The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction

September 2nd, 2009

Mr Charles Bean, Deputy Governor for Monetary Policy and Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England, delivered the Schumpeter Lecture at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona, 25 August 2009.

Selections from the text of the lecture published by the Bank for International Settlements:

The first distortion…

Creditors – especially if they are households rather than
sophisticated financial market participants – may not even factor in the implications of higher leverage for the possibility of default. And even if they do, the debt may be partially or wholly underwritten by the state, with the cost of the insurance only imperfectly passed back to the bank. Similarly, the bank may be thought to be too important to be allowed to fail, in which case people might expect an injection of capital by the state to make good abnormal losses. In any of these cases, there is an incentive for the bank to raise leverage. Moreover, the lower is the perceived uncertainty associated with the loans, the more the bank can afford to leverage up, while maintaining the same uncertainty over the return on its capital. So the environment of the Great Moderation would have been particularly conducive to intermediaries increasing the leverage of their positions.

The second distortion…

Moreover, a considerable amount of the remaining risk was contained in institutions which, while not formally recognised as banks, engaged in exactly the same sort of maturity transformation, financing long-term assets by short-term debt instruments. These included entities such as conduits, which housed the securitised loans and then financed them by selling short-term paper. But in many cases these entities had back-up credit lines to the supporting bank, so that when funding difficulties arose, the securitised loans in effect came back onto the bank’s balance sheet. And even where there was no formal obligation to act as a lender of last resort, originators often chose to provide back-up finance in order to protect their name in funding markets.

The motive for setting up these off-balance-sheet entities was entirely one of regulatory arbitrage. Off-balance-sheet vehicles were not required to hold capital in the same way as a bank would if the loans were on their balance sheet. So it appeared to be a neat way to boost profits without having to raise more capital. The Banco d’España, the Spanish banking supervisor, insisted that Spanish banks would have to treat conduits and the like as on balance sheet for capital purposes. As a result, Spain did not see the mushrooming of these off-balance-sheet vehicles.

And the third distortion…

One unintended consequence of financial innovation was that it enabled clever traders to create positions with considerable embedded leverage – that is, portfolios requiring little payment up front, but whose returns amplified changes in the value of the underlying assets. Traders then had a natural incentive to gravitate towards these types of highly risky instruments.

A related problem is that it is extremely difficult for management to observe the risk being taken on by their traders, particularly when innovative financial instruments have unusual return distributions. Take, for example, a deeply out of the money option. This pays a steady income premium and has little variation in value when the underlying instrument is a long way from the strike price, but generates rapidly escalating losses in bad states of the world. In good times this looks like a high return, low risk instrument. Only in very bad states of the world do the true risks taken on become apparent.

Knightian uncertainty about CDO returns increased information problems:

A typical CDO comprises a large number and variety of RMBS, including a mix of prime and sub-prime mortgages from a variety of originators. On the face of it, this might seem like a good thing as it creates diversification. However, even more than with plain vanilla RMBS, it becomes impossible to monitor the evolution of the underlying risks – it is akin to trying to unpick the ingredients of a sausage. That may not matter too much when defaults are low and only the holders of the first, equity, tranche suffer any losses. Holders of the safer tranches can in that case sit back and relax – a case of rational inattention. But once defaults begin to rise materially, it matters a lot what such a security contains. And with highly non-linear payoffs, returns can be extremely sensitive to small changes in underlying conditions.
When defaults on some US sub-prime mortgages originated in 2006 and 2007 started turning out much higher than expected, there was a realisation that losses could be much greater on some of these securities than previously believed. And a growing realisation of the informational complexity of these securities made them difficult to price in an objective sense. Essentially, investors switched from believing that returns behaved according to a tight and well-behaved distribution to one in which they had very little idea about the likely distribution of returns – a state of virtual Knightian uncertainty (Caballero and Krishnamurthy, 2008).

So who’s to blame?

