Archive for March, 2008

RPQ.PR.A : Creditwatch Negative by S&P

Thursday, March 13th, 2008

Connor, Clark & Lunn has announced:

that its preferred shares have been placed on CreditWatch with negative implications as of today. The preferred shares are currently rated P-1 (low) by Standard & Poor’s (“S&P”). The move comes as the result of recent downgrades in the Reference Portfolio as well the removal of Residential Capital from the portfolio and its replacement with Tribune Corp, which was lower-rated at the time of the replacement. There have been no defaults in the reference portfolio since its launch in February 2006.

The rating on the preferred shares reflects the A- rating on the C$95,040,000 fixed-rate managed credit linked note issued by the Bank of Nova Scotia (the “CLN”). The return on the CLN, and thus on the preferred shares, is linked to the credit performance of a portfolio of 127 companies (the “Reference Portfolio”). The Reference Portfolio is actively managed by Connor, Clark & Lunn Investment Management Ltd. The CLN benefits from subordination of 2.82% of the reference portfolio as well as a trading reserve account which would currently buy an additional 0.07% of subordination. As a result, if there are less than seven defaults in the next three and a quarter years, investors will continue to receive scheduled quarterly distributions as well as the full $25 par value at maturity.

CC&L ROC Pref Corp. matures in June 2011. The S&P rating speaks to the product’s ability to pay all of its dividends and to return the full $25 par value at maturity. CC&L remains confident that CC&L ROC Pref Corp. will meet its investment objectives.

A similary CC&L structured instrument, RPA.PR.A, sustained a “credit event” in January, but there have been no developments since then for this issue.

RPQ.PR.A is not tracked by HIMIPref™.

Economic Effects of Subprime, Part III: Leverage and Amplification

Thursday, March 13th, 2008

In the comments to my post Is the US Banking System Really Insolvent? Prof. Menzie Chin brought to my attention a wonderful paper: Leveraged Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage Market Meltdown (hereafter, “Greenlaw et al.”).

This paper has also been highlighted on Econbrowser under the title Tabulating the Credit Crunch’s Effects: One Educated Guess.

The source document is in several parts – to do justice to it, I will be be posting reviews of each section.

The initial post in this series Economic Effects of Subprime, Part I: Loss Estimates dealt with the authors’ methodology of estimating total losses of $400-billion on subprime securities. The second, Economic Effects of Subprime, Part II : Distribution of Exposure, looked at the way they allocated 49% of this loss to the “US Leveraged Sector”. In this post, I’ll be looking (very briefly!) at their “Section 4: Leverage and Amplification”.

I will admit, I had half a mind to skip it. I felt comfortable opining on their sections directly relevant to the securities markets, but economic predictions are another animal entirely. Fortunately, Willem Buiter stepped into the breach, with a highly entertaining polemic on VoxEU.

Greenlaw et al. review the procyclical nature of leveraging and eventually come up with the scorecard so far:

So far (up to late-January 2008) approximately $75 billion of new capital has been raised, compared to a cumulative running total of $120.9 billion for write-downs announced by banks and brokerage firms.

It does not appear that this figure of $120.9-billion is restricted to US banks and brokerages – and since the authors do not say, I suspect it is a world-wide figure.

At any rate, they go through a little arithmetic and conclude:

Our baseline scenario (marked in grey) is that leverage will decline by 5%, and that recapitalization of the leveraged system will recoup around 50% of the $ 200 billion loss incurred by the banking system. Under this baseline scenario, the total contraction of balance sheets for the financial sector is $1.98 trillion.

Section 4.4 does a little algebra to estimate the ratio of the decline in credit to end-users to the decline in total assets which, I am grateful to observe, is as fishy to Prof. Buiter as it is to me. Prof. Buiter observes:

The authors calculate/calibrate a value for the ratio of total credit to end-users (either the non-leveraged sector or just households and non-financial corporates) to the total assets of the leveraged sector (banks, the brokerage sector, hedge funds, Fannie May and Freddie Mac and savings institutions and credit unions). They then treat this ratio as a constant, which means that once they have the change in the value of the total assets of the leveraged sector, they know the change in credit to the end-users.

There are just too many ways to poke holes in the empirical argument. To start with, as noted by the authors) the credit variable used domestic non-financial debt, includes financing from non-leveraged entities and therefore does not correspond to the credit variable of the theoretical story.

My problem with this – which I think is the same as Prof. Buiter’s problem – is that the algebra treats the “leveraged sector” as being homogeneous … and it ain’t. Say, for instance, we have a Hedge Fund with $1 in investors’ money, levered up 10:1 to buy $10 of securities. Their balance sheet looks like:

Hedge Fund
Item Asset Liability
Securities $10  
Borrow   $9
Investors   $1

They are borrowing from a bank, which has the balance sheet:

Bank
Item Asset Liability
Loan to HF $9  
Deposits   $8.10
Capital   $0.90

Now what happens is the value of the securities falls to $9, the bank calls its loan and ends up owning the securities. The two balance sheets now look like:

Hedge Fund
Item Asset Liability
Securities $0  
Borrow   $0
Investors   $0

While the Bank’s balance sheet has changed to:

Bank
Item Asset Liability
Securities $9  
Depositors   $8.10
Capital   $0.90

So, with this particular example:

  • Aggregate leverage is unchanged: ($10 + $9) / ($1 + $0.90) = 10:1 = ($9 / $0.90)
  • the bank has been protected from the first loss on the securities since its claim was senior to that of the investors in the hedge fund.
  • Hedge fund investors have been wiped out
  • The bank’s liquidity has improved (since securities are more marketable than hedge fund loans)
  • There is no effect directly transmitted from the bank to the real economy.
  • There may be an effect on the real economy because the hedge fund investors aren’t so rich any more, but that’s second order

I just have all kinds of problems with this, Greenlaw et al‘s treatment of the leveraged sector as being homogeneous with effects on credit available to the real economy being a constant percentage of losses, regardless of where or how those losses are experienced.

