Issue Comments

FTS: DBRS Assigns Positive Trend

DBRS has announced that it:

confirmed the Unsecured Debentures and Preferred Shares ratings of Fortis Inc. (Fortis or the Company) at BBB (high) and Pfd-3 (high), respectively, and changed the trends to Positive from Stable. The trend change is largely driven by the Company’s low business risk profile (benefiting from its ownership of a diversified basket of utility businesses which provide over 90% of consolidated EBITDA), its strong credit metrics (which have improved modestly over the years), the significant reduction in external debt at subsidiary Terasen Inc. (Terasen) and the Company’s demonstrated ability to acquire and integrate stable utility businesses financed on a conservative basis.

Capital expenditures at the regulated utilities are subject to regulatory approval. It is anticipated that the majority of capital expenditures will be funded at the subsidiary level, with a combination of internally generated cash, operating company-level debt and equity from Fortis (expected to average $100 million annually for the next five years) to fund capital build-out programs, while maintaining their respective regulated capital structures. DBRS views the level of Fortis’s equity injections as reasonable, and does not anticipate that the Company will use debt to fund the injections, thereby avoiding double leverage.

DBRS will consider an upgrade to the Unsecured Debentures and Preferred Shares ratings if Fortis continues to exhibit strong financial and operating performance and maintain its conservative financial practices; barring any materially negative regulatory actions at the operating subsidiaries, or mergers and acquisitions activity financed on an aggressive basis.

Fortis’ preferreds are rated Pfd-3(high) by DBRS. S&P rates Series D, E and H as P-2; Series C is also rated P-2, but S&P seems to think that these are denominated in USD.

Fortis has five series of preferred shares outstanding: FTS.PR.C (OpRet); FTS.PR.E (OpRet); FTS.PR.F (PerpetualDiscount); FTS.PR.G (FixedReset) and FTS.PR.H (FixedReset). All are tracked by HIMIPref™ and all have been relegated to the Scraps index on credit concerns.

Market Action

June 7, 2010

There’s some hasty back-pedalling in Hungary:

“Any comparison with countries that have much higher credit default swap ratings than Hungary is unfortunate,” State Secretary Mihaly Varga told reporters today in Budapest. “The comments that have been made about this issue are exaggerated and if they come from colleagues that’s unfortunate.”

Prime Minister Viktor Orban, who took power a week ago, sought permission for a wider budget deficit from the European Union and the International Monetary Fund, which led the 20 billion-euro ($24 billion) bailout for Hungary. European Commission President Jose Manuel Barroso this week rebuffed Orban, urging him to continue fiscal consolidation.

The government will aim to meet the deficit target of 3.8 percent of gross domestic product, which is “attainable” through changes to spending and revenue plans, Varga said today. Orban called a three-day emergency cabinet meeting to hammer out the action plan.

Kenneth A. Posner writes an interesting piece on Contingent Capital:

This idea has in fact been around for some time: in 1991, Tom Stanton suggested contingent capital for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (FRE, Fortune 500) — if people had listened then, the idea would have saved taxpayers untold billions today — the government’s bailout of the two mortgage agencies is unlimited, with the Congressional Budget Office estimating it could cost $373 billion by 2020.

The proposed global bank tax has been rejected:

Group of 20 nations failed to agree on a proposal to impose a global tax on banks that was aimed at making the financial industry shoulder the cost of bailouts, settling instead for a common set of guidelines.

G-20 finance ministers and central bank governors said in a statement in Busan, South Korea, that governments will take account of each nation’s “circumstances and options.” The result allows nations such as Canada, China and Brazil, whose banks suffered less during the global financial crisis, to skip introducing a tax. European countries and the U.S. have advocated the levy.

“If we’re living in an ideal world, a global financial tax would be a good idea but in reality, it is almost impossible to implement,” said Tomo Kinoshita, an economist at Nomura Holdings Inc. in Hong Kong. “There are too many obstacles.”

Yesterday’s statement leaves in place an initiative to seek tighter global standards for capital levels at banks, which is a “more practical” way to help reduce the risk of financial crises, Kinoshita said. Banks have opposed the effort, warning that the costs may curb credit expansion and economic growth.

It is my understanding that the Europeans are opposed to increased capitalization, since a greater proportion of their credit markets consists of bank loans.

PrefBlog was mentioned in Larry McDonald’s Canadian Business Online Blog post Round-up of financial blogs. Thanks, Larry!

The Goldman pogrom continued:

The commission established by Congress to investigate the causes of the financial crisis issued a subpoena to Goldman Sachs on Monday for “failing to comply with a request for documents and interviews in a timely manner.”

A person briefed on the investigation said that Goldman had already provided more than 20 million pages of documents, and that the commission had begun interviewing witnesses, on a range of issued, including derivatives, the complex financial instruments that were at the heart of the crisis.

Not just 20-million!

Goldman Sachs sent more than a billion pages of documents, FCIC Vice Chairman Bill Thomas said on a conference call with reporters today. Not all of the information is what the panel requested, and Goldman Sachs didn’t cooperate with requests to interview Chief Executive Officer Lloyd Blankfein, Chief Operating Officer Gary Cohn and Chief Financial Officer David Viniar, FCIC Chairman Phil Angelides said.

“We did not ask them to pull up a dump truck to our offices and dump a bunch of rubbish,” said Angelides, 56, who previously served as California’s treasurer. “This has been a very deliberate effort over time to run out the clock.”

Bank CDS levels in Europe show a certain amount of nervousness:

The cost of insuring against a default on financial-company bonds surged, with the Markit iTraxx Financial Index of credit- default swaps linked to the senior debt of 25 European banks and insurers climbing 6 basis points to 189, according to CMA DataVision in London, near the highest level since March 2009. The Markit iTraxx SovX Western Europe Index of contracts on 15 governments fell 1.5 basis points to 167, compared with the record-high 174.4 reached on June 4.

It is my understanding that the recently issued and poorly received EMA.PR.A will be repriced and offered at 24.50.

It was another very strong day on the Canadian preferred share market, with PerpetualDiscounts up 67bp and FixedResets gaining 15bp. Volume was elevated.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 2.67 % 2.72 % 42,323 20.68 1 0.0000 % 2,093.6
FixedFloater 5.18 % 3.27 % 28,327 19.96 1 0.1908 % 3,090.8
Floater 2.41 % 2.79 % 91,149 20.19 3 0.0734 % 2,240.9
OpRet 4.88 % 3.79 % 95,117 0.95 11 0.2128 % 2,313.4
SplitShare 6.41 % -0.05 % 102,857 0.08 2 0.5331 % 2,164.4
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.2128 % 2,115.4
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.6698 % 1,861.0
Perpetual-Discount 6.09 % 6.16 % 205,412 13.70 77 0.6698 % 1,761.6
FixedReset 5.45 % 4.19 % 415,259 3.51 45 0.1536 % 2,166.1
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
CIU.PR.B FixedReset -1.09 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-01
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.30
Bid-YTW : 4.31 %
TCA.PR.X Perpetual-Discount 1.05 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 45.45
Evaluated at bid price : 47.20
Bid-YTW : 5.97 %
TD.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 1.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 20.85
Evaluated at bid price : 20.85
Bid-YTW : 5.90 %
POW.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.07 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 21.46
Evaluated at bid price : 21.73
Bid-YTW : 6.25 %
IAG.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.10 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 18.41
Evaluated at bid price : 18.41
Bid-YTW : 6.27 %
NA.PR.K Perpetual-Discount 1.14 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 23.72
Evaluated at bid price : 24.02
Bid-YTW : 6.15 %
BNS.PR.O Perpetual-Discount 1.15 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 23.58
Evaluated at bid price : 23.78
Bid-YTW : 5.97 %
TD.PR.R Perpetual-Discount 1.15 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 23.53
Evaluated at bid price : 23.72
Bid-YTW : 5.98 %
HSB.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.18 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 20.50
Evaluated at bid price : 20.50
Bid-YTW : 6.23 %
PWF.PR.K Perpetual-Discount 1.21 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 20.04
Evaluated at bid price : 20.04
Bid-YTW : 6.27 %
SLF.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.24 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 19.54
Evaluated at bid price : 19.54
Bid-YTW : 6.16 %
RY.PR.B Perpetual-Discount 1.25 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 20.27
Evaluated at bid price : 20.27
Bid-YTW : 5.85 %
POW.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.42 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 22.66
Evaluated at bid price : 22.90
Bid-YTW : 6.21 %
PWF.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 1.54 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 24.09
Evaluated at bid price : 24.47
Bid-YTW : 6.21 %
TD.PR.Q Perpetual-Discount 1.54 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 23.54
Evaluated at bid price : 23.74
Bid-YTW : 5.98 %
NA.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 1.64 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 24.63
Evaluated at bid price : 24.86
Bid-YTW : 6.10 %
GWO.PR.M Perpetual-Discount 1.72 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 23.48
Evaluated at bid price : 23.65
Bid-YTW : 6.14 %
BMO.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 1.75 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 22.24
Evaluated at bid price : 22.66
Bid-YTW : 5.88 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
SLF.PR.G FixedReset 62,015 RBC crossed 16,000 at 24.35.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 24.45
Evaluated at bid price : 24.50
Bid-YTW : 4.16 %
IAG.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 56,100 Desjardins crossed 19,800 at 24.14; TD crossed 17,700 at the ame price; TD sold 17,700 to Desjardins at the same price again.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 23.88
Evaluated at bid price : 24.07
Bid-YTW : 6.24 %
BNA.PR.C SplitShare 55,000 RBC crossed 50,000 at 19.10.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2019-01-10
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 19.11
Bid-YTW : 8.28 %
TD.PR.G FixedReset 41,030 TD crossed 25,000 at 27.15.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-05-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.10
Bid-YTW : 4.19 %
TD.PR.S FixedReset 39,673 TD crossed 24,000 at 25.70.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2018-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.69
Bid-YTW : 4.21 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 31,000 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-07
Maturity Price : 19.35
Evaluated at bid price : 19.35
Bid-YTW : 6.17 %
There were 41 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
Contingent Capital