First, in my view it would be a mistake to look for a single guilty culprit. Underestimation of risk born of the Great Moderation, loose monetary policy in the United States and a perverse pattern of international capital flows together provided fertile territory for the emergence of a credit/asset-price bubble. The creation of an array of complex new assets that were supposed to spread risk more widely ended up destroying information about the scale and location of losses, which proved to be crucial when the market turned. And an array of distorted incentives led the financial system to build up excessive leverage, increasing the vulnerabilities when asset prices began to fall. As in Agatha Christie’s Murder on the Orient Express, everyone had a hand in it.

September 1, 2009

September 1st, 2009

Guillermo Calvo of Columbia University writes an interesting piece for VoxEU, Dumping Russia in 1998 and Lehman ten years later: Triple time-inconsistency episodes:

This column introduces “triple time-inconsistent” episodes. First, a public institution is expected to cave in and offer a bailout to prevent a crisis. Then, in an attempt to regain credibility, it pulls back. Finally, it resumes bailing out the survivors of the wreckage caused by the policy surprise. This column characterises the 1998 Russian crisis and the current crisis as triple time-inconsistency episodes and says that a financial crisis may simply be a bad time to try to build credibility.

It is far from me to chastise or ridicule those involved in triple time inconsistency. There are always good reasons why bright and well-intentioned public officials make serious mistakes during major crises. The two cases singled out in this note took place in arguably “unprecedented” circumstances. In situations like these, “shooting from the hip” becomes the rule, and errors are to be expected. However, I believe that there are at least two lessons that we could draw from these episodes, which could help to lower the incidence of triple time inconsistency and other inefficiencies:

  • •A financial crisis is not the best time for reform or building credibility, especially if those actions go against the private sector’s expectations. Policymakers should focus their attention on putting out the fires and minimise the short-run social costs.
  • •Policymakers should spend more time discussing worst-case scenarios before crises occur. These discussions should be carried out with some regularity (much like fire drills) and involve a wide spectrum of public officials that might eventually have to be involved in rescue operations during crisis. This will ensure a better understanding of the involved risks and tradeoffs, and improve the effectiveness of policies that need to be implemented in the spur of a moment.

Fat chance of the second one! When was the last time you saw a ten-year government deficit projection that included a discussion of the projected effects of a severe recession?

CIT is going to defer interest payments on its sub-debt:

Commercial lender CIT Group Inc. said in a regulatory filing Tuesday it will defer interest payments on some outstanding junior notes.

CIT was to make the next interest payment on the junior notes on Sept. 15, according to the Securities and Exchange Commission filing. The deferred interest will continue to accrue and compound until payments are made, the company said.

Interest is being deferred on junior subordinated notes due March 15, 2067.

Deferring interest payments can help CIT Group continue to reduce its near-term debt burden, furthering its efforts to remain in business after nearly collapsing earlier in the year.

The SEC filing on CIT’s site is copy-protected – idiots.

The Boston Fed has published an interesting paper by Katharine Bradbury and Jane Katz, Trends in U.S. Family Income Mobility, 1967-2004:

Using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and a number of mobility concepts and measures drawn from the literature, we examine mobility levels and trends for U.S. working-age families, overall and by race, during the time span 1967–2004. By most measures, we find that mobility is lower in more recent periods (the 1990s into the early 2000s) than in earlier periods (the 1970s). Most notably, mobility of families starting near the bottom has worsened over time. However, in recent years, the down-trend in mobility is more or less pronounced (or even non-existent) depending on the measure, although a decrease in the frequency with which panel data on family incomes are gathered makes it difficult to draw firm conclusions. Measured relative to the overall distribution or in absolute terms, black families exhibit substantially less mobility than whites in all periods; their mobility decreased between the 1970s and the 1990s, but no more than that of white families, although they lost ground in terms of relative income.

Taken together, this evidence suggests that over the 1967-to-2004 time span, a low-income family’s probability of moving up decreased, families’ later year incomes increasingly depended on their starting place, and the distribution of families’ lifetime incomes became less equal.

It should be noted, however, that:

We do not address shorter‐term “volatility”—shocks to family incomes from year to year—or longer‐term “intergenerational mobility”—how much a person’s adult family income level (or position) depends on the level (position) of his/her parents during childhood.