I won’t look at their section 5.1, Correlations between GDP and Credit … I’m just not comfortable enough with economic thought. I’ll leave that task to Prof. Buiter:

More painfully, the authors seem blithely unaware of the difference between causation and correlation, or prediction and causation. What they perform is, effectively, half of what statistically minded economists call a Granger causality test but should be called a test of incremental predictive content. They run a regression of real GDP growth on its own past values and on past values of real credit growth and find that past real credit growth has some predictive power over future GDP growth, over and above the predictive power contained in the history of real GDP growth itself: past real credit growth helps predict, that is, Granger causes, real GDP growth. Lagged real credit growth is (barely) statistically significant at the usual significance level (5%).

When you do this kind of regression for dividends or corporate earnings and stock values, you find that stock values Granger-cause (help predict) future dividends. Of course, anticipated future dividends determine (cause) equity prices, so causation is the opposite from Granger-causation.

The authors are undeterred and treat the estimate of GPD growth on credit growth as a deep structural parameter.

The authors could be right about the effect of de-leveraging in the leveraged sector on real GDP growth, but the paper presents no evidence to support that view.

So, to sum up:

  • I’m suspicious of the authors’ loss estimates
  • I’m suspicious of the authors’ allocation
  • I’m suspicious of the authors’ calculation on the effect of losses on credit available to the real economy
  • Prof. Buiter is suspicious of the authors’ calculation of the effects of credit availability changes on GDP

All in all, the paper by Greenlaw et al. has turned out to be a typical product of brokerage house research departments:

  • Great Data
  • Interesting Ideas
  • Unsupportable conclusions

Moody's to Assign Global Ratings to Municipals

Thursday, March 13th, 2008

Via Naked Capitalism and MarketWatch comes Moody’s Senior Managing Director for Global Public, Project and Infrastructure Finance Group Laura Levenstein’s testimony to the House Financial Services Committee:

we have recently decided to assign global ratings to municipal issuers upon request and welcome additional market feedback on measures that would improve the overall transparency and value of Moody’s ratings systems.

Historically, this type of analysis has not been as helpful to municipal investors. If municipal bonds were rated using our global ratings system, the great majority of our ratings likely would fall between just two rating categories: Aaa and Aa. This would eliminate the primary value that municipal investors have historically sought from ratings – namely, the ability to differentiate among various municipal securities. We have been told by investors that eliminating that differentiation would make the market less transparent, more opaque, and presumably, less efficient both for investors and issuers.

In 2001, Moody’s met with over 100 market participants to understand their views on the need for and value of globally consistent ratings. The vast majority of participants surveyed indicated that they valued the municipal rating scale in its current form. Additionally, many market participants expressed concerns that any migration of municipal ratings to be consistent with the global rating scale would result in considerable compression of ratings in the Aa and Aaa range, thereby reducing the discriminating power of the rating and transparency in the market.

In 2006, we published a Request for Comment asking market participants whether they would value greater transparency about the conversion of our municipal rating system to a global rating system. We received over 40 written responses and had telephone and in-person discussions with many other market participants. Generally, the majority indicated that they valued the distinctions the current rating system provides in terms of relative credit risk, but that they would endorse the expansion of assigning global ratings to taxable municipal bonds sold inside the U.S.

In 2007, based on the above feedback and to further improve the transparency of our long-term municipal bond ratings, we

  • implemented a new analytical approach for mapping municipal ratings to global ratings, thereby enabling investors to compare municipal bonds to corporate bonds while maintaining the municipal scale that investors and issuers told us they valued;
  • published a conversion chart that market participants could use to estimate a global rating from a municipal rating; and
  • announced that, when requested by the issuers, we would assign a global rating to any of their taxable securities, regardless of whether the securities were issued within or outside the United States.


We are already re-evaluating our existing municipal ratings system and will be issuing a Request for Comment in which we will:

  • propose assigning global ratings to any tax-exempt bond issuance, including previously issued securities as well as new issues, at the issuer’s request beginning in May 2008;
  • clarify that the conversion table we published in our March 2007 report can beapplied to both tax-exempt and taxable municipal securities; and,
  • ask whether market participants would prefer a simplified conversion table that would make it easier to estimate a global rating from a municipal rating.

This is all rather odd … according to the critics, we desperately need a separate scale for structured finance, because it’s obviously misleading to use a global scale. And we need to put Munis on a global scale, because it’s obviously misleading to use a separate scale. It’s just odd.

And, Assiduous Readers will know without having been told, the investor universe is different for tax-exempt munis than it is for corporate bonds. Pension funds don’t invest in tax-exempt munis … they’re already tax-exempt. Mom & Pop invest in tax-exempt munis, at five grand a crack.

Barney Frank’s remarks, almost certainly made with full knowledge of the gist of the testimony, were reported on the March 12 Market Action Report.

David Einhorn will be happy about this proposed change, but I don’t know what the unintended consequences will be. I’m just extremely worried about this hint of political influence in credit rating agency decisions.

March 12, 2008

Wednesday, March 12th, 2008

Econbrowser‘s James Hamilton has an interesting philosophical piece on the limits to the Fed’s ability to influence the economy, Asking too much of monetary policy:

I am certainly a believer in the potential real effects, sometimes for good, sometimes for ill, of monetary policy. But I just as certainly do not believe, nor should any reasonable person believe, that no matter what the economic problem might be, you can always solve it just by printing more money.

I would nevertheless caution that we need to be open to the possibility that no matter how low the Fed brings its target rate, it may not arrest the unfolding financial disaster. Unless the intention is to go all the way with enough inflation to avert the defaults, that means we need an exit strategy– some point at which we all admit that further monetary stimulus is doing nothing more than generating inflation, and at which point we acknowledge that the goal for monetary policy is no longer the heroic objective of making bad loans become good, but instead the more modest but also more attainable objective of making sure that fluctuations in the purchasing power of a dollar are not themselves a separate destabilizing influence.