Hedging a McDonald CoCo

In the first update to the post A Structural Model of Contingent Bank Capital, when responding to Prof. Pennacchi’s commentary (then anonymous, then later quoted in full with permission), I said:

As an unconstrained bond manager, I would be sorely tempted to buy a put on the equity, with the strike price equal to the conversion price and view the CC + put as a package. My view on the attractiveness of the package would be heavily influenced by the net yield of the continuing position. However, the chances of me, as a bond specialist, of having a mandate that allows the purchase of equity puts are infinitesimal and there will be asset allocation problems at the most integrated of management firms. I think that this area becomes hedge fund territory.

So I decided to do a little playing with numbers to see how this might work.

In order to keep the assumptions close to those of McDonald’s original paper, I simulated a ten year bond with a coupon of 4.09%, while the risk-free ten year is at 4.00%. Additionally, I implemented the McDonald CoCo with the index trigger set arbitrarily high, so that the instrument reflects my original recommendation. As has been previously noted, I consider 9bp at issue time to be an unrealistically narrow spread (it considers only that portion of credit risk that is due to jumps in the bank’s asset value), but let’s see what happens anyway!

I then prepared a spreadsheet with various bond prices; commencing at 100.00 and decrementing with 0.50 intervals down to 79.00 (why 79.00? See below!). I then worked out the effective conversion price for each bond price; for instance, when the bond price is 90.00, the effective conversion price is 45.00, since I will be getting two shares in exchange should the stock price ever hit 50.00.

For each bond price, I then calculated the excess yield over the risk-free rate (which is presumed to be a flat yield curve at 4%) and converted this to a dollar figure. For instance, at a bond price of 100.00 the excess yield is 9bp, which is $0.09 annually. At a bond price of 90.00, the yield is 5.40%, 140bp over the risk-free rate, and 1.40% of 90 is just over $1.25 annually.

In order to hedge the conversion, I need to buy two puts, so when the bond price is 100.00 I can spend $0.045 per put and when the bond price is 90.00 I can spend $0.6288 per put.

The market price of the puts was calculated for a one-year term on the put, with a strike price equal to the effective conversion price and volatility of 30%. The current price of the stock was chosen so that the price of the put is equal to the amount I can spend.

It should be noted that this is not a true hedge: there is the opportunity for profit. For instance, say the price of the bond is 90.00 and I buy two one-year puts on the stock at 45.00. As long as the contemporary stock price is 65.06 or more, then my projected yield for the package for the first year of the ten year term of the bond will be 4% – the risk free rate that I am trying to hedge (similar in principle to owning a bond and buying a CDS on it).

There is a chance of underperforming the risk-free rate over the term of the bond if the stock price declines further and subsequent years’ puts become more expensive. However, there is always the chance of profit, based on the CoCo specification that the issuers’ put option is exercised immediately as soon as the stock price reaches the conversion trigger. Thus, this embedded put can never be in-the-money for the issuer; this in turn means that, for instance, if I am able to achieve the paper’s assumption that I will be able to sell the common at 50.00 then I will have outperformed significantly: I will have converted at the effective conversion price of less than 50.00 (given that I bought the bond below par), sold it at 50; and still have a long put option on the stock that, even if it is out of the money, may well have significant time value on it.

It is this question of mismatches on the time value of the option that lead me to use 1-year options; if the exercise is repeated with 10-year options (which would be OTC instruments) then the time-value mismatch makes the hedge a more expensive proposition.

Thus, when the bond price is 90.00, it yields 5.40%, providing me with 140bp over risk-free, or $1.2574 annually, used to buy two puts at $0.6288 with a strike price of 45.00 at a time when the price of the stock is 65.06.

Repeating these calculations provides the following charts:


Click for big

Click for big

These graphs look entirely reasonable in the light of our experience of the past few years: it seems entirely reasonable to me that spreads will widen from 9bp to 305bp when the stock price halves.

The minimum bond price calculated is 79.00; prices lower than this, hedging the conversion price at 39.50, require the stock to be priced at less than 50.00; at which point the bond will no longer exist. Mind you, with the bond at 79.00, you’re winning if the stock does touch 50.00 and you can dump it for more than 39.50; with this kind of gap, do you really need to hedge?

However, there is an implication for Prof. Pennacchi’s assertion that:

it is best to set a trigger than can result in conversion when the bank’s original shareholders’ equity is only mildly depleted rather than have a trigger where conversion occurs at a very low value of original shareholders’ equity.

The above charts show that hedging cost will rise dramatically as the stock price approaches the trigger/conversion price.

Please note that I have no quibbles with Prof. Pennacchi’s math or reasoning; my objection relates to the embedded assumption that investors will have the ability in practice of a stop-loss order to be executed at a predictable price (or, at least, one that is based on the fundamentals of a bank’s assets). The May 6 bungee-jump (or “flash-crash”, as the cool kids are calling it now) showed that. I will also remind Assiduous Readers of the 1987 crash, exacerbated by equally mathematically pure portfolio insurance.

The spreadsheet used to make the charts is available for the edification and amusement of those who want to play with the numbers a bit.

Contingent Capital

Pennacchi Discusses CoCo Structural Model

After posting my review of his paper, A Structural Model of Contingent Bank Capital, I eMailed Prof. Pennacchi asking him about the political, regulatory and academic response to his paper and inviting him to comment further,

He very kindly responded and has granted permission to quote his reply:

I have presented my paper at the NY Fed, a Moodys-NYU Conference (both in NYC), and just recently at the International Risk Management Conference in Florence, Italy. I must say that I really haven’t received any negative comments on the paper. The reception has been quite good.

I understand your concern that if contingent capital (CC) converts at par, and bank assets follow a diffusion process (which, mathematically, means the value of the assets have a continuous sample path and cannot experience (downward) “jumps” in value), the paper concludes that CC will be default free. You are concerned that this would only hold if the new equity is sold immediately by the CC investors and that, during a crisis, new bank equity issues may have to be issued at a discount.

I have a couple of observations. First, looking at historical new equity issues during a crisis may not be fully relevant to an environment where CC is converted. This is because, historically, new equity issues during a crisis have occurred in a context where there is significant “debt overhang.” The discount occurs because issuing new equity makes the bank safer (less likely to default on its debt), thereby transfering value from the original equityholders to the bank’s debt holders (such as subordinated debt investors). Hence, under these conditions we would expect that the announcement of a new equity issue would result in a fall in the bank’s stock price.

But CC is different. Indeed, one of its advantages is that it reduces the debt overhang problem. When contingent capital is converted, there is a simultaneous wiping out of existing debt (the CC bond) replaced with new shares of equity (to the former CC investors). Hence, there is not the type of transfer of value from the original equityholders to debtholders (CC investors) as would be the case if new equity was issued without wiping out the claims of the bank’s subordinated debtholders.

Second, assuming that there would be no discount at conversion, then CC investors would receive $1 of stock for every $1 of par value at the new issue debt. At this point, the model assumes the debt has been paid off in full, so there has been no default. You question whether this is really default-free. It may not be default-free based on the CC bonds’ original maturity date, but it is default-free at the conversion date.

Note that the CC investors who are now stockholders could sell but they could also hold if they thought there would be temporary downward pricing pressure from others who sell. It could be that by holding on to their shares they would receive even more than their par value as of the CC bond’s original maturity date, which would be even better than holding a default-free Treasury bond. Of course they could also get less if the stock price declines. But the point is, the situation no longer becomes comparable to a default-free investment. I am taking the perspective of the bond being default-free as of the conversion date. As I state in the paper, the effective maturity date of this default-free security is uncertain. If you do not want to think of that as a default-free security, I have no problem with that perspective. However, the CC investors will get their par value (in stock if prior to maturity and cash if at actual maturity) at some date in the future, even if that date is not known ahead of time.