This is a shame, because it the latter measure that I find to be of most interest. The authors conclude, in part:

What are the implications for policy? Because we find no evidence to suggest that the typical poor family is more likely to move up and out of poverty within several years than it was 40 years ago, policy remedies for those at the bottom should aim beyond short‐term help, as the poor at any point in time are likely to have low long‐term incomes. Beyond short‐term relief, the choice of policy presumably hinges, at least in part, on the reasons for the decline in mobility, for example, whether it reflects rising barriers to opportunity or rising returns to highstakes labor market promotion practices, including tournament‐style regimes common in the professions.

I’m not sure how to take this report. It sees to me that the results could come from increased efficiency in determining the starting point – e.g., you get that good job right out of school instead of having to pay your dues for twenty years and waiting for your supervisor to die. As I noted, I am far more concerned by inter-generational income mobility.

Volume picked up a little today, but the market didn’t, really, with PerpetualDiscounts down 19bp and FixedResets up 5bp. Just to make things more confusing, PerpetualPremiums were up 11bp … geez, it’s nice to see a healthy population in that slot!

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.7311 % 1,446.6
FixedFloater 5.72 % 4.00 % 61,030 18.60 1 -0.0526 % 2,683.1
Floater 2.52 % 2.15 % 32,002 22.07 4 -0.7311 % 1,807.2
OpRet 4.86 % -13.60 % 128,783 0.09 15 0.0765 % 2,281.9
SplitShare 6.42 % 6.55 % 1,244,765 4.08 2 -0.5063 % 2,061.2
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.0765 % 2,086.6
Perpetual-Premium 5.73 % 5.34 % 152,079 2.55 12 0.1083 % 1,890.0
Perpetual-Discount 5.68 % 5.69 % 194,740 14.36 59 -0.1854 % 1,809.1
FixedReset 5.50 % 4.01 % 478,982 4.11 40 0.0480 % 2,105.2
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
SLF.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -1.83 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 20.88
Evaluated at bid price : 20.88
Bid-YTW : 5.76 %
TRI.PR.B Floater -1.81 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 19.00
Evaluated at bid price : 19.00
Bid-YTW : 2.09 %
CM.PR.P Perpetual-Discount -1.44 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 22.94
Evaluated at bid price : 24.00
Bid-YTW : 5.75 %
CM.PR.E Perpetual-Discount -1.29 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 24.11
Evaluated at bid price : 24.40
Bid-YTW : 5.80 %
SLF.PR.C Perpetual-Discount -1.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 19.51
Evaluated at bid price : 19.51
Bid-YTW : 5.71 %
CM.PR.R OpRet -1.19 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2009-10-01
Maturity Price : 25.60
Evaluated at bid price : 26.46
Bid-YTW : -28.10 %
BMO.PR.K Perpetual-Discount -1.14 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 23.21
Evaluated at bid price : 23.38
Bid-YTW : 5.65 %
BNS.PR.J Perpetual-Discount -1.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 22.62
Evaluated at bid price : 23.54
Bid-YTW : 5.60 %
BNA.PR.D SplitShare -1.08 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2014-07-09
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.75
Bid-YTW : 6.55 %
BAM.PR.N Perpetual-Discount -1.03 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 18.34
Evaluated at bid price : 18.34
Bid-YTW : 6.61 %
BNS.PR.N Perpetual-Discount -1.01 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 23.38
Evaluated at bid price : 23.56
Bid-YTW : 5.64 %
CIU.PR.B FixedReset 1.05 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-01
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 28.00
Bid-YTW : 4.01 %
NA.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.60 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 21.65
Evaluated at bid price : 21.65
Bid-YTW : 5.66 %
BAM.PR.I OpRet 1.80 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2009-10-01
Maturity Price : 25.75
Evaluated at bid price : 26.02
Bid-YTW : 3.65 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
TD.PR.E FixedReset 242,062 TD crossed two blocks, 100,000 and 123,500 shares, both at 27.65. Nice tickets!
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.65
Bid-YTW : 3.96 %
BAM.PR.P FixedReset 50,620 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.52
Bid-YTW : 6.05 %
BAM.PR.B Floater 46,079 TD crossed 20,000 at 12.60.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 12.52
Evaluated at bid price : 12.52
Bid-YTW : 3.17 %
BAM.PR.N Perpetual-Discount 43,059 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 18.34
Evaluated at bid price : 18.34
Bid-YTW : 6.61 %
SLF.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 39,733 Scotia crossed 20,200 at 19.50.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-09-01
Maturity Price : 19.51
Evaluated at bid price : 19.51
Bid-YTW : 5.71 %
CM.PR.L FixedReset 34,757 RBC crossed 23,000 at 27.80.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.71
Bid-YTW : 4.15 %
There were 34 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