Indeed, with the Treasury curve virtually decoupled from the corporate curve, it doesn’t look like there’s anything more the Fed can do. Cutting rates again probably will not have any major effect on corporate yields, or on banks’ willingness to lend; I think that the only justification for such a move would be to help increase profit margins at the banks in order to assist their recapitalization, as was done in 1993 – the year of the steepest yield curve on record, which led to 1994 – the year of the worst government bond market on record.

At the moment, I don’t think there’s a lot of evidence that such drastic treatment is necessary. Below are some graphs available from the FDIC showing the recovery of the American banking system from 1990-94 … sorry they’re not too clear, click on them for a better version, or just go directly to the full report.

Some of this was due to Resolution Trust, to be sure, but a good chunk was due to a very steep yield curve that made it very profitable to borrow short and lend long.

It is interesting to note, from the FDIC report, that data for 4Q93 (the point at which the Fed said, “OK, play-time’s over, we’re going to start hiking now”) indicated that the 13,220 institutions reporting had $375-billion in capital backstopping $4,707-billion in total liabilities and capital, an equity leverage ratio of 12.61. The current FDIC report, 4Q07, shows 8,533 institutions with capital of $1,352-billion backstopping $13,039-billion, equity leverage of 9.6:1.

One may well quibble over the 4Q07 equity figure … perhaps there are massive unrecorded losses about to appear. And one may quibble even more about the relative quality of assets between then and now – subprime and perhaps credit card and auto debt coming up for kicking in The Great Leverage Unwinding of 2007-08. But all in all, as I’ve pointed out in posts on loss estimates and loss distribution, I’m having a hell of a time finding credible, sober analysis concluding that Armageddon is Now.

Anyway, what I’m trying to say is that I agree with Prof. Hamilton (subject to quibbles about loss estimates), when he states:

The problem then is many hundreds of billions of dollars in loans that are not going to be repaid, the prospect of whose default could completely freeze the market for credit.

That, it seems to me, is a problem you can’t solve by lowering the fed funds rate.

By me, the Fed is doing the right thing with the TSLF introduced yesterday. The problem is liquidity, and there are many players with indigestible lumps of sub-prime paper on their books. These are, I’ll bet a nickel, on their books at marked-to-disfunctional-market prices well below ultimate recovery, but so what? They can’t sell them to hot money – hot money’s got its own problems:

At least a dozen hedge funds have closed, sold assets or sought fresh capital in the past month as banks and securities firms tightened lending standards. The industry is reeling from its worst crisis because bankers — staggered by almost $190 billion of asset writedowns and credit losses caused by the collapse of the subprime-mortgage market — are raising borrowing rates and demanding extra collateral for loans.

They can’t sell them to real money – real money read in the paper just last week that it’s all worthless junk. So the paper has to sit on the books for a while and be financed in the interim.

Perhaps not entirely coincidentally, there’s an article on VoxEU titled Why Monetary Policy Cannot Stabilize Asset Prices. VoxEU is up to its old tricks … the page is blank. To read the article, you have to click “View|Source” on your browser, pick a section to copy/paste, save this extract as a .html file on your hard drive and then open this with a browser. The graph has to be viewed separately.

Mechanical difficulties aside, it seems that this will soon be a CEPR discussion paper; the authors state:

Figure 1 analyses the effects of a 100 basis points increase in interest rates. Note that after about 8 quarters, interest rates have declined but remain about 35 basis points above their initial level. After 12 quarters, they have fallen further to a level some 10 basis points above the starting point. Overall, the increase in interest rates will dissipate in about three years.

Turning to real property prices, we note that these start to fall in response to the tightening of monetary policy. After 16 quarters, they reach a bottom of about 2.6% below the initial level and then start to return gradually to their starting level. Overall, property prices react quite slowly to monetary policy actions.

Next we consider the responses of real GDP.3 The figure shows that it also reaches a trough after 16 quarters, when it is some 0.8% below its initial level.4 Thus, the responses of real GDP are almost exactly 1/3 of those of real property prices.5 This is an important finding. To see why, suppose that monetary policy makers come to believe that a real property price bubble of 15% has developed, and decide to tighten monetary policy in order to bring down asset prices. In doing so, the average central bank in the 17 countries we study should also expect to depress the level of real GDP by 5%, a truly massive amount.

Whatever merits such a stabilisation policy has in theory, our research suggests that in practice, monetary policy is too blunt an instrument to be used to target asset prices – the effects on real property prices are too small, given the responses of real GDP, and they are too slow, given the responses of real equity prices. In particular, there is a risk that setting monetary policy in response to asset price movements will lead to large output losses that exceed by a wide margin those that would arise from a possible bubble burst.

In other news, Accrued Interest points out that It’s just a dead animal:

Now I’m not here to say whether Bear Stearns has liquidity problems or not. The recovery in both the stock and bond market for Bear paper would indicate that they probably don’t. But this kind of panicky trading is exactly why its hard to own financial bonds right now. I mean, anyone who had traded through bear markets knows that the rumor mill becomes very active. Right now everyone is nervous. The longs are nervous because they’ve been losing money and/or under performing their index for months now. I’m sure there are many portfolio managers and/or traders worried about losing their jobs over poor performance.

The shorts are nervous too. Right now corporate credit spreads are at all-time wides. That means that getting short a credit is expensive to begin with.

So amidst all this nervousness, it seems that Wall Street starts giving more credence to rumors.

Sit tight, do your homework, turn off the TV and stare at financial statements until you’re crosseyed, that’s the path to success. The bond market is excitable and always will be … ignore it, keep your company-specific bets small, your leverage non-existant and have another look at them financial statements.

In other news, it looks like Barney Frank, Chairman of the House Financial Services Committee wants to start his own credit rating agency:

U.S. Representative Barney Frank gave ratings companies a month to fix “ridiculous” standards that they apply to local government debt, as his House committee opened a hearing today on how the firms evaluate municipal bonds.

“I am going to say to the rating agencies and to the insurers: they have about a month to fix this,” Frank, the Massachusetts Democrat who chairs the House Financial Services Committee, told reporters in Washington yesterday. “We’re going to tell them they have to straighten it out.”

