NEW.A and NEW.PR.B respectively.

The issue pays $0.822 p.a., payable quarterly, for an issue yield on the issue price of 6.00%.

There is a monthly retraction feature:

A holder retracting Series 2 Preferred Shares will receive a cash price per Series 2 Preferred Share retracted equal to the amount, if any, by which 95% of the Unit Value exceeds the aggregate of (i) the average cost to the Company, including commissions, of purchasing a Class A Capital Share in the market; and (ii) $1.00. See “Retraction and Redemption of Series 2 Preferred Shares”.

… and annual calls at par until maturity:

Any outstanding Series 2 Preferred Shares will be redeemed by the Company on June 26, 2014 (the “Redemption Date”) at a price per share (the “Series 2 Preferred Share Redemption Price”) equal to the lesser of $13.70 and Unit Value.

Asset coverage is somewhere around 2.9:1 and DBRS has assigned a provisional rating of Pfd-2 on the issue; this seems a little conservative given the nature of the portfolio and the degree of asset coverage.

As previously discussed on PrefBlog, this issue refunds the NEW.PR.B. Sadly, the issue will not be tracked by HIMIPref™; it’s just too small.

Issue Comments

Empire Life Issued 6.73% Sub-Debt in May

Assiduous Readers with extremely good memories will remember that Empire Life was rated by DBRS in May, at which time I speculated that a new issue might be coming out.

Well, it did, but it was a private placement and I missed it. Their press release states:

The Empire Life Insurance Company (Empire Life) and E-L Financial Corporation Limited (E-L) (TSX:ELF)(TSX:ELF.PR.F)(TSX:ELF.PR.G) announced today that Empire Life offered in Canada, by way of private placement to accredited investors, $200 million principal amount of subordinated unsecured 6.73% fixed/floating debentures (Debentures) due May 20, 2019. The offering is expected to close May 20, 2009.

The Debentures will mature on May 20, 2019 and will bear interest at a fixed annual rate of 6.73% for the first five years, payable in equal semi-annual payments, and a variable annual rate equal to the three-month CDOR plus 5.75% for the last five years, payable quarterly. The Debentures have been provisionally rated “A (low)” with a stable trend by DBRS Limited.

The proceeds will be used for regulatory capital and general corporate purposes, and to repay a $125 million subordinated debenture issued to E-L (subject to approval by the Superintendent of Financial Institutions). The proceeds from the Debentures are expected to qualify as Tier 2B capital for regulatory purposes.

The issue has been offered on an agency basis by a syndicate of dealers co-led by RBC Dominion Securities Inc. and Scotia Capital Inc. Other syndicate members include: National Bank Financial Inc., TD Securities Inc., BMO Nesbitt Burns Inc., CIBC World Markets Inc. and HSBC Securities (Canada) Inc.

Impact of the debentures issue on financial strength

On a pro forma basis, the Company estimates that its Minimum Continuing Capital and Surplus Requirements (MCCSR) ratio would increase from 201% to 219% (as at March 31, 2009) following the issue of these Debentures and repayment of the E-L debenture.

Remember that as preferred shareholders in the holding company (ELF.PR.G, ELF.PR.F) we don’t care all that much about the MCCSR of the operating subsidiaries.

Interesting External Papers

BoE Releases June 2009 Financial Stability Report

The Bank of England has released its June Financial Stability Report filled with the usual tip-top commentary and analysis.

They open with a rather attention-grabbing chart showing their measure of financial market liquidity:

A number of steps towards “greater self insurance” are suggested; most of these a precious boiler-plate, but I was very pleased to see the inclusion of “constant net asset value MMMFs should be regulated as banks or forced to convert to variable net asset funds.” Section 3 fleshes out this idea a little more:

Measures to strengthen regulation and supervision will inevitably also increase avoidance incentives. Left unaddressed, this potentially poses risks for the future. Money market mutual funds (MMMFs) and structured investment vehicles (SIVs) are just two examples from the recent crisis of entities which contributed importantly to the build-up of risk in the financial system, but were not appropriately regulated. By offering to redeem their liabilities at par and effectively on demand, constant net asset value MMMFs in effect offer banking services to investors, without being regulated accordingly. The majority of the global industry comprises US domestic funds, with over US$3 trillion under management. During the crisis, as fears grew that these funds would not be able to redeem liabilities at par — so-called ‘breaking the buck’ — official sector interventions to support MMMFs were required. To guard against a recurrence, such funds need in future either to be regulated as banks or forced to convert into variable net asset value funds.