Third, and finally, I do not believe that bank assets follow a diffussion (no jump) process. The main, unique contribution of my paper is to value CC under the assumption that bank asset values (and stock prices) are likely to jump, especially jump downward during a crisis. So while my reasoning may differ from yours, what my paper shows is that CC will indeed be credit risky, not default-free. As my paper shows, one should expect that CC will have a positive credit spread when issued. I only compare my model to the diffusion (no jump) case to emphasize why jumps in asset value matter. However, less one thinks that such jump risks make CC a flawed product, my paper also goes on to show that CC is less risky than if the bank has, instead, issued a comparable quantity of subordinated debt. In summary, it is unrealistic to think that CC is default-free. However, conversion to equity when the bank’s condition has a moderate decline is actually a safety valve that relieves financial distress and protects CC investors relative to if they were sub debt investors. Because CC capital conversion reduces the bank’s leverage, it would make it easier for the bank to issue further new shares of common stock without experiencing much, if any, of a discount because there would be little overhang.

One policy recommendation from my paper’s results is that CC becomes safer (less credit risky) the greater is the value of original shareholders’ equity when conversion is triggered. In other words, it is best to set a trigger than can result in conversion when the bank’s original shareholders’ equity is only mildly depleted rather than have a trigger where conversion occurs at a very low value of original shareholders’ equity.

I hope this response helps to provide some intuition regarding the risk characteristics of CC.

Thank you, sir!

Contingent Capital

A Structural Model of Contingent Bank Capital

George Pennacchi, a Professor of Finance at the University of Illinois, has published a paper titled A Structural Model of Contingent Bank Capital that leads to some surprising – to me – conclusions:

This paper develops a structural credit risk model of a bank that issues deposits, share-holders’ equity, and fixed or floating coupon bonds in the form of contingent capital or subordinated debt. The return on the bank’s assets follows a jump-di¤usion process, and default-free interest rates are stochastic. The equilibrium pricing of the bank’s deposits, contingent capital, and shareholders’ equity is studied for various parameter values characterizing the bank’s risk and the contractual terms of its contingent capital. Allowing for the possibility of jumps in the bank’s asset value, as might occur during a financial crisis, has distinctive implications for valuing contingent capital. Credit spreads on contingent capital are higher the lower is the value of shareholders’ equity at which conversion occurs and the larger is the conversion discount from the bond’s par value. The effect of requiring a decline in a financial stock price index for conversion (dual price trigger) is to make contingent capital more similar to non-convertible subordinated debt. The paper also examines the bank’s incentive to increase risk when it issues di¤erent forms of contingent capital as well as subordinated debt. In general, a bank that issues contingent capital has a moral hazard incentive to raise its assets’risk of jumps, particularly when the value of equity at the conversion threshold is low. However, moral hazard when issuing contingent capital tends to be less than when issuing subordinated debt. Because it reduces e¤ective leverage and the pressure for government bailouts, contingent capital deserves serious consideration as part of a package of reforms that stabilize the financial system and eliminate “Too-Big-to-Fail”.

I am very pleased to see that the structure I have been advocating is receiving academic scrutiny. He discusses the model in terms of the CC proposals of McDonald and Flannery, both of which have been discussed on PrefBlog.

I have difficulty with some of the assumptions:

If a bank’s asset returns follow a pure difusion process without jumps, and fixed-coupon contingent capital converts to shareholders’ equity at its par value, then contingent capital’s new-issue yield-to-maturity (par coupon rate) equals a default-free par rate, such as a Treasury bond yield. But since the possibility of conversion lowers contingent capital’s effective maturity, contingent capital’s comparable default-free yield is less than that of its stated maturity. Thus, if the term structure of default-free Treasury yields is upward sloping, as it normally is, the yield on contingent capital will be less than that of an equivalent-maturity Treasury bond. However, for the case of contingent capital that pays floating-rate coupons, coupon credit spreads above the short-term, default-free interest rate always will be zero.

This assumes that

  • The converted noteholder sells his equity immediately upon receipt
  • He realizes the trigger price for it (or, as in the case of the McDonald pricing computations discussed elsewhere, very nearly)

This doesn’t work for me. According to me, in order to determine a credit spread, you would have to assume that the converted noteholder hangs on to his equity and sells it on the original maturity date. Assuming immediate sale at the trigger price (nearly) is akin to computing credit spreads due to default with the assumption that the holder can see default coming and sells early.

I suggest that, at the very least, one should look at the discount to market on bank new issues during the crisis (not rights issues, which will often be heavily discounted to ensure take-up; unfortunately this basically eliminates European banks from the sample), and apply this discount to the proceeds on conversion and sale. For example, the CIBC recapitalization was done with the help of a private placement at $62.65 net of fees, compared to its previous close of $72.07. A 14% haircut on conversion – even when converted at par, converting at an explicit discount will be worse – will change the numbers considerably.

Assiduous Readers may make their own assumptions about the effect of the “effective stop-loss order effect” of immediate market orders to sell upon conversion (during a crisis!) according to whatever answers they want to justify. But I don’t think an implicit assumption of 0% frictional or temporal cost is justifiable. It’s too much like assuming 100% recovery on default.

I have more difficulty – similar to my problems with recent advocacy of floating rate contingent capital:

If a bank’s asset returns follow a pure diffusion process without jumps, and fixed-coupon contingent capital converts to shareholders’ equity at its par value, then contingent capital’s new-issue yield-to-maturity (par coupon rate) equals a default-free par rate, such as a Treasury bond yield.

This ignores things like liquidity premia, central bank collateralization premia and default uncertainty, which in this case can be expressed as conversion uncertainty – and that’s just for starters!

I feel compelled to republish one of my favourite graphs, previously shown in the post BoE Releases June 2009 Financial Stability Report:

Arguments that depend on corporate bond yields hugging the green line are doomed to failure, even when the bonds are senior! I will also point out that the liquidity premium on CC is likely to be significantly higher than that on senior bonds, as the investor base is likely to be significantly smaller.

When, more realistically, the bank’s asset returns incorporate a jump process, contingent capital that is speci…ed to convert at its par value will have a yield that rises above default-free yields. This positive credit spread is due to the potential losses that contingent capital investors would suffer if a sudden decline in the bank’s asset value requires conversion at below par value. An implication is that new issue credit spreads on contingent capital rise as the bank’s total capital and the value its original shareholders’ equity declines. Credit spreads on contingent capital also are higher the lower is the value of shareholders’ equity at which conversion is specified to occur and the larger is the conversion discount from the bond’s par value. The effect of requiring a decline in a financial stock price index for conversion, the “dual price trigger” feature proposed by McDonald (2009), is to make contingent capital more similar to non-convertible subordinated debt.

The guts of the paper are:

Figure 2 gives the new issue yields for …xed-coupon contingent capital, c, when the bank’s initial total capital ranges from 6.5% to 15%. Recall that the default-free term structure is assumed to have an initial instantaneous maturity interest rate of r0 equal to 3.5% and the par yield on a five-year Treasury coupon bond is 4.23%. This 4.23% default-free, five-year par yield is given by the dashed line denoted Schedule A in the …gure. In comparison, Schedule B of Figure 2 shows that the benchmark contingent capital bond’s new issue yield is 5.41%, 4.56%, and 4.39% when initial capital is 6.5%, 10%, and 15%, respectively.

This contingent capital bond’s yield spread above the five-year Treasury is due to the possibility that it could convert at less than par following a downward jump in the bank’s asset (and equity) value. If all of the benchmark parameters are maintained except one assumes there is no possibility of jumps (λ = 0), then the contingent capital bond’s spreads over the five-year Treasury yield would not be positive. Indeed, given the assumption of an upward-sloping term structure, Schedule C of Figure 2 shows that spreads would be slightly negative. Since conversion lowers the e¤ective maturity of contingent capital and, without jumps, it always converts at par, it is e¤ectively a default-free bond with a maturity of less than five years. Hence, its yield is more like a that of a shorter-term default-free bond, which is below the five-year default-free yield. Thus, one sees that the possibility of jumps in the bank’s asset value, as might occur during a financial crisis, has a qualitatively important impact on the pricing of contingent capital.


Click for Big

Other charts include:

  • Effect of Maturity
  • Effects of conversion terms
  • Effects of conversion parameters
  • Effect of a Dual Price Trigger

But by me, the most interesting conclusion is:

A bank that issues contingent capital faces a moral hazard incentive to increase its assets’ jump risks. However, this incentive to transfer value from contingent capital investors to the bank’s shareholders is smaller than that when the bank has issued a similar amount of subordinated debt rather than contingent capital. Thus, relative to the status quo, there is likely to be a decline in moral hazard if contingent capital replaces subordinated debt. The results show that excessive risk-taking incentives also decline as contingent capital’s equity conversion threshold rises. With a bigger “equity cushion” at the conversion threshold, there is a smaller likelihood that a sudden loss in bank asset value would prevent full conversion, thereby better protecting contingent capital investors from losses.