California Treasurer Bill Lockyer and other state officials are calling for Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s Investors Service, and Fitch Ratings to change a system they say costs taxpayers by exaggerating the risk that municipal issuers will default on their debts. Every state except Louisiana would be AAA if measured by the scale used for corporate borrowers, according to research by Moody’s.

“This notion of having a separate standard for the municipals because they would do too well on the other standard is ridiculous,” Frank said.

Cool! Credit ratings courtesy of the politicians! Doesn’t that make you feel safe? Sign me up!

Back on Earth, Berkshire Hathaway is worried that municipal bond insurance will return to ultra-cheap levels in a price-war:

The risk of guaranteeing municipal debt is increasing because the economy is slowing and some insurers may cut prices to regain lost business, said Ajit Jain, head of Berkshire Hathaway Inc.’s new bond insurer.

Fiscal stress in Vallejo, California, and Jefferson County, Alabama, may be the “tip of the iceberg” for municipal defaults, said Jain, who runs Warren Buffett’s Berkshire Hathaway Assurance Corp. He said downgrades of some insurers hurt the industry’s integrity and those firms may spark “pricing wars” if they regain their financial footing and seek to recoup lost business.

Ambac and MBIA, the two largest bond insurers, may trigger a price war if they stabilize their AAA ratings and start backing municipal bonds again, Jain said.

“That will be unavoidable,” he said in his testimony. “Unless you continue to believe that this is zero-loss business, that conduct assures a bleak future for this business.”

Another light day for volume. Split-shares got hammered, particularly the BNA issues that have something of a penchant for volatility. PerpetualDiscounts were also weak.

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 5.46% 5.47% 33,229 14.69 2 -0.1015% 1,094.4
Fixed-Floater 4.75% 5.55% 64,138 14.81 8 -0.1569% 1,045.1
Floater 4.79% 4.79% 85,140 15.91 2 +0.1465% 867.1
Op. Retract 4.85% 3.58% 76,364 2.79 15 +0.1893% 1,044.8
Split-Share 5.37% 5.89% 97,468 4.15 14 -0.8128% 1,025.1
Interest Bearing 6.15% 6.48% 69,095 4.24 3 +0.3395% 1,090.4
Perpetual-Premium 5.77% 5.48% 277,034 7.62 17 -0.0465% 1,022.8
Perpetual-Discount 5.48% 5.53% 311,507  14.60  52 -0.1323% 941.3
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
BNA.PR.B SplitShare -4.8072% Asset coverage of 3.3+:1 as of January 31, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 8.50% based on a bid of 20.00 and hardMaturity 2016-3-25 at 25.00. Compare with BNA.PR.A (5.88% to hardMaturity 2010-9-30) and BNA.PR.C (7.22% to hardMaturity 2019-10-1).
FFN.PR.A SplitShare -2.8141% Asset coverage of just under 2.0:1 as of February 29, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.92% based on a bid of 9.67 and hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00.
BCE.PR.Z FixFloat -2.0417%  
POW.PR.D PerpetualDiscount -1.9870% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.60% based on a bid of 22.69 and a limitMaturity.
MFC.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -1.5837% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.18% based on a bid of 21.75 and a limitMaturity.
FBS.PR.B SplitShare -1.5609% Asset coverage of just under 1.5:1 as of March 6, according to TD Securities. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.42% based on a bid of 9.46 and a hardMaturity 2011-12-15 at 10.00.
BNA.PR.C SplitShare -1.5454% See BNA.PR.A, above.
CIU.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -1.3005% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.46% based on a bid of 21.25 and a limitMaturity.
POW.PR.B PerpetualDiscount -1.2689% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.63% based on a bid of 24.12 and a limitMaturity.
DFN.PR.A SplitShare -1.2476% Asset coverage of just under 2.5:1 as of February 29, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.80% based on a bid of 10.29 and a hardMaturity 2014-12-1 at 10.00.
PWF.PR.I PerpetualPremium -1.0481% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.70% based on a bid of 25.49 and a call 2012-5-30 at 25.00.
GWO.PR.E OpRet +1.6653% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.60% based on a bid of 25.03 and a call 2011-4-30 at 25.00.
HSB.PR.C PerpetualDiscount +1.8605% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.26% based on a bid of 24.25 and a limitMaturity.
BAM.PR.I OpRet +1.8652% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.05% based on a bid of 25.53 and a softMaturity 2013-12-30 at 25.00. Compare with BAM.PR.H (5.30% to softMaturity 2012-3-30) and BAM.PR.J (5.40% to softMaturity 2018-3-30).
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
TD.PR.R PerpetualDiscount 771,292 New issue settled today. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.65% based on a bid of 24.88 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.G PerpetualDiscount 55,330 RBC crossed 50,000 at 21.15. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.36% based on a bid of 21.20 and a limitMaturity.
BMO.PR.H PerpetualDiscount 50,200 Nesbitt crossed 50,000 at 24.00. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.53% based on a bid of 23.91 and a limitMaturity.
SLF.PR.E PerpetualDiscount 25,208 Desjardins crossed 25,000 at 21.40. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.28% based on a bid of 21.36 and a limitMaturity.
MFC.PR.C PerpetualDiscount 17,310 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW 5.18% based on a bid of 21.75 and a limitMaturity.

There were eight other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

TD.PR.R Settles: Too Much Hot Money?

Wednesday, March 12th, 2008

TD.PR.R, announced March 3, settled today and was unable to trade above par, with volume of 771,292 in a range of 24.85-97. The closing quotation was 24.88-90, 29×2.

This is particularly surprising since the very similar TD.PR.Q (the only difference is a three month shift in redemption schedule and a long first coupon for TD.PR.R), which had been trading around 25.60 prior to the TD.PR.R announcement, closed at 25.10-15, 20×8 today.