Footnote: In the United States, the Department of the Treasury has recently announced plans to strengthen the regulatory framework around MMMFs. The Group of Thirty, under Paul Volcker’s chairmanship, has recommended that MMMFs be recognised as special-purpose banks, with appropriate prudential regulation and supervision

They also make the rather breath-taking recommendation that: “The quality of banks’ capital buffers has fallen over time. In the future, capital buffers should comprise only common equity to increase banks’ capacity to absorb losses while remaining operational.” This would imply that Preferred Shares and Innovative Tier 1 Capital would not be included in Tier 1 Capital, if it is included in capital at all! In section 3, they elucidate:

The dilution of capital reduces banks’ ability to absorb losses.
Capital needs to be permanently available to absorb losses and banks should have discretion over the amount and timing of distributions. The only instrument reliably offering these characteristics is common equity. For that reason, the Bank favours a capital ratio defined exclusively in these terms — so-called core Tier 1 capital. This has increasingly been the view taken by market participants during the crisis, which is one reason why a number of global banks have undertaken buybacks and exchanges of hybrid instruments (Box 4).

Pre-committed capital insurance instruments and convertible hybrid instruments (debt which can convert to common equity) may also satisfy these characteristics. As such, these instruments could also potentially form an element of a new capital regime, provided banks and the authorities have appropriate discretion over their use. Taken together, these instruments might form part of banks’ contingent capital plans. There is a case for all banks drawing up such plans and regularly satisfying regulators that they can be executed. Subordinated debt should not feature as part of banks’ contingent capital plans, even though it may help to protect depositors in an insolvency.

There’s also an interesting chart showing bank assets as a percentage of GDP:

To my pleasure, they updated my favourite graph, the decomposition of corporate bond spreads. I had been under the impression that production of this graph had been halted pending review of the parameterization … wrong again!

They also show an interesting calculation of expected loss rates derived from CDS index data:

They also recommend a higher degree of risk-based deposit insurance:

Charging higher deposit insurance premia to riskier banks would go some way towards correcting this distortion. These premia should be collected every year, not only following a bank failure, so that risky banks incur the cost at the time when they are taking on the risk. That would also allow a deposit insurance fund to be built up. This could be used, as in the United States and other jurisdictions, to meet the costs of bank resolutions. It would also reduce the procyclicality of a pay-as-you-go deposit insurance scheme, which places greatest pressures on banks’ finances when they can least afford it. For these reasons, the Bank favours a pre-funded, risk-based deposit insurance scheme.

Canada has a pseudo-risk-based system; there are certainly tiers of defined risks, but the CDIC is proud of the fact that, basically, everybody fits into the bottom rung. The CDIC is also pre-funded (in theory) but the level of pre-funding is simply another feel-good joke.

Market Action

June 25, 2009

The populist movement against Wall Street is having the desired effect:

Wall Street’s largest trade group has started a campaign to counter the “populist” backlash against bankers, enlisting two former aides to Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson to spearhead the effort.

Michele Davis, Paulson’s former spokeswoman, and Jim Wilkinson, his former chief of staff, are among those leading the effort. SIFMA is paying their firm, Brunswick Group LLC, a monthly retainer of $70,000, the documents show. Both Davis and Wilkinson declined to comment. Paulson left office in January.

Assisting them is a Democratic polling company, Brilliant Corners Research and Strategies, which is paid $5,000 a month. It is run by pollster Cornell Belcher, who worked on President Barack Obama’s campaign. BKSH & Associates Worldwide, a lobbying firm chaired by Republican strategist Charlie Black, signed on for $10,000.