He even addresses Julie Dickson’s proposal (although not her fabricated assertion, unchallenged by the press, that fixed-dollar conversion is universally favoured):

In other words, for the benchmark contingent capital bond, at a point just before conversion, there would need to be a sudden asset value loss exceeding 2% to prevent full conversion, while for the contingent capital bond with e = 1%, at a point just before conversion, there would need to be a sudden asset value loss only slightly more than 1% for bondholders to sustain a conversion loss. This finding has implications for recent regulatory proposals that would have contingent capital convert only when a bank was in dire straits and close to being seized by regulators. [footnote] Delaying conversion to a point when the value of original shareholders’ equity is low raises the new issue yields on contingent capital.

footnote: Canada’s superintendent of financial institutions, Julie Dickson, proposes that the conversion trigger for contingent capital would be “when the regulator is ready to seize control of the institution because problems are so deep that no private buyer would be willing to acquire shares in the bank.” Financial Times, April 9, 2010.

Update, 2010-6-6: A new reader has very kindly provided extensive commentary on my critique of this post. He claims (as paraphrased by me, JH):

(i) New equity issues from banks are not structurally equivalent to CC conversion : New equity makes extant debt safer; therefore transfers value from extant equity holders to debt holders; therefore a decline in equity price is expected. This is not the case when CC is converted.

JH – By this reasoning, my reference to the 14% new issue discount on the CIBC recapitalization is not relevant. Well …maybe!

(ii) CC holders experience a regime change on conversion and the original maturity date does not apply. The new equity may be sold or held, depending upon the holders’ views on the stock. If the stock price rises from the trigger price, the noteholders could even realize excess returns. Thus, the CC may be thought of as being default-free as of the conversion date.

JH – Well, you can bet this is the line that the salesmen will take! A lot of it depends upon perspective: it may be true from the bank’s point of view, the market’s point of view and the regulators’ point of view … but, naturally enough, I am considering it from a specialist bond managers’ point of view: who will at the very least see the risk/return profile of the portfolio visibly change; whose mandate will almost certainly prohibit the holding of equity; and who will very likely be forced to sell the stock at whatever it will fetch which (due to the ‘cascading stop-loss effect’ at the very least) will likely be lower than the conversion price.

Additionally, the reasoning incorporates the assumptions that all mathematical models must incorporate, at least to some degree: that there is infinite liquidity and that assets will be fairly priced in the future. The credit crunch has reminded us of just how battered these assumptions can be during a crisis; as a practitioner, I must take a jaundiced view.

(iii) Bank asset values jump, therefore CC is in fact credit-risky; but credit risk declines with higher trigger points

In the presence of jumps, credit risks result from the potential for the equity value to jump over the trigger point; therefore the CC will convert at a higher price than market, therefore the CC holders will experience a loss; therefore the CC is credit risky.

But importantly, CC is less credit risky than sub-debt and, by reducing leverage, will facilitate new issues of equity. It is also important to note that the credit risk introduced by the jump process declines with higher trigger/conversion prices.

JH – Again, perspective is important; a specialist bond manager (or bond portfolio manager within an integrated firm, for that matter) will not view the paper as having minimal credit risk when the trigger price is 99.9% of the current stock price. Additionally, the significant amount of duration risk at this limiting point will make such an issue very hard to integrate into a well defined portfolio.

There may well be a branch of bond mathematics that deal with this question, but I am not aware of it: I am sufficiently arrogant to claim that if I am not aware of a branch of bond mathematics, then at least 95% of bond portfolio managers are similarly ignorant.

As an unconstrained bond manager, I would be sorely tempted to buy a put on the equity, with the strike price equal to the conversion price and view the CC + put as a package. My view on the attractiveness of the package would be heavily influenced by the net yield of the continuing position. However, the chances of me, as a bond specialist, of having a mandate that allows the purchase of equity puts are infinitesimal and there will be asset allocation problems at the most integrated of management firms. I think that this area becomes hedge fund territory.

Update, 2010-6-6: My correspondent was Prof. Pennacchi. He has given me permission to quote his remarks in full, which I have done in the post Pennacchi Discusses CoCo Structural Model.

Contingent Capital

Contingent Capital with a Dual Price Trigger

Robert McDonald of Northwestern University has published a paper titled Contingent Capital with a Dual Price Trigger that I consider excellent – mainly because it advocates a framework for Contingent Capital that includes the structure I advocate (and have been advocating ever since HM Treasury’s Turner Report response brought the basic idea to my attention) and supports it with rationale that reflects my biases.

This paper proposes a form of contingent capital for financial institutions that converts from debt to equity if two conditions are met: the firm’s stock price is at or below a trigger value and the value of a financial institutions index is also at or below a trigger value. This structure protects financial firms during a crisis, when all are performing badly, but during normal times permits a bank performing badly to go bankrupt. I discuss a number of issues associated with the design of a contingent capital claim, including susceptibility to manipulation and whether conversion should be for a fixed dollar amount of shares or a fixed number of shares; the susceptibility of different contingent capital schemes to different kinds of errors (under and over-capitalization); and the losses likely to be incurred by shareholders upon the imposition of a requirement for contingent capital. I also present some illustrative pricing examples.

His specific proposal is:

The contingent capital claim that I describe, “dual trigger contingent capital”, converts automatically based on market prices, without reference to accounting-based measures of capital. Specifically, it converts to equity when the bank’s own stock price falls sufficiently, and then only if a broad nancial stock index is also below a trigger value. (This condition can be eliminated by making the trigger sufficiently large.) This structure reduces the debt load for poorly-performing institutions in times of crisis, but permits individual banks to fail in good times.

The major benefits of using market prices are:

Simplicity and transparency should facilitate market acceptance and reduce the (appropriately-measured) cost to banks of issuing convertible claims. The use of market-based triggers, with no reliance on accounting numbers, means that conversion is unaffected by accounting rule reinterpretations or changes. Making conversion automatic and based only on market prices should reduce pressure on regulators and the accounting community at critical times. Also, private information of either the firm or the regulator has no bearing on the conversion decision.

My point that using market prices and fixed conversion rates will facilitate the hedging of CC in the options market – and therefore the liquidity in a crisis – may be considered included in the “facilitate market acceptance” phrase.

I did not address one point he considers critical (which was further discussed, albeit in a highly unsatisfactory manner, by FRBNY staff) is:

A critical issue is the precise manner in which conversion occurs, and the possibility of stock price manipulation. In Section 3 I discuss a number of design considerations and I conclude that conversion of the bond into a fixed number of shares at a premium price minimizes concerns about manipulation.(footnote) The tradeo is that such a structure raises the yield on convertible debt. (This greater yield is of course fair compensation for the loss imposed upon bondholders should conversion occur.)

footnote: “Premium price” here means that the value of the shares upon conversion is lower than the par value of the bonds. In e ect, the bondholder is paying a greater than market price for the shares received. I dicuss this more in Section 1.

So consider a pref issued at $25 when the common is at $50. In the base proposal, if the common falls below $25 (for a defined period), the pref will convert at par into the trigger price; preferred shareholders will receive one common for each pref. With “premium pricing”, preferred shareholders will received less than one share, while the trigger price remains the same. I’ll discuss this later.

Also, note that I am (for obvious reasons) focussing on preferred shares while all the academic discussion I have seen focusses on sub-debt. I think that should CC effectively replace sub-debt, then similar conversion features will be applied to prefs – otherwise, preferreds will be effectively senior to CC (in that they will retain their claims when everything else is converted, and remain senior when the bank goes bust) and I don’t think the markets will stand for such leapfrogging.

His example provides the rationale behind an expected yield spread over senior debt:

To more fully understand the events at conversion, suppose that at some time after issue the nancial index is below 90 and the stock price reaches $50. At this point bondholders are entitled to 20 shares. Typically, however, the stock price will not close exactly at $50, but say at $48. In this case the bondholders receive shares worth 20  $48 = $960. Thus, conversion on average will leave the bondholders slightly worse o than if the bond paid par value. As a result, the market will demand a slightly higher interest rate on the bond than if it were sure to convert into $50 worth of shares.(footnote)

footnote: An alternative would be to adjust the number of shares to make their value equal to the par value of the bond. As I discuss in Section 3, this alternative conversion scheme increases the returns to stock price manipulation.

In other words, the option effect. I should note that there will also be a spread required due to uncertainty – typically, bond holders will not have a mandate or desire to hold equity; hence, it is likely that the embedded short option will be overvalued.

He notes:

This structure accomplishes several things:

  • The conversion of bonds to shares occurs only if there is a widespread fall in the value of financial firm shares. One would expect such a widespread fall during a nancial crisis, not at other times.
  • A dual trigger convertible permits the failure of an institution as long as the nancial industry as a whole is peforming well. Without a fall in the index, bonds would not convert and the financial institution could go bankrupt. The note can be structured to avoid this.
  • There would be no regulatory involvement in the conversion decision
  • Conversion would not depend upon acccounting rules or the institution’s reported capital. If the market believed that a bank’s assets were worth less than the bank reported, conversion would occur if the share price and index conditions were satisifed.
  • The proposal is not subject to equity death spirals: In the fixed share structure, the number of shares exchanged for bonds would be fixed.