Given the volume for TD.PR.R and the fact that the take-up of the greenshoe was announced on the day following the new issue announcement, I can only assume that the underwriting was a success but that, unfortunately for some, there were a great many players who decided that the new issue would instantly trade at a sixty-cent premium and resolved to subscribe to the issue and sell at the opening.

Too many cooks spoil the broth! We are now in the fairly unusual situation in which one member of a Preferred Pair is in the PerpetualDiscount index, and the other is a PerpetualPremium!

It is also noteworthy that the similar TD.PR.P, which pays a dividend of $1.3125 compared to $1.40 for the other two, closed at 24.40-44, 6×7, with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.45%.

Curve Prices (that is to say, fair values as estimated by HIMIPref™) were: TD.PR.P = 24.10; TD.PR.Q = 25.26; TD.PR.R = 25.14.

March 11, 2008

Tuesday, March 11th, 2008

Today’s big news was the expansion of the Term Securities Lending Facility:

The Federal Reserve announced today an expansion of its securities lending program.  Under this new Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF), the Federal Reserve will lend up to $200 billion of Treasury securities to primary dealers secured for a term of 28 days (rather than overnight, as in the existing program) by a pledge of other securities, including federal agency debt, federal agency residential-mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and non-agency AAA/Aaa-rated private-label residential MBS.  The TSLF is intended to promote liquidity in the financing markets for Treasury and other collateral and thus to foster the functioning of financial markets more generally.  As is the case with the current securities lending program, securities will be made available through an auction process.  Auctions will be held on a weekly basis, beginning on March 27, 2008.  The Federal Reserve will consult with primary dealers on technical design features of the TSLF.

The kerfuffle over Bear Stearns yesterday shows that the market is prepared to believe anything, as long as it’s bad. Yes, times are tough. But they actually managed to scrape out a profit last year (Nov. 30 year end) and have $18-billion cash on the balance sheet thanks to a vigorous term issuance programme in which they haven’t been afraid to pay up for five year money. They’re not going to disappear overnight. Though mind you, as Naked Capitalism points out, they’re very highly levered:

With this in mind, why were Bear and Lehman so highly geared? Lehman is levered 40 to 1, Bear is geared 34:1 (by contrast, Carlyie is levered 32:1). Trading firms should know better.

In deteriorating debt markets, the last thing you want to be carrying is a big balance sheet. Perhaps the banks in question assumed that the Fed’s interest rate cuts would produce enough gains in value (due to lower prevailing rates) to make deleveraging less urgent.

But now Bear and Lehman (and no doubt their peers as well) are delevearging out of necessity, as mark-to-market losses force them to write down assets, leading to hits to equity, and then putting them at gearing levels that are untenable. So shrink they must.

And, mind you, if I was thinking about buying their stock, I wouldn’t be counting on a return to pre-2007 earnings anytime soon. Neither would Punk Ziegel.

“The key problem is not the write-offs and losses that the company must take in the just-ended first fiscal quarter. The key issue is building a new business model,” Bove said. “Bear Stearns must adjust and it is probably going to be forced to find a merger partner,” he added.

Find a partner? Maybe they have!

Joseph Lewis, the second-largest shareholder in Bear Stearns Cos., may add to his holdings after the stock fell on speculation the company lacks sufficient access to capital, a person close to him said.

Times are tough, did I say above? Econbrowser‘s James Hamilton won’t quarrel if you say a recession has begun and his partner Menzie Chinn takes a certain amount of Democrat glee in the prospects for a two recession Bush presidency:

So, I’ll echo Jim’s assessment: too soon to be sure, but chances are pretty darn good that we that we’re into the second recession of the G.W. Bush presidency.

It seems to me the next question of interest is whether the recession is likely to be short or long. I keep on seeing predictions of a short V-shaped recession [3], [4], [5]. Most macro forecasts do predict a resurgence in 2008H2 (just as CEA Chair Lazear alluded to in his last press conference). For instance, today’s Deutsche Bank forecast is for (-0.5%) and (-0.3%) in Q1 and Q2, respectively, with growth spiking in Q3 at 2.6% before settling at 0.9% in Q4. Still, with oil and ag commodity prices stubbornly high, the extent of the financial system turmoil uncertain, and the less-than optimally constructed fiscal stimulus limited to only one percent of GDP, I’m don’t think the 2008H2 acceleration will be a sustained one.

Well … I’m not an economist and I have a high degree of skepticism towards any macro-forecast anyway … but if I had to bet a nickel I’d bet on a long grinding recession that squeezes every last bit of leverage out of the system. The credit markets are thoroughly disfunctional, borrowers are extending term to stay alive (Bear Stearns, CIT, …) rather than to expand and these funds are staying on the balance sheet as cash at a negative carry (Bear Stearns, CIT, …). I don’t know what will happen tomorrow, but I can say it looks pretty ugly out there today!

As usual, Accrued Interest has some sensible remarks regarding what will bring an end to the credit market:

What would bring an end to this bear market? Simple. Bear markets end when the market runs out of sellers.

I would prefer to phrase it … ‘Bear markets end when prices stop going down’, but this is a mere quibble.

Naked Capitalism has an interesting piece on the Credit Rating Agencies’ alleged reluctance to cut the ratings on AAA sub-prime paper:

The Bloomberg story confirms our cynicism about the S&P’s and Moody’s. It reports that the rating agencies have held back from downgrading AAA subprime related securities.

Why is this important? In most deals, roughly 80% is of the value of the transaction was in the AAA tranches. These are far and away the most important in terms of economic value. But, not surprisingly, many of the buyers of this paper did so because they had portfolio constraints or capital requirements that made top-rated instruments particularly desirable. Thus in many cases, downgrades of this paper would have a pronounced impact, leading in many cases to sales, depressing prices.

The ratings methods balance estimated losses against so-called credit support, a measure of how likely it is that owners of each piece of the bond will incur losses. For AAA rated debt, credit support needs to be five times the expected losses, according to Sylvain Raynes, author of The Analysis of Structured Securities, a college textbook.