ES.PR.B: Small Call for Redemption

September 1st, 2009

Energy Split Corp. has announced:

that it has called 31,450 Preferred Shares for cash redemption on September 16, 2009 (in accordance with the Company’s Articles) representing approximately 1.592% of the outstanding Preferred Shares as a result of the special annual retraction of 220,106 Capital Shares by the holders thereof. The Preferred Shares shall be redeemed on a pro rata basis, so that each holder of Preferred Shares of record on September 15, 2009 will have approximately 1.592% of their Preferred Shares redeemed. The redemption price for the Preferred Shares will be $21.00 per share.

Holders of Preferred Shares that are on record for dividends but have been called for redemption will be entitled to receive dividends thereon which have been declared but remain unpaid up to but not including September 16, 2009.

Payment of the amount due to holders of Preferred Shares will be made by the Company on September 16, 2009.

ES.PR.B was last mentioned on PrefBlog when it was upgraded to Pfd-4(low) by DBRS. They closed today at 17.61-00, 15×2, so the redemption price is a small bonus to holders who don’t mind having their board lots broken up.

ES.PR.B is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

CGI.PR.B & CGI.PR.C: Manager Still Cautious on Capital Unit Dividend

September 1st, 2009

Morgan Meighan has announced (emphasis added):

Canadian General Investments, Limited (the Company) has declared an “estimated” regular quarterly cash dividend of $0.06 per share payable on September 15, 2009 to common shareholders of record at the close of business on September 10, 2009.

The dividend is being filed with the TSX as an “estimated dividend” as a result of a dividend payment restriction contained in the Company’s Class A, Series 2 and Series 3 Preference Share provisions. This restriction provides that the Company shall not pay a dividend on its common shares unless after giving effect thereto, the ratio of its Assets to Obligations (both as defined in the Preference Share provisions) exceeds 2.5 times. Although the coverage ratio as at the close of business on August 31, 2009 was approximately 3.3 times, as a result of market conditions, it is not certain at today’s date whether the Company will still meet the coverage requirement on September 15, 2009.

The Company will make a further announcement regarding payment prior to September 15, 2009. In the event that payment of the common share dividend is deferred, the dividend will be paid to registered shareholders as of the original record date at such later time as the Company determines that it can properly be paid.

The wording follows that of the June declaration (3.0x); March declaration (2.6x) and the December declaration reported on PrefBlog (2.6x).

The caution seems excessive to me, but is prudent. I bet next time they write a prospectus it will be made clear that the asset test applies at the time of declaration, not the time of payment!

CGI.PR.B & CGI.PR.C were last mentioned on PrefBlog when they were downgraded to Pfd-1(low) by DBRS following a methodological change. Both are tracked by HIMIPref™ but are relegated to the “Scraps” index on volume concerns.

Sheila Bair Writes Op-Ed on Super-Regulator

September 1st, 2009

Sheila Bair, head of the FDIC has written a New York Times op-ed piece, The Case Against a Super-Regulator:

The truth is, no regulatory structure — be it a single regulator as in Britain or the multiregulator system we have in the United States — performed well in the crisis.

The principal enablers of our current difficulties were institutions that took on enormous risk by exploiting regulatory gaps between banks and the nonbank shadow financial system, and by using unregulated over-the-counter derivative contracts to develop volatile and potentially dangerous products.