These are eminently sensible reasons. However, I remain dubious about the inclusion of the second, industry-wide trigger. Firstly, it will depend upon the composition of third-party indices, which can be – and often are – manipulated. Secondly, it will complicate pricing of the CC, which will mean that not all of the mathematical benefits of the reduced conversion chance will be realized.

Additionally, his footnote to the second point states:

If an institution is too-big-to-fail, the use of an index trigger raises the possibility of multiple equilibria. Consider a circumstance where a) the financial index would fall below the trigger if and only if the too-big-to-fail institution were to fail and b) conversion of the contingent capital would prevent failure. If the contingent capital were expected to convert and prevent failure, the index would never fall below the trigger value and thus the contingent capital would not convert. If the contingent capital were expected not to convert, the index would fall below the trigger value and the capital would convert. While the requirements seem empirically unlikely, it would be important to understand the equilibrium that would obtain in this case. I thank Zhenyu Wang for pointing out this issue.

He discusses the Flannery and Squam Lake proposals previously discussed on PrefBlog:

The Flannery and Squam Lake proposals differ in the nature of the trigger, but more importantly they differ in the severity of the event that will cause conversion. The Squam Lake proposal implicitly seems to view hybrid convertibles as a last-ditch measure: banks would have violated covenants and more importantly, regulators would have declared the existence of a crisis. Presumably one reason for using contingent capital would be to prevent a systemic crisis from occurring in the rst place. Is it possible that the use of a regulatory trigger creates multiple equilibria? Could regulators declaring the existence of a crisis could induce or worsen a crisis? More generally, it seems possible that regulators worrying about maintaining con dence in capital markets would would be reluctant to declare the existence of a crisis until it is too late.

I take the view that a regulatory declaration that a crisis existed would grossly exacerbate an already bad market situation. Additionally, prior uncertainty regarding a regulatory decision will depress the price of the CC, exacerbating the value transfer problem deplored by FRBNY staff.

McDonald discusses the potential for manipulation:

In the context of contingent capital, a concern is that unprofitable manipulation of the stock can become profitable when the trader also has a position in market-triggered contingent convertibles. This seems to be a legitimate concern. In this discussion we will suppose for the sake of argument that it is possible for traders to temporarily move the price (for example temporarily push it down), while maintaining the traditional academic skepticism that such trading in shares alone can be pro table. Ultimately the possibility of extensive manipulation and its importance is an empirical question.

He gives an example of manipulation:

To see how manipulation could be profitable, suppose that the stock is $51, and a $1000 bond converts into 20 shares when the price goes below $50. A trader owning this bond could possibly manipulate the price down to $49. This forces conversion, and the bondholder now owns 20 shares. When the price returns to $51, the bondholder has a position worth $1020, and has induced a 2% gain on the convertible (from $1000 to $1020) by triggering conversion.

It should be noted that the profitability of this eneavor will be increased if the trader has actually just purchased the CC at $900. But my question is: Is this manipulation, or is it arbitrage? Additionally, the assumption that the price returns to $51 implicitly assumes that the value of the firm is $51 and that markets are sufficiently efficient to reflect this value – this is a precise estimate and shaky assumption at the best of times and it may be assumed that conversion will occur during a period of highly inefficient markets.

To my mind, the important question is not whether a trader might be able to make a few bucks with the strategy, but whether such a strategy has the potential to cascade, with the approach of imminent conversion of other instruments – another series of bonds converting at $48. I’m not really all that concerned about transitory manipulation, since that simply provides an opportunity for value investors to buy at an artificially low price; but there could be genuine public policy concerns if this artificially low price made it difficult, or even impossible, for the firm to issue new capital at rates that permitted it to operate as a going concern. The attack on CIT group which essentially locked it out of the bond market until bankruptcy was triggered comes to mind as a possible example; but I have a feeling that we don’t know the whole story on that one.

It should be noted that, to the extent that converted former noteholders elect to sell their shares at the market, the effect can be modelled as a stop-loss order; such orders have been suggested as a factor in the May 6 market bungee-jump even though the exchanges have built in some protection against the effect.

I can’t really get all that excited about the issue of market manipulation – the only people hurt will be the idiots who trade on momentum. I suggest that the potential for what is, effectively, a stop-loss cascade is more worthy of academic attention.

His prescription is premium conversion:

The difficulty of the manipulation just described can be increased by creating a wedge between the par value of the bond and the conversion value of the shares, i.e, the bond could convert at a premium price for the shares. For example, the bond could convert into 19 shares rather than 20. The bondholder who forced conversion would then receive a position worth $950 at the $50 trigger price, a loss of ($1000 – $950)/19 = $2:63/share generated by conversion. If the share price were $51 as in the previous example, the bondholder would lose $1.63/share by manipulating the price below $50. Temporary manipulation to a price below $50 would not become profitable until the true share price was at least $52.63. Hence, any manipulation would have to be by a greater amount to compensate for the premium price. Because conversion at a premium price would require a greater manipulation to make conversion profitable, manipulation would be both less likely and easier to detect. In fact, if shares convert at a premium, bondholders would have an incentive to manipulate the price up to avoid conversion. This seems likely to be more difficult than the downward manipulation just discussed, because the price has to be kept up indefinitely (or until the bond matures) to forestall conversion. If at any time the price falls, the bond converts. Also, propping up the price will be increasingly difficult to accomplish if the bank is in distress.

This is not entirely satisfactory, as it assumes the manipulator will be buying the bond at par, whereas in practice it is much more probable – virtually certain – that the manipulator will have purchased the bond well below par from a spooked investor who is taking a loss. For any premium, there will be some bond price that restores profitability, which may be thought of as providing a floor for the bond price. Thus, extant holders will be indirect and incomplete beneficiaries of the potential for manipulation.

He then notes that fixed-dollar conversion (conversion at market value) and is more susceptible to manipulation than fixed-share conversion.

He discusses instances in which CC does not act optimally in the context of Type I errors (conversion occurs when capital is not required) and Type II (conversion does not occur when capital is required):

In summary, market-based triggers seem prone to type I errors, and regulatory and accounting-based triggers seem prone to type II errors. It seems unlikely that there would be a systemic crisis without financial firms having low stock prices. This would reduce the likelihood of a type II error for market-based triggers. Accounting and regulation, however, are not automatic, and both are subject to political winds and whims. Basing conversion on regulatory judgment would reduce the likelihood of a type I error, in which bonds converted into stock without any crisis. But as discussed, one can imagine regulators failing to act. It is interesting to note that both the Flannery and Squam Lake proposals try not to saddle financial firms with “too much” equity. Flannery’s would convert only enough bonds to meet a capital requirement, and Squam Lake’s would convert only for banks with a low capital ratio.

To my immense gratification, he details problems with accounting-based conversion triggers:

  • Most accounting is done periodically rather than continuously.
  • Accounting rules are subject to political pressure.
  • Accounting rules are subject to arbitrage.
  • Accounting measures are often backward-looking

Of immense interest are his calculations regarding CC pricing:

In this section I perform some simple pricing exercises to illustrate characteristics of a dual-trigger contingent convertible under the assumption that both the stock price of the firm and the index are lognormally-distributed. Specifically, I assume that the stock price, St, and index price,Qt, both follow Ito processes, which is the standard assumption in the Black-Scholes model:

The correlation between dSt and dQt is ρ. Appendix A details the calculations. The stock price cannot reach zero in equation (1), so the yield calculation occurs in a context where bankruptcy is impossible. The yields I report therefore reflect only the effects of conversion.

Critical inputs into the pricing model are the volatility of the index, which I set to equal 20%, approximately the historical volatility of the Dow Jones Financial Services index from 1992 to 2007, and the stock volatility, which I set to 30%, approximately the historical volatility of banks like Citi, BofA, and Wells Fargo over this period. The correlation between the firm stock return and that of the index, again selected based on history, is 0.85.

Tables 1 and 2 illustrate the pricing of the convertible in a simple setting where
bankruptcy of the firm does not occur under any circumstances, but the convertible converts when the stock and index triggers are both satisifed. Pricing is by Monte Carlo. Specifically, I simulate the stock and index price, drawing new prices every day. The first time the stock and index prices are both below the trigger, the bond converts into a fixed number of shares. This simulation thus explictly models conversion occurring at a price below the trigger price, and thus generates a yield greater than the risk-free rate. The number in both tables is the annual yield premium above the risk-free rate.