All but six of the 80 AAA ABX bonds failed an S&P test for investment-grade status, which requires credit support to be twice the percentage of troubled collateral. The guideline was one of four tests used by S&P, and a failure to meet the standard wouldn’t have automatically resulted in a downgrade. The other companies used similar metrics to grade bonds, Raynes said. Investment grade refers to all bonds rated above BBB- by S&P and Baa3 by Moody’s….

On a $118 million Washington Mutual bond issued in 2007, WMHE 2007-HE2 2A4, 5.6 percent of its loans are in foreclosure and its safety margin, or the debt available to absorb losses, is less than the combined total of its loans at risk. Both S&P and Moody’s rate it AAA.

Fitch rates that bond B, five levels below investment grade and 15 levels less than its rivals….

The full Bloomberg story explains the Fitch discrepency a little better:

“We have built in 20 percent more home price declines from the end of ’07,” said Glenn Costello, managing director for residential mortgage-backed securities at Fitch. “When you build in that much home price decline, I feel good when I pick up the paper and I see that home prices are only down another 3 percent. My ratings are still good.”

Fitch is a good shop. I like Fitch.

In yet another sign of the cavalier sloppiness that was epidemic at the height of the bubble, there are indications that CDO deal documents are not clear:

These bad decisions, in turn, have resulted in the collapse of many investment vehicles: more than 100 collateralised debt obligations (CDOs) and structured investment vehicles (SIVs) have already entered the murky post-event of default (EOD) state. This number will grow in the coming weeks.

Unfortunately, the legal documents that govern these transactions are so poorly written – full of ambiguities, inconsistencies, “circular references” and worse, contradictions – that many investors, trustees and respective legal advisors do not know how to interpret them.

The lawyers will feast!

Speaking of lawyers and their feasting, I was asked recently about BCE’s bonds following their triumph over the bondholders. It was one of Markit’s “CDS Deteriorators” on March 10, with 5-Year CDS yields increasing 73bp to 646bp. According to Markit’s CDS commentary for March 10:

BCE’s spreads widened on expectations that the company’s LBO will go ahead. A Quebec Court threw out a bondholder lawsuit that alleged the takeover of the Canadian telecoms company by an investment consortium was unlawful.

Volume returned to the preferred market today and was actually relatively heavy – the first time that’s happened in a while! I don’t know quite what to make of the price and volume activity in the PWF/GWO issues … there’s no news that I can see – it may just be a single manager re-jigging his portfolio. Or random chance!

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 5.46% 5.47% 33,714 14.69 2 +0.6357% 1,095.5
Fixed-Floater 4.75% 5.54% 65,192 14.81 8 +0.3328% 1,046.7
Floater 4.73% 4.81% 85,992 15.75 2 -0.2826% 865.8
Op. Retract 4.84% 3.11% 75,909 2.93 15 -0.1809% 1,042.9
Split-Share 5.32% 5.67% 97,130 4.04 14 +0.3192% 1,033.5
Interest Bearing 6.17% 6.52% 68,570 4.23 3 +0.6168% 1,086.7
Perpetual-Premium 5.76% 5.45% 282,678 7.74 17 +0.0534% 1,023.3
Perpetual-Discount 5.46% 5.52% 261,975 14.61 51 -0.0211% 942.6
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
GWO.PR.E OpRet -3.6399% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.97% based on a bid of 24.62 and a softMaturity 2014-3-30 at 25.00.
GWO.PR.H PerpetualDiscount -2.1885% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.55% based on a bid of 21.90 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.H PerpetualDiscount -1.1765% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.80% based on a bid of 21.00 and a limitMaturity.
PWF.PR.K PerpetualDiscount -1.0480% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.53% based on a bid of 22.66 and a limitMaturity.
WFS.PR.A SplitShare +1.0152% Asset coverage of just under 1.7:1 as of March 6, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.80% based on a bid of 9.95 and a hardMaturity 2011-6-30 at 10.00.
BCE.PR.R FixFloat +1.0417%  
BCE.PR.B FixFloat +1.0417%  
BNS.PR.M PerpetualDiscount +1.0427% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.35% based on a bid of 21.32 and a limitMaturity.
FBS.PR.B SplitShare +1.1579% Asset coverage of just under 1.6:1 as of March 6, according to TD Securities. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.94% based on a bid of 9.61 and a hardMaturity 2011-12-15 at 10.00.
MFC.PR.A OpRet +1.2785% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 3.89% based on a bid of 25.35 and a softMaturity 2015-12-18 at 25.00.
BSD.PR.A InterestBearing +1.5991% Asset coverage of 1.6+:1 as of March 7, according to Brookfield Funds. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.90% (mostly as interest) based on a bid of 9.53 and a hardMaturity 2015-3-31 at 10.00.
W.PR.H PerpetualDiscount +1.6352% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.70% based on a bid of 24.24 and a limitMaturity.
BNA.PR.C SplitShare +2.2947% Asset coverage of 3.3+:1 as of January 31, according to the company. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.03% based on a bid of 20.06 and a hardMaturity 2019-1-10 at 25.00. Compare with BNA.PR.A (5.67% to call 2008-10-31) and BNA.PR.B (7.71% to hardMaturity 2016-3-25).
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
PWF.PR.J OpRet 100,272 Desjardins crossed 100,000 at 26.10. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 3.79% based on a bid of 26.08 and a call 2010-5-30 at 25.00.
PWF.PR.D OpRet 94,410 Nesbitt crossed 60,000 at 26.49. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.46% based on a bid of 26.41 and a call 2008-4-10 at 26.00. Will yield 4.02% if it makes it to the softMaturity 2012-10-30 at 25.00.
PWF.PR.K PerpetualDiscount 29,300 Nesbitt crossed 25,000 at 22.70. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.53% based on a bid of 22.66 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.G PerpetualDiscount 28,030 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.37% based on a bid of 21.16 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.O PerpetualDiscount 24,831 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW 5.23% based on a bid of 23.45 and a limitMaturity.

There were thirty-three other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

Subprime! Problems forseeable in 2005?