The reference to derivative contracts and shadow banks is almost certainly made with AIG specifically in mind. Assiduous Readers will know that I have no problems with these two things … what made AIG a systemic threat was regulatory incompetence that allowed regulated institutions to have a lot of AIG paper on their books without sufficient collateral or capital charges.

We can’t put all our eggs in one basket. The risk of weak or misdirected regulation would be increased if power was consolidated in a single federal regulator.

Hear, hear!

One advantage of our multiple-regulator system is that it permits diverse viewpoints. The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation voiced strong concerns about the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision’s relatively relaxed rules for determining how much capital banks should have on hand.

If I remember correctly, it was the FDIC that insisted that the leverage ratio be maintained as a regulatory measure.

Index Performance: August 2009

September 1st, 2009

Performance of the HIMIPref™ Indices for Performance, 2009, was:

Total Return
Index Performance
August 2009
Three Months
to
August 31, 2009
Ratchet +19.52% * +12.73% *
FixFloat +24.66% +28.42%
Floater +19.52% +12.73%
OpRet +1.31% +5.23%
SplitShare +4.32% +13.37%
Interest +1.31%**** +5.34%****
PerpetualPremium +2.09% +9.74%***
PerpetualDiscount +6.42% +14.39%
FixedReset +0.47% +6.31%
* The last member of the RatchetRate index was transferred to Scraps at the February, 2009, rebalancing; subsequent performance figures are set equal to the Floater index
*** The last member of the PerpetualPremium index was transferred to PerpetualDiscount at the October, 2008, rebalancing; subsequent performance figures are set equal to the PerpetualDiscount index. The PerpetualPremium index acquired four new members at the July, 2009, rebalancing.
**** The last member of the InterestBearing index was transferred to Scraps at the June, 2009, rebalancing; subsequent performance figures are set equal to the OperatingRetractible index
Passive Funds (see below for calculations)
CPD +3.11% +8.03%
DPS.UN +5.71% +12.93%
Index
BMO-CM 50 +4.76% +11.19%

PerpetualDiscounts had a very good month, moving their trailing one-year performance decisively into the black, while the weaknesses of the FixedReset asset class (relatively recently issued at their call price with a near-term call for the issuer) started to make themselves apparent. At the median YTW of about 4%, expected monthly return is about 0.33% and they did better than that this month. I suspect that any significant future gains in index value will result from capture of new-issue concessions … but with forty member in the index that won’t amount to much, and the recent new issue announcements (BPO 6.75%+417, DC, 6.75%+410, WES Convertible, ETC, 7.25%+453) have been of relatively low credit quality.

I won’t make any bets on where the next preferred share market unhappiness is going to come from … but I’ll make a guess!

Meanwhile, Floaters continued their wild ride.


Click for big

Update Oopsy! I forgot to change the label for the y-axis in the above graph … total returns are normalized to 2008-08-29 = 100.0.

The calculation of the Median Average Trading Value for the FixedReset index is plagued by technical factors and cannot be considered the most reliable statistic in the world – but a downward trend as prior issues become seasoned and the flood of new issues turns to a trickle (which has both a technical effect and a real effect: a constant stream of new issues can keep an entire market liquid) is quite apparent. When they first appeared, I suspected that they would eventually become significantly less liquid than PerpetualDiscounts … not there yet, not even close, but we will see!


Click for big

Claymore has published NAV and distribution data (problems with the page in IE8 can be kludged by using compatibility view) for its exchange traded fund (CPD) and I have derived the following table:

CPD Return, 1- & 3-month, to August, 2009
Date NAV Distribution Return for Sub-Period Monthly Return
May 29, 2009 15.88 0.00    
June 25 15.88 0.2100 +1.32% +1.38%
June 30, 2009 15.89   +0.06%
July 31, 2009 16.42     +3.35%
August 31, 2009 16.93 0.00   +3.11%
Quarterly Return +8.03%

Claymore currently holds $275,986,648 (advisor & common combined) in CPD assets, a stunning increase from the $84,005,161 reported in the Dec 31/08 Annual Report.