I’ve been figuring that Dubai would be the logical refuge for hedge funds made unwelcome in the G-7. But who knows? Maybe it’s Singapore:

Assan Din, a former Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. credit trader, is setting up a hedge fund to trade corporate bonds and derivatives in Asia.

SaKa Capital’s fund, which will have a capacity of more than $500 million, will start in September with $25 million to $50 million sourced mainly from founding members and friends, Din, 38, said. The Singapore-based firm will subsequently raise capital from institutional investors, including U.S. pension funds and endowments, once it builds a track record, he added.

A nice little bump in volume today, with a good solid up-day for preferreds. I suspect that some of the relatively short list of price movers were there because some players didn’t know (or didn’t care) that CM went ex-Dividend today.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.3170 % 1,216.7
FixedFloater 7.09 % 5.52 % 35,008 16.29 1 0.0000 % 2,126.6
Floater 3.13 % 3.48 % 77,919 18.56 3 -0.3170 % 1,520.0
OpRet 4.96 % 2.64 % 127,509 0.10 14 -0.0420 % 2,200.9
SplitShare 5.77 % 6.35 % 67,090 4.21 3 0.1819 % 1,890.3
Interest-Bearing 5.99 % 8.19 % 21,362 0.50 1 -0.1994 % 1,989.2
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1125 % 1,740.3
Perpetual-Discount 6.33 % 6.37 % 162,056 13.45 71 0.1125 % 1,602.8
FixedReset 5.67 % 4.77 % 498,361 4.35 40 0.2120 % 2,015.1
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
CIU.PR.B FixedReset -3.45 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-01
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.55
Bid-YTW : 5.45 %
BAM.PR.H OpRet -1.33 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2012-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.21
Bid-YTW : 5.43 %
NA.PR.N FixedReset -1.02 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 25.09
Evaluated at bid price : 25.14
Bid-YTW : 4.90 %
GWO.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.01 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 20.03
Evaluated at bid price : 20.03
Bid-YTW : 6.54 %
CM.PR.L FixedReset 1.10 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.94
Bid-YTW : 4.64 %
BAM.PR.J OpRet 1.10 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2018-03-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 22.10
Bid-YTW : 7.25 %
CM.PR.K FixedReset 1.13 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 25.15
Evaluated at bid price : 25.20
Bid-YTW : 4.94 %
ELF.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.14 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 16.80
Evaluated at bid price : 16.80
Bid-YTW : 7.24 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 1.32 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 18.41
Evaluated at bid price : 18.41
Bid-YTW : 6.39 %
PWF.PR.M FixedReset 1.34 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-03-02
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.40
Bid-YTW : 4.90 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.45 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 19.65
Evaluated at bid price : 19.65
Bid-YTW : 6.40 %
CM.PR.M FixedReset 1.45 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.87
Bid-YTW : 4.77 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BMO.PR.P FixedReset 318,203 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 23.14
Evaluated at bid price : 25.07
Bid-YTW : 5.08 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 74,912 Nesbitt crossed 13,400 at 18.42.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 18.41
Evaluated at bid price : 18.41
Bid-YTW : 6.39 %
CM.PR.M FixedReset 60,770 Global Securities (who?) crossed 17,100 at 27.38 (special settlement, I’m sure) and then crossed another 17,100 at 26.72 in what appears to be some kind of dividend capture scenario.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.87
Bid-YTW : 4.77 %
BNS.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 57,875 RBC crossed 20,600 at 18.75.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 18.60
Evaluated at bid price : 18.60
Bid-YTW : 6.16 %
TD.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 45,919 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-06-25
Maturity Price : 20.06
Evaluated at bid price : 20.06
Bid-YTW : 6.16 %
MFC.PR.E FixedReset 42,225 Recent new issue.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-19
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.16
Bid-YTW : 5.58 %
There were 56 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.