Tuesday, March 11th, 2008

This won’t be much of a review, but I have come across a rather provocatively abstracted paper: Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis, by Yuliya Demyanyk and Otto van Hemert, both of the Federal Reserve Board, dated February 29, 2008:

[abstract] Using loan-level data, we analyze the quality of subprime mortgage loans by adjusting their performance for differences in borrower characteristics, loan characteristics, and house price appreciation since origination. We find that the quality of loans deteriorated for six consecutive years before the crisis and that securitizers were, to some extent, aware of it. We provide evidence that the rise and fall of the subprime mortgage market follows a classic lending boom-bust scenario, in which unsustainable growth leads to the collapse of the market. Problems could have been detected long before the crisis, but they were masked by high house price appreciation between 2003 and 2005.

[Extract from conclusion] The decline in loan quality has been monotonic, but not equally spread among different types of borrowers. Over time, high-LTV borrowers became increasingly risky (their adjusted performance worsened more) compared to low-LTV borrowers. Securitizers seem to have been aware of this particular pattern in the relative riskiness of borrowers: We show that over time mortgage rates became more sensitive to the LTV ratio of borrowers. In 2001, for example, the premium paid by a high LTV borrower was close to zero. In contrast, in 2006 a borrower with a one standard deviation above-average LTV ratio paid a 30 basis point premium compared to an average LTV borrower.

In many respects, the subprime market experienced a classic lending boom bust scenario with rapid market growth, loosening underwriting standards, deteriorating loan performance, and decreasing risk premiums. Argentina in 1980, Chile in 1982, Sweden, Norway, and Finland in 1992, Mexico in 1994, Thailand, Indonesia, and Korea in 1997 all experienced the culmination of a boom-bust scenario, albeit in different economic settings.

Were problems in the subprime mortgage market apparent before the actual crisis showed signs in 2007? Our answer is yes, at least by the end of 2005. Using the data available only at the end of 2005, we show that the monotonic degradation of the subprime market was already apparent. Loan quality had been worsening for five consecutive years at that point. Rapid appreciation in housing prices masked the deterioration in the subprime mortgage market and thus the true riskiness of subprime mortgage loans. When housing prices stopped climbing, the risk in the market became apparent.

 

 

March 10, 2008

Monday, March 10th, 2008

Bloomberg has a story headlined TIPS’ Yields Show Fed Has Lost Control of Inflation::

“The way TIPS are trading now, investors believe headline inflation will stay lofty and are willing to give up the real yield for that,” said Brian Brennan, a money manager who helps oversee $11 billion in fixed-income assets at T. Rowe Price Group Inc. based in Baltimore. Prices for the securities indicate “a real concern of a recession and high headline inflation,” he said.

This is the type of boneheaded analysis that is rife now that the smiley-boy salesmen have taken over the industry completely. If the driver of these real yields is inflation, then why is the 30-year Treasury bond yielding less than 4.5%?

As Accrued Interest points out, Treasury yields are being driven by fear, with investors piling into government guaranteed debt for the simple reason that they want to protect their capital. TIPS are simply maintaining a spread to nominals – an increasing spread, to be sure; inflation fears are part of the picture as I have previously discussed, but to ascribe the entire move to this is … boneheaded. Sorry folks, I just can’t think of any other word.

PerpetualDiscounts got smacked again today, on extremely light volume – all eyes, yet again, were on the equity markets and wondering if the music would stop with EVERYBODY holding the hot potato. BCE issues did very well – it appears that there are some who took the unsuccessful bondholders’ lawsuit a lot more seriously than I did.

Note that these indices are experimental; the absolute and relative daily values are expected to change in the final version. In this version, index values are based at 1,000.0 on 2006-6-30
Index Mean Current Yield (at bid) Mean YTW Mean Average Trading Value Mean Mod Dur (YTW) Issues Day’s Perf. Index Value
Ratchet 5.50% 5.52% 32,606 14.64 2 +0.8109% 1,088.6
Fixed-Floater 4.76% 5.57% 63,718 14.78 8 +1.1067% 1,043.2
Floater 4.72% 4.79% 86,094 15.78 2 +0.6984% 868.2
Op. Retract 4.84% 3.62% 73,774 2.74 15 -0.1461% 1,044.8
Split-Share 5.34% 5.68% 97,706 4.04 14 -0.2302% 1,030.2
Interest Bearing 6.21% 6.64% 67,951 4.22 3 -0.2713% 1,080.0
Perpetual-Premium 5.76% 5.63% 285,094 8.77 17 -0.0144% 1,022.8
Perpetual-Discount 5.46% 5.52% 263,316 14.62 51 -0.4534% 942.8
Major Price Changes
Issue Index Change Notes
FBS.PR.B SplitShare -2.5641% Asset coverage of just under 1.5:1 as of March 6, according TD Securities. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.28% based on a bid of 9.50 and a hardMaturity 2011-12-15 at 10.00.
SLF.PR.D PerpetualDiscount -1.8310% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.33% based on a bid of 20.91 and limitMaturity.
SLF.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -1.4286% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.39% based on a bid of 22.08 and a limitMaturity.
BMO.PR.J PerpetualDiscount -1.4112% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.61% based on a bid of 20.26 and a limitMaturity.
ELF.PR.F PerpetualDiscount -1.3453% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.13% based on a bid of 22.00 and a limitMaturity. 
CM.PR.E PerpetualDiscount -1.3158% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.91% based on a bid of 24.00 and a limitMaturity.
IAG.PR.A PerpetualDiscount -1.3133% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.48% based on a bid of 21.04 and a limitMaturity.
RY.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -1.2471% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.43% based on a bid of 21.38 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.N PerpetualDiscount -1.2245% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.49% based on a bid of 24.20 and a limitMaturity.
WFS.PR.A SplitShare -1.2036% Asset coverage of just under 1.8:1 as of February 29, according to Mulvihill. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 6.14% based on a bid of 9.85 and a hardMaturity 2011-6-30 at 10.00.
RY.PR.G PerpetualDiscount -1.1699% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.38% based on a bid of 21.12 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.H PerpetualDiscount -1.1628% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.73% based on a bid of 21.25 and a limitMaturity. 
RY.PR.E PerpetualDiscount -1.1531% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.30% based on a bid of 21.43 and a limitMaturity.
MFC.PR.A OpRet -1.1453% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 4.09% based on a bid of 25.03 and a softMaturity 2015-12-18 at 25.00.
SLF.PR.C PerpetualDiscount -1.1268% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.30% based on a bid of 21.06 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.L PerpetualDiscount -1.0295% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.40% based on a bid of 21.15 and a limitMaturity.
NA.PR.L PerpetualDiscount -1.0078% Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.66% based on a bid of 21.61 and a limitMaturity.
BCE.PR.A FixFloat +1.0417%  
BCE.PR.C FixFloat +1.0417%  
FTU.PR.A SplitShare +1.2360% Asset coverage of just under 1.5:1 as of February 29, according to the company. Probably a little under 1.4:1 now, given poor performance this month of US Financials. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 7.88% based on a bid of 9.01 and a hardMaturity 2012-12-1 at 10.00.
BCE.PR.B FixFloat +1.6518%  
BCE.PR.G FixFloat +1.9108%  
BCE.PR.Z FixFloat +2.0408%  
BCE.PR.I FixFloat +2.0842%  
Volume Highlights
Issue Index Volume Notes
NA.PR.L PerpetualDiscount 51,515 TD crossed 48,300 at 21.75. Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.66% based on a bid of 21.61 and a limitMaturity.
BNS.PR.O PerpetualPremium 21,239 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.64% based on a bid of 25.11 and a limitMaturity.
TD.PR.P PerpetualDiscount 13,607 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.46% based on a bid of 24.32 and a limitMaturity.
PWF.PR.H PerpetualPremium 11,500 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW of 5.82% based on a bid of 25.00 and a limitMaturity.
CM.PR.I PerpetualDiscount 11,478 Now with a pre-tax bid-YTW 5.81% based on a bid of 20.52 and a limitMaturity.