Table 1 presents the bond yield premium when conversion occurs at the trigger price: If the bond has a par value of $1000 and the trigger price is $50, the bond converts into 20 shares. The maximum yield occurs when the stock trigger is relatively high (70% of the initial price) and the index trigger is low (80% of the initial index price). In this case it is relatively likely that the index trigger will not be satisifed when the stock reaches the trigger price, and thus on average conversion will occur when the stock is signi cantly below the trigger price. The resulting premium is over 1%. Conversely, in the rightmost column the index trigger effectively does not exist. In this case the 25 basis point premium is entirely attributable to the bond converting below the trigger price. With a low stock trigger and a high index trigger, the bond premium is a negligible 2 basis points.

Table 2 examines the case where there is a 10% stock price premium at conversion.

>

Table 1: Debt premium as a function of the index trigger and stock trigger. Assumes S0 = $100, Q0 = $100, σs = 0:30, σi = 0:20, ρ = 0:80, T = 5:00 years, h = 0:0040 (simulation timestep), r = 0:0400, with 50000 simulations. The conversion premium is 0.0000.
Note: I have converted the figures from the published table into basis points – JH
Stock Trigger Index Trigger
80 100 120 140 1000
70 121 42 27 25 25
60 55 22 16 16 15
50 23 11 9 9 9
40 8 6 5 5 5
30 3 2 2 2 2

Thus, my original proposal is reflected in cell (1000, 50) of the table, and shows that there will be a yield premium of 9bp due to the conversion feature. Note, however, that this premium is a little bit of a cheat; losses are due only to the stock price over-shooting the conversion price, with the assumption that the shares are sold immediately.

Update, 2010-6-8: Prof. McDonald advises that: there is a certain amount of skepticism regarding the second, index-based, trigger; that there is concern regarding multiple equilibria if the conversion price is at a premium to the trigger price; that regulators consider the idea interesting but want more details and discussion; and that the potential for manipulation may increase the cost to issuers.

Update, 2010-6-10: I should note that the conversion trigger proposed by Prof. McDonald implies that a single trade of 100 shares can do the job. In my original proposal, I urged that the trigger be based on the common’s VWAP over a given period – say, 20 consecutive trading days. The latter format will make manipulation considerably more difficult, at the expense of potentially trapping CC noteholders in their investment if the common price declines precipituously over the VWAP measurement period.

Market Action

June 4, 2010

Hungary has joined Club Med:

Credit-default swaps on sovereign bonds surged on speculation Europe’s debt crisis is worsening after Hungary said it’s in a “very grave situation” because a previous government lied about the state of the economy.

The cost of insuring against losses on Hungarian sovereign debt jumped 83.5 basis points to 391.5, according to CMA DataVision prices. Swaps on France, Austria, Belgium and Germany also rose, sending the Markit iTraxx SovX Western Europe Index of contracts on 15 governments 10 basis points higher to 163, and close to the all-time high of 167 on May 6.

Hungary’s bonds fell after a spokesman for Prime Minister Viktor Orban said talk of a default is “not an exaggeration” because a previous administration “manipulated” figures. The country was bailed out with a 20 billion-euro ($24 billion) aid package from the European Union and International Monetary Fund in 2008.

The delays in bank reform are now being discussed publicly:

The Group of 20 nations is split on the scale and timing of increases in bank-capital requirements that have been under discussion since governments were forced to bail out lenders, an official from a G-20 government said.

Countries such as the U.S. whose economies are largely financed by markets want banks to be required to hold more assets on their balance sheets to buffer against future crises, said the official, who will attend this weekend’s talks of G-20 finance chiefs in Busan, South Korea. Policy makers in continental Europe, where banks provide more financing, are concerned that too-high reserves risk choking off growth, the official told reporters on condition he not be named.

Goldman has set up a $450-million CLO:

Goldman Sachs Group Inc. arranged a $450 million collateralized loan obligation, according to people familiar with the transaction, making it the third widely syndicated transaction of the year.

Last week’s deal marks a reversal for CLO issuance, which according to Moody’s Investors Service, fell to $26.5 billion in 2009, its lowest level in more than a decade as the credit crisis and subsequent drop in loan prices made it economically difficult to arrange new funds.

Golly, I sure hope that they pointed to investors that the fund was able to buy its holdings because other people wanted to sell them!

Recovery, Schmecovery:

[US] Private payrolls rose by 41,000, Labor Department figures showed today, trailing the 180,000 gain forecast by economists. Including government workers, employment rose by 431,000, boosted by a jump in hiring of temporary census workers. The jobless rate fell to 9.7 percent from 9.9 percent.

There’s some whimpering about the Magna deal:

Magna has offered to pay Mr. Stronach $300-million (U.S.) in cash plus grant him nine million new subordinate-voting shares of the company for a total value of $863-million. The deal values each of his multiple-voting shares at $1,187, a massive premium over Magna’s share price. Magna’s widely held subordinate voting shares closed 62 cents higher at $69.86 (U.S.) Thursday.

“In our minds, it is an entirely excessive, inappropriate and egregious price that we’re being asked to pay, so that’s why we’re reacting so quickly and so strongly to what this proposal lays out,” CPPIB chief executive officer David Denison said Thursday in an interview.

Suck it up, boys! That’s what happens when you buy participating debentures rather than, you know, actual equity.

It was another day of fine performance on moderating volume in the Canadian preferred share market today, with PerpetualDiscounts gaining 31bp and FixedResets up 12bp.

The Financial Post Block Trades Report is back in operation. The link in the right-hand panel has been updated.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 2.66 % 2.72 % 44,004 20.70 1 -1.3457 % 2,093.6
FixedFloater 5.19 % 3.27 % 27,945 19.97 1 0.0000 % 3,084.9
Floater 2.41 % 2.80 % 91,173 20.18 3 -0.0917 % 2,239.2
OpRet 4.89 % 3.85 % 95,717 1.70 11 -0.0957 % 2,308.5
SplitShare 6.44 % 6.17 % 106,244 3.54 2 0.1112 % 2,152.9
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 -0.0957 % 2,110.9
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.3090 % 1,848.6
Perpetual-Discount 6.13 % 6.19 % 205,357 13.65 77 0.3090 % 1,749.9
FixedReset 5.46 % 4.24 % 418,123 3.52 45 0.1185 % 2,162.7
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
BAM.PR.E Ratchet -1.35 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 21.72
Evaluated at bid price : 21.26
Bid-YTW : 2.72 %
PWF.PR.J OpRet -1.20 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2011-05-30
Maturity Price : 25.25
Evaluated at bid price : 25.54
Bid-YTW : 3.95 %
POW.PR.A Perpetual-Discount -1.18 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 22.31
Evaluated at bid price : 22.58
Bid-YTW : 6.30 %
IAG.PR.C FixedReset 1.02 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-01-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 26.77
Bid-YTW : 4.00 %
CIU.PR.B FixedReset 1.06 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-07-01
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.60
Bid-YTW : 4.00 %
PWF.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 1.13 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 22.03
Evaluated at bid price : 22.35
Bid-YTW : 6.23 %
BAM.PR.R FixedReset 1.15 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 23.26
Evaluated at bid price : 25.50
Bid-YTW : 4.96 %
GWO.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.15 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 21.05
Evaluated at bid price : 21.05
Bid-YTW : 6.19 %
GWO.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.16 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 22.50
Evaluated at bid price : 22.61
Bid-YTW : 6.26 %
HSB.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 1.22 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 20.70
Evaluated at bid price : 20.70
Bid-YTW : 6.29 %
PWF.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 1.28 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 22.75
Evaluated at bid price : 23.02
Bid-YTW : 6.32 %
ENB.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.48 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 23.69
Evaluated at bid price : 24.00
Bid-YTW : 5.76 %
CM.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 1.58 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 22.89
Evaluated at bid price : 23.15
Bid-YTW : 6.12 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
RY.PR.X FixedReset 105,480 RBC crossed 99,800 at 27.04.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2014-09-23
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 27.05
Bid-YTW : 4.27 %
SLF.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 72,744 RBC sold 10,000 to Desjardins at 19.00, then crossed 26,000 at 19.01. Desjardins crossed 18,900 at 19.03.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 19.12
Evaluated at bid price : 19.12
Bid-YTW : 6.23 %
BNA.PR.C SplitShare 49,136 RBC crossed 46,200 at 19.10.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Hard Maturity
Maturity Date : 2019-01-10
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 19.02
Bid-YTW : 8.34 %
RY.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 46,700 TD crossed two blocks of 20,000 shares each at 19.20.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 19.17
Evaluated at bid price : 19.17
Bid-YTW : 5.92 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 41,561 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 19.57
Evaluated at bid price : 19.57
Bid-YTW : 6.22 %
BNS.PR.K Perpetual-Discount 40,840 Scotia bought 10,000 from National at 20.28.
YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-04
Maturity Price : 20.24
Evaluated at bid price : 20.24
Bid-YTW : 6.02 %
There were 27 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.
MAPF

MAPF Performance: May 2010

The fund had a positive month in May following three consecutive losses, and outperformed all the relevant indices and passive funds as the Floating Rate sector took a large loss. The Seniority Spread declined marginally (and perhaps spuriously) from 320bp on April 30 to 315bp on May 31.