The DPS.UN NAV for August 26 has been published so we may calculate the approximate August returns.

DPS.UN NAV Return, August-ish 2009
Date NAV Distribution Return for period
Estimated July Ending Stub -0.61% *
July 29, 2009 19.03    
August 26, 2009 20.30   +6.67%
Estimated August Ending Stub -0.29% **
Estimated August Return +5.71%
* CPD had a NAV of $16.32 on July 29 and a NAV of $16.42 on July 31. The return for the period was therefore +0.61%. This figure is subtracted from the DPS.UN period return to arrive at an estimate for the calendar month.
** CPD had a NAV of $16.98 on August 26 and a NAV of $16.93 on August 31. The return for the period was therefore -0.29%. This figure is added to the DPS.UN period return to arrive at an estimate for the calendar month.
The August return for DPS.UN’s NAV is therefore the product of three period returns, -0.61%, +6.67% and -0.29% to arrive at an estimate for the calendar month of +5.71%

Now, to see the DPS.UN quarterly NAV approximate return, we refer to the calculations for June and July:

DPS.UN NAV Returns, three-month-ish to end-August-ish, 2009
June-ish +2.28%
July-ish +4.45%
August-ish +5.71%
Three-months-ish +12.93%

HIMIPref™ Index Rebalancing: August 2009

September 1st, 2009
HIMI Index Changes, August 31, 2009
Issue From To Because
TRI.PR.B Scraps FloatingRate Volume
PWF.PR.A Scraps FloatingRate Volume
CGI.PR.B SplitShare Scraps Volume
RY.PR.H PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
CL.PR.B PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
GWO.PR.F PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
NA.PR.M PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
NA.PR.K PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
BNS.PR.O PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
PWF.PR.I PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price
TD.PR.Q PerpetualDiscount PerpetualPremium Price

The PerpetualPremium index is filling up nicely and now has twelve members! It disappeared at the October 2008 Rebalancing, when CL.PR.B fell below 25.00.

There were the following intra-month changes:

HIMI Index Changes during August 2009
Issue Action Index Because
BMT.PR.A Delete Scraps Redeemed

Best & Worst Performers: August 2009

August 31st, 2009

These are total returns, with dividends presumed to have been reinvested at the bid price on the ex-date. The list has been restricted to issues in the HIMIPref™ indices.

August 2009
Issue Index DBRS Rating Monthly Performance Notes (“Now” means “August 31”)
IGM.PR.A OpRet Pfd-2(high) -3.34% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of -23.52% based on a bid of 26.54 and a call 2009-9-30 at 26.00.
NA.PR.N FixedReset Pfd-2 -1.61% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 3.99% based on a bid of 26.32 and a call 2013-9-14 at 26.32.
BAM.PR.P FixedReset Pfd-2(low) -0.75% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.16% based on a bid of 26.40 and a call 2014-10-30 at 25.00.
BNS.PR.R FixedReset Pfd-1(low) -0.42% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.32% based on a bid of 25.79 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.G FixedReset Pfd-1(low) -0.29% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 3.99% based on a bid of 27.62 and a call 2014-5-30 at 25.00.
BAM.PR.N Perpetual-Discount Pfd-2(low) +12.92% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.54% based on a bid of 18.53 and a limitMaturity.
IAG.PR.A Perpetual-Discount Pfd-2(high) +13.05% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.76% based on a bid of 20.00 and a limitMaturity.
BAM.PR.B Floater Pfd-2(low) +19.22%
BAM.PR.K Floater Pfd-2(low) +19.81%
BAM.PR.G FixFloat Pfd-2(low) +24.66%

August 31, 2009

August 31st, 2009

Spend-Every-Penny has declared:

As the United States and other countries debate giving more authority to central banks and other regulatory agencies, [Spend-Every-Penny] Sunday said he is sticking with his current approach to systemic oversight, which brings together the heads of the Bank of Canada, the federal banking regulator and other key authorities on a regular basis to compare notes. The decision means a previously obscure grouping of senior officials – the Financial Institutions Supervisory Committee – will be thrust into the spotlight as Canada’s answer to the pledge the federal government and its allies in the Group of 20 made to correct regulatory failings that contributed to the financial crisis.