There were three other index-included $25-pv-equivalent issues trading over 10,000 shares today.

Dividend Details for FIG.PR.A Not Available

Monday, March 10th, 2008

No information regarding the relevant dates for the interest payment on FIG.PR.A is currently available, either on the sponsor’s website or via the TSX.

Dates have been estimated as 3/20, 3/25, 4/1.

ABK.PR.B Issue Closes

Monday, March 10th, 2008

Assiduous Readers will recall that the redemption of ABK.PR.C was to be funded by a new issue.

Scotia Managed Companies has announced:

that it has completed its public offering of 1,329,368 Class B Preferred Shares, raising approximately $35.6 million. The Class B Preferred Shares were offered to the public by a syndicate of agents led by Scotia Capital Inc. In addition, the Company has redeemed all of its outstanding Class A Preferred Shares and 66,684 of its Class A Capital Shares.

Holders of 332,342 Class A Capital Shares (before giving effect to the four-for-one share subdivision) did not retract their Class A Capital Shares pursuant to the special retraction right created in accordance with the capital reorganization approved by holders of the Class A Capital Shares on January 25, 2008 and, accordingly, 1,329,368 Class A Capital Shares remain outstanding after giving effect to the four-for-one share subdivision, which became effective as of March 10, 2008. The Class B Preferred Shares were offered in order to fund in part, the redemption of 66,684 Class A Capital Shares and all of the Class A Preferred Shares and to maintain the leveraged “split share” structure of the Company.

The prospectus for ABK.PR.B states:

Holders of Class B Preferred Shares will be entitled to receive quarterly fixed cumulative preferential distributions equal to $0.3344 per Class B Preferred Share. On an annualized basis, this would represent a yield on the offering price of the Class B Preferred Shares of approximately 5.00%. Based on the expected closing date of March 10, 2008, the initial dividend will be approximately $0.3344 per Class B Preferred Share and is expected to be payable on or about June 10, 2008. See ‘‘Details of the Offering — Certain Provisions of the Class B Preferred Shares’’.

The Class B Preferred Shares may be surrendered for retraction at any time and will be redeemed by the Company on March 8, 2013 (the ‘‘Redemption Date’’). In addition, the Class B Preferred Shares are redeemable at the option of the Company, at any time, in whole or in part, at a premium which declines to $26.75 in year five and may otherwise be redeemed by the Company prior to the Redemption Date in certain limited circumstances including on March 10 in each year or, where such day is not a business day, on the preceding business day, if there are any unmatched retractions of Class A Capital Shares. See ‘‘Description of Share Capital — Certain Provisions of the Class A Capital Shares’’.

It should be noted that these shares have the nasty provision of being callable at par annually, if there are unmatched capital unit retractions:

The Company may also redeem Class B Preferred Shares on March 10 of any year commencing in 2009 at a price per share equal to $26.75 to the extent that unmatched Class A Capital Shares have been tendered for retraction under a Special Annual Retraction. See ‘‘Details of the Offering — Certain Provisions of the Class B Preferred Shares — Redemption’’.

This issue will not be tracked by HIMIPref™. It’s too small and the annual redemption at par makes the risk/reward profile too asymmetric for my taste.

Update, 2008-3-11: DBRS has rated this issue Pfd-2(low):

the split share structure provides downside protection of 50% to the Class B Preferred Shares (after expenses). The redemption date for the Class B Preferred Shares and the Class A Capital Shares is March 8, 2013.

The Pfd-2 (low) rating of the Class B Preferred Shares is based on the downside protection available to the Preferred Shareholders, as well as the initial dividend coverage.

The primary constraints to the rating are the following:

(1) The downside protection available to holders of the Class B Preferred Shares depends completely on the value of the common shares of the Portfolio.

(2) The concentration of the entire portfolio in the financial services industry and the general exposure of the Canadian banks to the current credit cycle.

(3) Volatility of price and changes in dividend policies of the Portfolio’s underlying banks may result in reductions in downside protection from time to time.