The fund’s Net Asset Value per Unit as of the close May 31 was $10.1623.

Returns to May 31, 2010
Period MAPF Index CPD
according to
Claymore
One Month +1.10% +0.30% +0.94%
Three Months -3.25% -2.29% -2.11%
One Year +20.07% 11.29% +7.73%
Two Years (annualized) +23.43% +2.76% +0.64%*
Three Years (annualized) +16.09% +1.16% -0.89%
Four Years (annualized) +13.26% +1.13%  
Five Years (annualized) +11.61% +1.51%  
Six Years (annualized) +11.37% +2.37%  
Seven Years (annualized) +12.74% +2.63%  
Eight Years (annualized) +11.94% +3.27%  
Nine Years (annualized) +12.43% +3.11%  
The Index is the BMO-CM “50”
MAPF returns assume reinvestment of dividends, and are shown after expenses but before fees.
CPD Returns are for the NAV and are after all fees and expenses.
* CPD does not directly report its two-year returns. The figure shown is the square root of product of the current one-year return and the similar figure reported for May 2009.
Figures for Omega Preferred Equity (which are after all fees and expenses) for 1-, 3- and 12-months are +0.4%, -2.4% and +10.3%, respectively, according to Morningstar after all fees & expenses
Figures for Jov Leon Frazer Preferred Equity Fund Class I Units (which are after all fees and expenses) for 1-, 3- and 12-months are +0.6%, -2.5% & +5.5% respectively, according to Morningstar
Figures for AIC Preferred Income Fund (which are after all fees and expenses) for 1-, 3- and 12-months are +0.4%, -2.5% & +4.6%, respectively

MAPF returns assume reinvestment of dividends, and are shown after expenses but before fees. Past performance is not a guarantee of future performance. You can lose money investing in Malachite Aggressive Preferred Fund or any other fund. For more information, see the fund’s main page.

I am very pleased with the returns over the past year (which, now that the market and the fund’s returns have moderated, are now merely incredible, as opposed to “ridiculous” or “nonsensical”), but implore Assiduous Readers not to project this level of outperformance for the indefinite future. The year in the preferred share market was filled with episodes of panic and euphoria, together with many new entrants who do not appear to know what they are doing; perfect conditions for a disciplined quantitative approach.

Sometimes everything works … sometimes the trading works, but sectoral shifts overwhelm the increment … sometimes nothing works. The fund seeks to earn incremental return by selling liquidity (that is, taking the other side of trades that other market participants are strongly motivated to execute), which can also be referred to as ‘trading noise’. There have been a lot of strongly motivated market participants in the past year, generating a lot of noise! The conditions of the past year may never be repeated in my lifetime … but the fund will simply attempt to make trades when swaps seem profitable, whether that implies monthly turnover of 10% or 100%.

There’s plenty of room for new money left in the fund. Just don’t expect the current level of outperformance every year, OK? While I will continue to exert utmost efforts to outperform, it should be borne in mind that beating the index by 500bp represents a good year, and there will almost inevitably be periods of underperformance in the future.

The yields available on high quality preferred shares remain elevated, which is reflected in the current estimate of sustainable income.

Calculation of MAPF Sustainable Income Per Unit
Month NAVPU Portfolio
Average
YTW
Leverage
Divisor
Securities
Average
YTW
Capital
Gains
Multiplier
Sustainable
Income
per
current
Unit
June, 2007 9.3114 5.16% 1.03 5.01% 1.1883 0.3926
September 9.1489 5.35% 0.98 5.46% 1.1883 0.4203
December, 2007 9.0070 5.53% 0.942 5.87% 1.1883 0.4448
March, 2008 8.8512 6.17% 1.047 5.89% 1.1883 0.4389
June 8.3419 6.034% 0.952 6.338% 1.1883 $0.4449
September 8.1886 7.108% 0.969 7.335% 1.1883 $0.5054
December, 2008 8.0464 9.24% 1.008 9.166% 1.1883 $0.6206
March 2009 $8.8317 8.60% 0.995 8.802% 1.1883 $0.6423
June 10.9846 7.05% 0.999 7.057% 1.1883 $0.6524
September 12.3462 6.03% 0.998 6.042% 1.1883 $0.6278
December 2009 10.5662 5.74% 0.981 5.851% 1.0000 $0.6182
March 2010 10.2497 6.03% 0.992 6.079% 1.0000 $0.6231
May 2010 10.1623 6.35% 0.995 6.382% 1.0000 $0.6486
NAVPU is shown after quarterly distributions of dividend income and annual distribution of capital gains.
Portfolio YTW includes cash (or margin borrowing), with an assumed interest rate of 0.00%
The Leverage Divisor indicates the level of cash in the account: if the portfolio is 1% in cash, the Leverage Divisor will be 0.99
Securities YTW divides “Portfolio YTW” by the “Leverage Divisor” to show the average YTW on the securities held; this assumes that the cash is invested in (or raised from) all securities held, in proportion to their holdings.
The Capital Gains Multiplier adjusts for the effects of Capital Gains Dividends. On 2009-12-31, there was a capital gains distribution of $1.989262 which is assumed for this purpose to have been reinvested at the final price of $10.5662. Thus, a holder of one unit pre-distribution would have held 1.1883 units post-distribution; the CG Multiplier reflects this to make the time-series comparable. Note that Dividend Distributions are not assumed to be reinvested.
Sustainable Income is the resultant estimate of the fund’s dividend income per current unit, before fees and expenses. Note that a “current unit” includes reinvestment of prior capital gains; a unitholder would have had the calculated sustainable income with only, say, 0.9 units in the past which, with reinvestment of capital gains, would become 1.0 current units.

Significant positions were held in Fixed-Reset issues on April 30; all of which (with the exception of YPG.PR.C) currently have their yields calculated with the presumption that they will be called by the issuers at par at the first possible opportunity. A split-share issue (BNA.PR.C) is also held; since this has a maturity date, the yield cannot be regarded as permanently sustainable. This presents another complication in the calculation of sustainable yield.

However, if the entire portfolio except for the PerpetualDiscounts were to be sold and reinvested in these issues, the yield of the portfolio would be the 6.44% shown in the MAPF Portfolio Composition: May 2010 analysis (which is in excess of the 6.29% index yield on May 31). Given such reinvestment, the sustainable yield would be $10.1623 * 0.0644 = $0.6545 , whereas similar calculations for April and March result in $0.6503 and $0.6457, respectively.

Different assumptions lead to different results from the calculation, but the overall positive trend is apparent. I’m very pleased with the results! It will be noted that if there was no trading in the portfolio, one would expect the sustainable yield to be constant (before fees and expenses). The success of the fund’s trading is showing up in

  • the very good performance against the index
  • the long term increases in sustainable income per unit

As has been noted, the fund has maintained a credit quality equal to or better than the index; outperformance is due to constant exploitation of trading anomalies.

Again, there are no predictions for the future! The fund will continue to trade between issues in an attempt to exploit market gaps in liquidity, in an effort to outperform the index and keep the sustainable income per unit – however calculated! – growing.

Issue Comments

FIG.PR.A: Mass Retraction Prior to Warrant Expiry

Faircourt Asset Management, on behalf of Faircourt Income & Growth Split Trust, has announced:

that it has received requests for redemptions totaling approximately 6.4 million Units of the Trust. Payment will be made on July 22nd, 2010 based on the Net Asset Value per Trust Unit calculated using a three day volume weighted average price for exchange-traded securities held by the Trust, determined as of June 30, 2010 less costs of funding the redemption, including commissions.

The Trust currently has approximately 4.9 million Warrants outstanding, at an exercise price of $4.00 per unit while the current Net Asset Value of the Trust as at the close of business June 2nd is $4.57 or $4.34 on fully diluted basis. The Warrants will expire on June 25th, 2010. Holders of Warrants desiring to exercise Warrants and purchase Units should ensure that subscriptions and payment in full of the Subscription Price are received by the Warrant Agent prior to 4:01 p.m. (Toronto time) on June 25, 2010. Warrants submitted to the Warrant Agent for exercise on June 25, 2010 will be exercised in accordance with the practices and procedures of the Warrant Agent and the applicable CDS Participants

The fund, advised by Acuity Investment Management Inc., is most notable for having the Capital Units underperform the benchmark by over 20% annually in the five years to 2009-12-31. There were 9,806,610 units outstanding as of year-end, so this announcement reflects a mass churning by unitholders – assuming they exercise their warrants, which are in-the-money. Otherwise, of course, it’s just a plain mass-retraction.

FIG.PR.A was last mentioned on PrefBlog when the Capital Units’ dividend was reinstated. FIG.PR.A is tracked by HIMIPref™ but is relegated to the Scraps index on credit concerns.

Market Action

June 3, 2010

Covered bonds are seeing increased issuance:

About $5.7 billion of the securities have been sold or are being marketed this week worldwide, almost double last week’s volume, data compiled by Bloomberg show. Bank of Montreal, Canada’s fourth-largest bank, sold $2 billion of the bonds due in 2015.