[Spend-Every-Penny] made clear that even though unelected public servants will play crucial roles, responsibility for ensuring that Canada stays out of financial trouble rests with him.

There’s a very good chance that there won’t be another major banking crisis before he retires, so it’s a pretty safe way to appear tough and authoritative. In most countries, however, the idea that the politicians are ultimately responsible for the performance of their appointees is generally understood. I can’t find a public copy of the speech anywhere, by the way. I hope Spend-Every-Penny won’t be so shy when something bad happens … but I won’t bet on it.

I see that Toronto, well known for its inability to license a souvlaki cart in less than three years is attempting to create a bigger sink-hole than the one on Finch Avenue by bidding to host the Pan-Am games. Send in the clowns!

I noted on March 23 that Liddy, the last CEO of AIG, demonstrated his lack of qualification for the office by throwing his people to the wolves during the bonus controversy. The new guy, Benmosche, is much better:

Benmosche criticized Cuomo and lawmakers during a town-hall style meeting this month for life insurance workers in Houston. Cuomo subpoenaed AIG in March during a national furor about $165 million in retention bonuses sent after the firm’s bailout and said those who returned the cash wouldn’t have their names published. That month, some employees received death threats and protesters visited the Connecticut homes of two AIG executives.

“What he did is so unbelievably wrong,” Benmosche said during the Aug. 11 remarks, according to a record obtained by Bloomberg. “He doesn’t deserve to be in government, and he surely shouldn’t be the attorney general of the state of New York. What he did is criminal. You don’t create lynch mobs to go out to people’s homes and do the things he did.”

Speaking of bonuses…:

U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission Chairman Mary Schapiro, in a letter to brokerage chiefs, warned that burgeoning recruitment bonuses may push employees to engage in improper sales and trades.

Large, up-front bonuses and enhanced commissions may lead brokers “to believe they must sell securities at a sufficiently high level to justify special arrangements,” she wrote today. “Those pressures may in turn create incentives to engage in conduct that may violate obligations to investors.”

Brokers may be motivated to make excessive trades to generate fees, a process known as churning, Schapiro said. They might recommend products that don’t suit their clients’ objectives or generate fees with transactions that aren’t in their customers’ interest, Schapiro said.

Warning! Increased political scrutiny may lead regulators to believe they must make gratuitously precious statements about activities that are already illegal.

Volume ticked upward today, but the market ended a very good month on a sour note, with PerpetualDiscounts losing 13bp and FixedResets down 14bp. The latter may be related to the BPO new issue.

PerpetualDiscounts closed with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.66%, equivalent to 7.92% interest at the standard equivalency factor of 1.4x. Long Corporates closed the month with a yield of about 5.95% (after generating +2.83% total return in August), implying that the pre-tax interest-equivalent spread remains at about 200bp.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.3957 % 1,457.2
FixedFloater 5.72 % 4.00 % 60,880 18.60 1 0.4757 % 2,684.5
Floater 3.13 % 3.16 % 174,664 19.27 2 -0.3957 % 1,820.5
OpRet 4.86 % -10.56 % 132,541 0.09 15 0.1285 % 2,280.1
SplitShare 5.67 % 3.97 % 98,723 0.08 3 -0.3891 % 2,056.3
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1285 % 2,085.0
Perpetual-Premium 5.69 % 5.10 % 69,784 2.60 4 0.5453 % 1,888.0
Perpetual-Discount 5.68 % 5.66 % 188,811 14.31 67 -0.1288 % 1,812.5
FixedReset 5.50 % 4.00 % 483,272 4.12 40 -0.1369 % 2,104.2
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
BAM.PR.P FixedReset -3.83 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.40
Bid-YTW : 6.16 %
POW.PR.D Perpetual-Discount -2.74 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-08-31
Maturity Price : 21.37
Evaluated at bid price : 21.65
Bid-YTW : 5.85 %
BAM.PR.I OpRet -2.63 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Soft Maturity
Maturity Date : 2013-12-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.56
Bid-YTW : 5.19 %
MFC.PR.B Perpetual-Discount -1.94 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-08-31
Maturity Price : 20.27
Evaluated at bid price : 20.27
Bid-YTW : 5.76 %
NA.PR.L Perpetual-Discount -1.39 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-08-31
Maturity Price : 21.31
Evaluated at bid price : 21.31
Bid-YTW : 5.75 %
CIU.PR.B FixedReset -1.39 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-01
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.71
Bid-YTW : 4.26 %
GWO.PR.E OpRet 1.16 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2009-09-30
Maturity Price : 25.50
Evaluated at bid price : 26.21
Bid-YTW : -30.79 %
BNS.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 1.20 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2017-05-26
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.30
Bid-YTW : 5.53 %
CM.PR.R OpRet 1.79 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2009-09-30
Maturity Price : 25.60
Evaluated at bid price : 26.78
Bid-YTW : -40.35 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
BAM.PR.P FixedReset 44,640 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-10-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.40
Bid-YTW : 6.16 %
BMO.PR.L Perpetual-Premium 43,803 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2017-06-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.15
Bid-YTW : 5.76 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 30,940 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-08-31
Maturity Price : 20.70
Evaluated at bid price : 20.70
Bid-YTW : 5.75 %
RY.PR.Y FixedReset 26,300 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-12-24
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.50
Bid-YTW : 4.07 %
BNS.PR.X FixedReset 23,568 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-25
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.82
Bid-YTW : 3.82 %
BAM.PR.N Perpetual-Discount 23,507 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2039-08-31
Maturity Price : 18.53
Evaluated at bid price : 18.53
Bid-YTW : 6.54 %
There were 44 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.

A Financial Conditions Index for the US

August 31st, 2009

The Bank of Canada has announced a new discussion paper by Kimberly Beaton, René Lalonde, and Corinne Luu, A Financial Conditions Index for the United States:

The financial crisis of 2007–09 has highlighted the importance of developments in financial conditions for real economic activity. The authors estimate the effect of current and past shocks to financial variables on U.S. GDP growth by constructing two growth based financial conditions indexes (FCIs) that measure the contribution to quarterly (annualized) GDP growth from financial conditions. One FCI is constructed using a structural vector-error correction model and the other is constructed using a large-scale macroeconomic model. The authors’ results suggest that financial factors subtracted around 5 percentage points from quarterly annualized real GDP growth in the United States in 2008Q4 and 2009Q1 and should subtract another 5 percentage points from growth in 2009Q2. Moreover, to assess the effect of financial shocks in terms of policy interest rate equivalent units, the authors convert the effect of financial developments on growth into the number of basis points by which the federal funds rate has been tightened. The authors show that the tightening of financial conditions since mid-2007 is equivalent to about 300 basis points of tightening in terms of the federal funds rate. Thus, the aggressive monetary easing undertaken by the Federal Reserve over the financial crisis has not been sufficient to offset the tightening of financial conditions. Finally, in a key contribution to the literature, the authors assess the relationship between financial shocks and real activity in the context of the zero lower bound. They find that the effect of the tightening of financial conditions on GDP growth in the current crisis may have been amplified by as much as 40 per cent due to the fact that policy interest rates reached the zero lower bound.

In particular, our MFCI adjusted for the binding lower bound suggests that financial factors subtracted around 5 percentage points from quarterly annualized growth in 2008Q4 and 2009Q1. Moreover, in order to assess the effect of financial shocks in terms of policy interest rate equivalent units, we have converted the effect of financial developments on growth into the number of basis points by which the federal funds rate has been tightened. The results suggest that the net tightening of financial conditions since mid-2007 is equivalent to about 300 basis points of tightening in terms of the federal funds rate, despite the actual 500 basis point decline in the policy rate. Given the ongoing disruptions in financial markets, the degree of tightening of price and non-price credit conditions and the substantial losses in wealth over 2008, and the long transmission lags between a shock to financial conditions and its impact on the real economy, these financial conditions are expected to continue to dampen growth going forward.