The increase in covered bond sales contrasts with a decline in issuance for corporate debt, which fell to $70 billion last month, less than half April’s tally and the least since 2003.

It’s a nice trend, one that I hope continues and widens. It would be very nice if, for instance, long bonds secured by long lived assets (real-estate, etc.) were more available. The pendulum has swung too far in favour of companies’ equity holders.

The BMO Covered Bonds were USD, private placement, five-year, 2.85% coupon. Sounds good? Tough luck, Charlie, the regulators are protecting you from them.

DBRS comments:

Despite the above strengths, the Covered Bonds have the following challenges. First, a weakened housing market in Canada could result in higher defaults and loss severities than the assumptions used for credit protection assessment. This risk is significantly mitigated by the mortgage insurance covering principal and interest provided by AAA-rated CMHC. Second, BMO may be required to add mortgages to maintain the Cover Pool, incurring substitution and potential credit deterioration risk. These risks are mitigated by the mortgage insurance provided by CMHC and the ongoing monitoring of the Cover Pool to ensure the overcollateralization available (at least 3% as of May 31, 2010) is commensurate with the AAA rating assigned. Third, there is an inherent liquidity gap between the scheduled repayments of the Covered Bonds and the repayment of underlying mortgage loans over time. This risk is mitigated by the overcollateralized Cover Pool, the buildup of a reserve fund if BMO’s rating falls below A (low) or R-1 (middle) and the extendible maturity date for 12 months upon a default by BMO. Lastly, there is no specific covered bond legislative framework in Canada. This risk is mitigated by the contractual obligations of the transaction parties, supported by the well developed commercial and bankruptcy laws in Canada, satisfactory opinions provided by legal counsel to BMO and a generally creditor-friendly legal environment in Canada.

The legal framework problem is alleged to be under review, as discussed on PrefBlog on March 9 and by Ogilvy Renault, inter alia.

The SEC’s Market Structure Roundtable kicked off with a speech by Mary Shapiro:

Our roundtable is also informed by a more recent event: the severe, albeit brief, market disruption of May 6. For 20 minutes that afternoon, U.S. financial markets failed to execute their essential price discovery function, experiencing a decline and recovery that was unprecedented in its speed and scope. That period of fluctuating prices both directly harmed investors who traded based on flawed price discovery signals and undermined investors’ faith in the integrity and fairness of the markets

Her first conclusion – of direct harm – is a little hard to follow. There were two types of traders who traded during that period: value investors and idiots. The former made money. Shouldn’t we consider harm to idiots to be a good thing? I haven’t seen many signs of undermined faith, either. Meanwhile, Luis Aguilar appears to be lobbying for a post-SEC job as “investor advocate”.

On February 5 I discussed a form of solar power that actually has a chance of being more than a feel-good exercise; now, another method is attracting attention:

“We’ve produced tens of thousands of gallons, and by the end of 2010, I hope I can say we’ve produced hundreds of thousands,” [Solazyme cofounder] Wolfson, 39, says. “In the next two years, we should get the cost down to the $60 to $80-a-barrel range.”

At that price, Solazyme’s algae fuel would compete with $80-a-barrel oil.

Algae proponents differ on growing methods. Open ponds, the choice of most researchers, rely on photosynthesis. Algae grow and fill with oil as they use sunlight to convert carbon dioxide into sugar and chemical energy. Ponds, though, can get infested by pesky, low-oil native organisms or become the targets of microscopic aquatic creatures.

Solazyme is trying fermentation, producing its algae without light in metal vats. This requires adding sugar or other feedstock before the algae are dried and the oil extracted.

There’s hope for the world yet, evidenced by attitudes towards greenwashing:

When asked for their reasons for not living more greenly, 46 per cent of Canadians cited their belief that companies are “greenwashing,” lying about or exaggerating their products’ environmental sustainability. This cynicism beat out cost and inconvenience as reasons for not helping the environment.

smoking …:

In the new survey, 13 per cent of people in Grades 10 to 12 called themselves current smokers, up from 11 per cent during the previous survey period. While only 3 per cent of those in Grades 6 to 9 called themselves current smokers, unchanged from 2006-2007, that number rose from 2 per cent in 2004-2005.

“It is a troubling development,” [senior policy analyst at the Canadian Cancer Society] Mr. [Rob] Cunningham said. “The overwhelming majority of smokers begin as teens or preteens.”

… and Facebook …:

Privacy concerns don’t seem to have scared Canadians off Facebook.

More than 912,000 Canadians signed up for the site last month, a six-per-cent increase in membership.

Good, bad, indifferent … diversity of views and rejection of preaching platitudes can only be a good thing.

There was another strong advance in the Canadian preferred share market, this time on moderate volume, as PerpetualDiscounts gained 50bp and FixedResets were up 6bp. There were no losers on the performance table and PerpetualDiscounts dominated the volume highlights.

The Financial Post’s block trade reporter continues to be inoperable.

HIMIPref™ Preferred Indices
These values reflect the December 2008 revision of the HIMIPref™ Indices

Values are provisional and are finalized monthly
Index Mean
Current
Yield
(at bid)
Median
YTW
Median
Average
Trading
Value
Median
Mod Dur
(YTW)
Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 2.62 % 2.75 % 44,240 20.87 1 0.2326 % 2,122.2
FixedFloater 5.19 % 3.26 % 29,101 19.98 1 0.9634 % 3,084.9
Floater 2.41 % 2.80 % 92,327 20.18 3 0.0734 % 2,241.3
OpRet 4.89 % 3.86 % 96,796 2.82 11 0.1561 % 2,310.7
SplitShare 6.45 % 5.64 % 106,497 0.08 2 -0.0667 % 2,150.5
Interest-Bearing 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.1561 % 2,112.9
Perpetual-Premium 0.00 % 0.00 % 0 0.00 0 0.4975 % 1,843.0
Perpetual-Discount 6.15 % 6.22 % 206,512 13.61 77 0.4975 % 1,744.5
FixedReset 5.47 % 4.25 % 424,071 3.52 45 0.0580 % 2,160.2
Performance Highlights
Issue Index Change Notes
BNS.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.00 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 19.13
Evaluated at bid price : 19.13
Bid-YTW : 5.97 %
CM.PR.D Perpetual-Discount 1.02 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 23.45
Evaluated at bid price : 23.75
Bid-YTW : 6.13 %
PWF.PR.L Perpetual-Discount 1.04 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 20.41
Evaluated at bid price : 20.41
Bid-YTW : 6.34 %
CM.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.05 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 21.71
Evaluated at bid price : 22.04
Bid-YTW : 6.20 %
CM.PR.P Perpetual-Discount 1.11 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 22.37
Evaluated at bid price : 22.80
Bid-YTW : 6.09 %
SLF.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 1.12 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 18.08
Evaluated at bid price : 18.08
Bid-YTW : 6.24 %
W.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 1.18 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 21.50
Evaluated at bid price : 21.50
Bid-YTW : 6.51 %
SLF.PR.C Perpetual-Discount 1.19 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 17.86
Evaluated at bid price : 17.86
Bid-YTW : 6.24 %
PWF.PR.G Perpetual-Discount 1.33 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 23.44
Evaluated at bid price : 23.70
Bid-YTW : 6.30 %
PWF.PR.E Perpetual-Discount 1.38 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 21.85
Evaluated at bid price : 22.10
Bid-YTW : 6.30 %
POW.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.56 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 22.60
Evaluated at bid price : 22.85
Bid-YTW : 6.22 %
PWF.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 1.59 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 21.10
Evaluated at bid price : 21.10
Bid-YTW : 6.31 %
ENB.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 1.59 % YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 23.36
Evaluated at bid price : 23.65
Bid-YTW : 5.84 %
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Shares
Traded
Notes
TD.PR.S FixedReset 111,335 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Call
Maturity Date : 2013-08-30
Maturity Price : 25.00
Evaluated at bid price : 25.71
Bid-YTW : 4.23 %
CM.PR.J Perpetual-Discount 101,612 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 18.40
Evaluated at bid price : 18.40
Bid-YTW : 6.20 %
ELF.PR.F Perpetual-Discount 84,200 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 19.30
Evaluated at bid price : 19.30
Bid-YTW : 7.00 %
CM.PR.H Perpetual-Discount 71,310 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 19.53
Evaluated at bid price : 19.53
Bid-YTW : 6.23 %
SLF.PR.A Perpetual-Discount 57,925 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 18.94
Evaluated at bid price : 18.94
Bid-YTW : 6.28 %
CM.PR.I Perpetual-Discount 54,470 YTW SCENARIO
Maturity Type : Limit Maturity
Maturity Date : 2040-06-03
Maturity Price : 19.24
Evaluated at bid price : 19.24
Bid-YTW : 6.20 %
There were 26 other index-included issues trading in excess of 10,000 shares.